Skip to main content

Full text of "Indiana Law Review"

See other formats


Periodical 
Collection 


jndiana 
law 

Review 


'   ^ 


Volume  22  No.  4  1989 


,1»»r'*» 


t'5/fJJ«y 


ARTICLES 


The  Right  to  a  Lawyer  at  a  Lineup:  Support  From 
State  Courts  and  Experimental  Psychology 

Neil  C.  McCabe 

NOTES 

Partial  Settlement  of  Multiple  Tortfeasor  Cases  Under 
the  Indiana  Comparative  Fault  Act 

Retroactive  Application  of  Legislatively  Enlarged 

Statutes  of  Limitations  for  Child  Abuse: 

Time's  No  Bar  to  Revival 

"A  Modest  Proposal"— The  Prohibition  of  All-Adult 

Communities  by  the  Fair  Housing 

Amendments  Act  of  1988 

The  Fraud  on  the  Market  Theory:  A  **Basic''aUy  Good 

Idea  Whose  Time  Has  Arrived, 

Basic  Inc.  v.  Levinson 

Institutional  Arrangements  for  Governing  the 

Construction  of  Electric  Generating  Units: 

A  Transaction  Cost  Analysis 


REVIEWS 

^^^^Tjk       I  Search  thousands  of  law  review  and  bar  journal 

/       ^  |\     I  articles  effortlessly  on  WESTLAW!  It's  like  having 

I  11  \    I  a  staff  of  experts  always  at  your  command.  To 

■  f  I    ^1  answer  your  questions  on  Ttoation,  Business 

%.    y  \^      yl  Regulation,  Bankruptcy,  Securities,  and  more! 

WESILW! 


Find  relevant  articles  instantly  Search  the  full  text 
of  articles  using  descriptive  words,  titles,  author's 
names,  topics  or  any  combination. 

When  you  want  to  know  what  the  experts  say  on 
your  subject,  turn  to  WESTLAW. 

Find  out  more  by  contacting  your  West  Sales 
Representative  or  by  calling  1-800-328-0109 
(or  0-612-688-3654  collect  in  MN). 


WESTLAW. 

Key  Number  Power.  A  Winning  Tradition. 

©  1990  West  Publishing  Company  9204-8B/1-90 


WESTLAW 


Dedaons, 
Deciaons, 
Deciaons. 


^  ^  tj^'"^^^. 


Every  week,  there  are  over  1,000  decisions  rendered  by  the  federal 
appellate  courts,  federal  district  courts,  and  state  courts.  Many  will  affect 
your  clients.  But  you  can't  possibly  review  them  all.  So  how  do  you  decide 
which  to  read.? 

Put  BNA's  U.S.  Law  Week  to  work. 

Each  year  the  lawyers  who  edit  Law  Week  screen  over  50,000  state 
and  federal  opinions  for  you  and  report  digests  and  text  of  only  the  most 
important  ones  in  all  areas  of  the  law. 

With  Law  Week  every  week,  it  takes  just  a  few  minutes  to  keep  up  with 
critical  decisions  you  must  know  about  to  successfully  represent  your  clients. 

See  for  yourself  Call  for  a  free  sample  issue  today.  Then  make  your 
own  decision  to  subscribe.  For  a  sample  issue  of  Law  Week,  call  toll-free: 
1-800-372-1033. 

People  who  know  law,  know  BNA. 


THE  BUREAU  OF  NATIONAL  AFFAIRS,  INC. 

1231 25th  Street,  N.W.,  Washington,  D.C.  20037 


I 


Indiana  National 


on  the  subject  of  options 


Investment 
option 

Minimum 
Investment 

Maturities 

Credit 

income 

Benefits 

Tax-Exempt 
Municipal  Bonds/ 
Unit  Investment 
Trusts 

$   5,000 
1,000 

To  30  Years 

Backed  by  Issuer 

Semi-Annual 

Coupon/ 

Monthly, 

Quarterly, 

Semi-Annual 

Exempt  from  Federal  Income  Tax  for  Corpo- 
rations, and  from  State  and  Federal  Tax  for 
Individuals.* 

Money  Market 
Funds 

1,000 

Day  to  Day 

Issuing  Fund 

Monthly 

High  current  income,  preservation  of  capi- 
tal, easy  withdrawal  procedures.  Share 
value  stability  &  check  writing  redemption. 

Mutual  Funds 

250 

Open  End 
Funds 

Issuing  Fund 

Monthly 

High  current  return,  monthly  income,  liquid- 
ity, high  quality  portfolios. 

U.S.  Treasury 
Bills 

10,000 

One  Year 
or  Jess 

Direct  Obligations 
of  U.S.  Treasury 

Discount  to 
Maturity 

High  quality,  extremely  liquid,  state  tax 
exempt.* 

U.S.  Treasury 
Notes 

5,000 
1,000 

1  -  3  Years 
3  - 10  Years 

Direct  Obligations 
of  U.S.  Treasury 

Somi-Annual 
Coupon 

High  quality,  extremely  marketable,  state 
tax  exempt  * 

U.S.  Treasury 
Bonds 

1,000 

Over  10 
Years 

Direct  Obligations 
of  U.S.  Treasury 

Semi-Annual 
Coupon 

High  quality,  extremely  marketable,  state 
tax  exempt  * 

Discount  Ntotes: 
Primarily  Federal 
Home  Loan  Banks, 
FNMA,  Federal 
Farm  Ctedit  Banks 

10,000 

30  to  360 
Days 

Issuing  Agency 

At  Maturity 

May  offer  higher  yields  and  smaller  mini- 
mums  than  Treasury  issues.  High  quality 
and  extremely  liquid.* 

Federal  Farm 
Credit,  FNMA, 
Federal  Home 
Loan  Banks 

1,000 

5,000 

10,000 

6  Months  to 
30  Years 

Issuing  Agency 

At  Maturity  or 
Semi-Annual 
Coupon 

May  offer  higher  yields  and  smaller  mini- 
mums  than  Treasury  issues.  High  quality 
and  good  marketability* 

Bankers 
Acceptances 

100,000 

10  Days  to 
270  Days 

Guaranteed  by 
Issuing  Bank 

Discount  to 
Maturity 

High  quality  and  extremely  liquid.* 

Commercial  Paper 

100,000 

To  270 
Days 

Backed  by  Issuer 

At  Maturity  or 
Discount  to 
Maturity 

High  yields,  good  marketability 
highly  liquid.* 

'Possible  market  risk  if  sokl  before  maturity  date. 


Have  you  considered 
all  your  options? 


Investment  banking  from  Indiana  National 

You  may  not  have  thought  of  Indiana  National  as  a 
source  of  investment  banking.  But  we're  one  of 
Indiana's  major  marketers  of  tax-exempt  municipal 
bonds  and  notes,  government  and  agency  securities. 

Reaching  your  investment  goals 

Our  account  executives  have  proven  their  capabilittes 
and  market  insights  by  assisting  clients  in  the 
acquisition  of  over  $32  billion  in  fixed  income  securities 
during  the  last  five  years. 

And  because  they  focus  on  safety,  liquidity  and  rate  of 
return,  they  provide  the  kind  of  securities  that  meet 
clients'  investment  objectives. 


Managing  your  investment  plan 

At  Indiana  National  you  receive  individualized  attention 
to  your  investment  goals.  And  you  benefit  from  our 
decades  of  experience  in  personal  service  and  prompt 
execution  of  trades. 

The  next  time  you're  ready  to  make  an  investment, 
think  of  Indiana  National.  Because,  when  it  comes  to 
meeting  your  investment  objectives,  we've  got  all  the 
options. 

Call  1-800-382-1102  or  (317)  266-6829  for  more 
information. 

#9^  Indiana  National 


investment  Banking  Division 


Member  FDIC 


Please  enter  my  subscription  to  the 
INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW 


NAME 


ADDRESS 


Enclosed  is  $. 
Bill  me  for  _ 
Mail  to: 


for 


subscriptions. 


subscriptions. 


INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW 

INDIANA  UNIVERSITY 

SCHOOL  OF  LAW -INDIANAPOLIS 

735  West  New  York  Street 

Indianapolis,  Indiana  46202 

Subscription  Rates  (one  year): 

Regular,  $22;  Foreign,  $25;  Survey,  $15; 
Single  Issue,  $7 


Indiana  Laiv  Revieir 


Volume  22  1989  Number  4 

Copyright  ©  1989  by  the  Trustees  of  Indiana  University 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Articles 

The  Right  to  a  Lawyer  at  a  Lineup:  Support  From  State  Courts  and 
Experimental  Psychology Neil  C.  McCabe    905 

Notes 

Partial  Settlement  of  Multiple  Tortfeasor  Cases  Under  the  Indiana 
Comparative  Fault  Act 939 

Retroactive  Application  of  Legislatively  Enlarged  Statutes  of 

Limitations  for  Child  Abuse:  Time's  No  Bar  to  Revival 989 

*'A  Modest  Proposal"— The  Prohibition  of  Ail-Adult  Communities 
by  the  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988 1021 

The  Fraud  on  the  Market  Theory:  A  "Basic"ally  Good  Idea  Whose 
Time  Has  Arrived,  Basic  Inc.  v.  Levinson 1061 

Institutional  Arrangements  for  Governing  the  Construction  of  Electric 
Generating  Units:  A  Transaction  Cost  Analysis 1085 


Volume  22  1989  Number  4 

The  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  (ISSN  0090-4198)  is  the  property  of  Indiana  University  and  is  published  quarterly 
by  the  Indiana  University  School  of  Law — Indianapolis,  which  assumes  complete  editorial  itsponsibility  thereof.  Subscription 
rates:  one  year  $22;  foreign  $25.  Please  notify  us  one  month  in  advance  of  any  change  in  address  and  include  both  old 
and  new  addresses  with  zip  codes  to  ensure  delivery  of  all  issues.  Send  all  correspondence  to  Editorial  Assistant,  Indiana 
Law  Review,  Indiana  University  School  of  Law — Indianapolis,  735  West  New  York  Street,  Indianapolis,  Indiana  46202. 
Publication  office:  735  West  New  York  Street,  Indianapolis,  Indiana  46202.  Second  class  postage  paid  at  Indianapolis, 
Indiana  46201. 

POSTMASTER:  Send  address  changes  to  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW,  735  West  New  York  Street,  Indianapolis,  In- 
diana 46202. 


Indiana  La^^  Revieir 


Volume  22  1989 


Editor-in-Chief 
Robert  G.  Solloway 

Executive  Editors 

Articles  and  Production  Notes  and  Topics 

Carol  Kirk  Katharine  Liell  Polito 

Articles  Editors 
Rebecca  S.  Bowman  Madonna  F.  McGrath 

Debra  Linn  Burns  Peggy  J.  Naile 

Cynthia  Pearson  Purvis 

Business  Editor  and  Survey  Coordinator 
Robert  Davis 

Note  Development  Editors 
Bruce  J.  Alvarado  Catherine  A.  Kling 

Douglas  E.  Cressler  Olivia  A.  Napariu 

Karen  Glasser  Deane  Douglas  K.  Norman 


L 


Associate  Editors 
Rene  F.  Barnard  Kisti  L.  Good 

Carolyn  A.  Bielefeld  Barbara  E.  Lollar 

Raymond  Charles  Bowyer  Karen  R.  McClure 

Thomas  A.  Brodnik  Deborah  B.  Noah 

Gary  L.  Chapman  Paul  F.  Reidy 

L.S.  John  Ciecimirski  Mara  J.  Snyder 

Jane  A.  B.  Eppink  Clare  M.  Sproule 

Brian  S.  Fennerty  Darlene  M.  Stephens 

E.  Scott  Treadway 


Editorial  Assistant 
Amy  Morrison  Grubbs 

Faculty  Advisor 
Paul  J.  Galanti 


Indiana  University  School  of  Law — Indianapolis 

1989-1990  ADMINISTRATIVE  OFFICERS  AND  FACULTY 

Administrative  Officers 

Thomas  M.  Ehrlich,  LL.B.,  President  of  the  University 

Gerald  L.  Bepko,  LL.M.,   Vice-President 

Norman  Lefstein,  LL.B.,  Dean 

James  F.  Bindley,  J.D.,  Assistant  Dean  for  Administration 

Debra  a.  Falender,  J.D.,  Acting  Assistant  Dean  of  Administration 

Lawrence  P.  Wilkins,  LL.M.,  Associate  Dean  for  Academic  Affairs 

Faculty 

Thomas  B.  Allington,  Professor.  B.S.,  University  of  Nebraska,  1964;  J.D.,  1966;  LL.M., 

New  York  University,   1971. 
Edward  P.   Archer,   Professor.   B.M.E.,   Rensselaer  Polytechnic  Institute,    1958;  J.D., 

Gerogetown  University,   1962;  LL.M.,   1964. 
James  F.  Bailey,  III.,  Professor  and  Director  of  Law  Library.  A.B.,  University  of  Michigan, 

1961;  J.D.,  1964;  M.A.L.S.,  1970. 
Gerald  L.  Bepko,  Vice  President  and  Professor.  B.S.,  Northern  Illinois  University,  1962; 

J.D.,  I  IT /Chicago-Kent  College  of  Law.   1965;  LL.M.,    Yale  University,   1972. 
James  F.  Bindley,  Assistant  Dean  for  Administration  and  Director  of  Placement  &  Develop- 
ment, B.A.,  Loyola  University,   1969;  J.D.,   University  of  Kentucky.   1972. 
Paul  N.  Cox,  Professor.  B.S.,  Utah  State  University,  1972;  J.D.,  University  of  Utah,  1974; 

LL.M.,   University  of  Virginia,   1980. 
Clyde  Harrison  Crockett,  Professor.  A.B.,  University  of  Texas,  1962;  J.D.,  1965;  LL.M., 

University  of  London  (The  London  School  of  Economics  and  Political  Science),  1972. 
Debra  A.  Falender,  Professor  &  Associate  Dean  for  Student  Affairs.  A.B.,  Mount  Holyoke 

College,  1970;  J.D.,  Indiana  University,  1975. 
David  A.  Funk,  Professor.  A.B.,  College  of  Wooster,  1949;  J.D.,  Case  Western  Reserve 

University,  1951;  M.A.,  The  Ohio  State  University  1968;  LL.M.,  Case  Western  Reserve 

University,  1972;  LL.M.,  Columbia  University,   1973. 
Paul  J.  Galanti,  Professor.  A.B.,  Bowdoin  College,  1960;  J.D.,  University  of  Chicago,  1963. 
Helen  P.  Garheld,  Professor.  B.S.f,  Northwestern  University,  1945;  J.D.,  University  of 

Colorado,   1967. 
Harold  Greenberg,  Professor.   A.B.,    Temple  University,   1959;  J.D.,    University  of 

Pennsylvania,  1962. 
Jeffrey  W.  Grove,  Professor.  A.B.,  Juniata  College,  1965;  J.D.,  George  Washington  Univer- 
sity,  1969. 
Welllam  F.  Harvey,  Carl  M.  Gray  Professor  of  Law.  A.B.,  University  of  Missouri,  1954; 

J.D.,  Georgetown  University,  1959;  LL.M.,   1961. 
Paul  T.  Hayden,  Assistant  Professor.  B.A.,    Yale  University,   1979;  J.D.,   University  of 

California,  Los  Angeles,   1984. 
W.  William  Hodes,  Professor.  A.B.,  Harvard  College,  1966;  J.D.,  Rugters  Newark,  1969. 
Lisa  C.  Ikemoto,  Assistant  Professor.  B.A.,  University  of  California,  Los  Angeles,  1984; 

J.D.,  University  of  California,  Davis,  1987;  L.L.M.,  Columbia,  1989. 
Lawrence  A.  Jegen,  IIL,  Thomas  F.  Sheehan  Professor  of  Tax  Law  and  Policy,  1982. 

A.B.,  Beloit  College  1956;  J.D.,  The  University  of  Michigan  1959;  M.B.A.,  1960, 

LL.M.,  Harvard  University,   1963. 
Henry  C.  Karlson,  Professor.  A.B.,  University  of  Illinois,  1965;  J.D.,  1968;  LL.M.,  1977. 
WiLLLVM  Andrew  Kerr,  Professor.  A.B.,  West  Virginia  University,  1955.  J.D.,  1957,  LL.M., 

Harvard  University,   1958;  D.B.,  Duke  University,   1968. 
Eleanor  D.  Kinney,  Associate  Professor.  A.B.,  Duke  University,  1969;  M.A.,  University 

of  Chicago,  1970;  J.D.,  Duke  University,  1973. 
Walter  W.  Krieger,  Associate  Professor.  A.B.,  Bellarmine  College,  1959;  J.D.,  University 

of  Louisville,  1962;  LL.M.,  George  Washington  University,  1969. 
Norman   Lefstein,   Dean   and  Professor.    LL.B.,    University  of  Illinois,    1961;  LL.M., 

Georgetown  University,   1964. 


David  P.  Leonard,  Professor.  B.A.,  University  of  California  at  San  Diego,  1974;  J.D., 

UCLA  School  of  Law,  1977. 
William  E.  Marsh,  Professor.  B.S.,   University  of  Nebraska,  1965;  J.D.,  1958. 
SusANAH  M.  Mead,  Professor.  B.A.,   Smith  College,   1969;  J.D.,  Indiana  University, 

1976. 
Mary  H.   Mitchell,  Professor.  A.B.,   Butler  University,   1975;  J.D.,   Cornell  Law 

School,  1978. 
James  P.  Nehf,  Assistant  Professor.  B.A.,  Knox  College,  1979;  J.D.,  University  of  North 

Carolina,  1983. 
David  R.  Papke,  Associate  Professor.  A.B.,  Harvard  College,  1969;  J.D.,  Yale  Law  School, 

1973;  M.A.,  in  American  Studies,  Yale  University,  1973;  Ph.D.,  in  American  Studies, 

The  University  of  Michigan,  1984. 
Ronald  W.  Polston,  Professor.  B.S.,  Eastern  Illinois  University,  1953;  LL.B.,  University 

of  Illinois,  1958. 
Kenneth  M.  Stroud,  Professor.  A.B.,  Indiana  University,  1958;  J.D.,  1961. 
James  W.  Torke,  Professor.  B.S.,   University  of  Wisconsin,  1963;  J.D.,  1968. 
Joe  a.  Tucker,  Assistant  Professor.  B.A.,  Houston,  1977;  J.D.,  University  of  Texas,  1981. 
James  Patrick  Whtfe,  Professor  of  Law.  A.B.,  University  of  Iowa,  1953;  J.D.,  1956;  LL.M., 

George  Washington  University,  1959. 
Lawrence  P.  Wilkins,  Professor.  B.A.,  The  Ohio  State  University,  1968;  J.D.,  Capital 

University  Law  School,  1973;  LL.M.,   University  of  Texas  School  of  Law,  1974. 
Mary  Wolf,  Director  of  Clinical  Programs,  B.A.,  Saint  Xavier  College,  1969;  J.D.,  University 

of  Iowa  College  of  Law,  1974. 

Emeriti 

Agnes  P.  Barrett,  Associate  Professor  Emeritus.  B.S.,  Indiana  University,  1942;  J.D.,  1964. 
Cleon  H.  Foust,  Professor  Emeritus.  A.B.,   Wabash  College.   1928;  J.D.,   University  of 

Arizona,  1933. 
John  S.  Grimes,  Professor  of  Jurisprudence  Emeritus.  A.B.,  Indiana  University.  1929;  J.D., 

1931. 
Melvin  C.  Poland,  Cleon  H.  Foust  Professor  of  Law  Emeritus.  B.S.,  Kansas  State  University, 

1940;  LL.B.,  Washburn  University,  1949;  LL.M.,  The  University  of  Michigan,  1950. 
R.  Bruce  Townsend,  Cleon  H.  Foust  Professor  of  Law  Emeritus,  A.B.,  Coe  College,  1938; 

J.D.,    University  of  Iowa,   1940. 

Legal  Writing  Instructors 

Deborah  B.  McGregor,  B.A.,  University  of  Evansville,  1973;  J.D.,  Georgetown  University 

Law  Center,  1983. 
Tracy  A.  Nelson,  B.A.,  University  of  Denver,  1981;  J.D.,  Indiana  University,  Indianapolis, 

1985. 
David  A.  Reidy,  Jr.,  B.A.,  DePauw  University,  1984;  J.D.,  Indiana  University,  Bloomington 

1987. 
Joan  Ruhtenberg,  Director  of  Legal  Writing.  B.A.,  Mississippi  University  Women,  1959; 
J.D.,  Indiana  University,  1980. 

Law  Library  Staff 

MiNDE  C.  Glenn,  Reference  Librarian,  B.A.,  Western  Michigan  University,  1979;  M.L.S., 

Indiana  University,  1980. 
Wendell  E.  Johnting,  Asst.  Director  for  Technical  Services,  A.B.,  Taylor  University,  1974; 

M.L.S.,  Indiana  University,  1975. 
Mahnaz  K.  Moshfegh,  Acquisitions /Serials  Librarian,  B.A.,  National  University  of  Iran,  1966; 

M.S.,  Tehran  University,  1971;  M.A.,  Ball  State  University,  1977;  M.L.S.,  Indiana 

University,  1983;  Ph.D.,  Indiana  University,  1988. 
KiYOSHi  Otsu,  Catalog  Librarian,  A.  A.,  Parkland  College,  1976;  A.  B.,  University  of  Illinois, 

1980;  M.S.,  1982;  C.A.S.,  1983. 
Merlin  P.  Whiteman,  Asst.  Director  for  Readers'  Services,  B.A.,  Hope  College,  1973;  M.L.S., 

Indiana  University,  1974;  J.D.,  1982. 


Indiana  Laiv  Revieir 

Volume  22  1989  Number  4 


The  Right  to  a  Lawyer  at  a  Lineup:  Support  From  State 
Courts  and  Experimental  Psychology 


Neil  Colman  McCabe* 


I.    Introduction 

The  tales  of  two  Texas  bank  robbery  cases,  twenty  years  apart,  tell 
how  the  right  to  have  counsel  present  at  a  lineup  '  started  well  but  ran 
afoul  of  an  aberrant  interpretation  of  the  sixth  amendment.  The  two 
cases  also  provide  a  backdrop  for  a  demonstration  of  how  state  courts, 
armed  with  a  better  understanding  of  the  dangers  inherent  in  eyewitness 
identifications,  are  struggling  to  free  themselves  from  the  constraints  of 
United  States  Supreme  Court  doctrine. 

In  both  cases  the  robbers  wore  disguises  of  dubious  value.  In  1964, 
a  man  with  a  small  strip  of  tape  on  each  side  of  his  face  robbed  a 
bank  in  Eustace,  Texas.  In  1985,  another  holdup  man,  sporting  a  shower 
cap  and  sunglasses,  struck  several  banks  in  Houston.  Lineups  provided 
the  key  identification  testimony  in  both  cases. 

In  the  first  case.  United  States  v.  Wade,^  the  United  States  Supreme 
Court  declared  that  a  criminal  suspect  has  a  sixth  amendment  right  to 
a  lawyer  at  a  lineup.  By  the  time  of  the  later  case  of  Foster  v.  State, ^ 
however,  state  and  federal  courts  were  deciding  that  no  such  right  exists 


*  Professor  of  Law,  South  Texas  College  of  Law.  The  author  of  this  article 
serves  as  court-appointed  counsel  for  the  appellant  in  Foster  v.  State,  713  S.W.2d  789 
(Tex.  Ct.  App.  1986). 

1.  In  a  lineup  identification  proceeding  a  crime  witness  views  several  persons 
standing  in  a  line  and  is  asked  whether  any  of  them  is  the  perpetrator  of  the  offense. 

2.  388  U.S.  218  (1967).  The  companion  case  of  Gilbert  v.  California,  388  U.S. 
263  (1967),  also  involved  a  Hneup.  The  holdings  in  the  two  cases  became  known  as  the 
Wade-Gilbert  rule.  R.  LaFave  &  J.  Israel,  Criminal  Procedure  (1985). 

3.  713  S.W.2d  789  (Tex.  Ct.  App.  1986)  (The  Foster  case  actually  involved  a 
series  of  bank  robberies.) 

905 


906  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

in  the  typical  lineup.  That  is  true  because  in  Kirby  v.  Illinois,'^  only 
five  years  after  Wade,  the  United  States  Supreme  Court  held  that,  unless 
** adversary  judicial  proceedings"^  have  been  initiated  against  him,  an 
arrested  suspect  is  not  entitled  to  have  his  lawyer  attend  a  Uneup,^  Shortly 
afterward,  in  United  States  v.  Ash,'^  the  Court  held  that  there  is  no 
sixth  amendment  right  to  counsel  at  a  photographic  display,^  even  after 
indictment. 

With  Ash  it  became  clear  that  even  the  initiation  of  adversarial 
criminal  proceedings  did  not  mean  that  defense  counsel  was  to  be  allowed 
to  attend  every  phase  of  the  prosecution  after  that  point.  The  actual 
proceeding  in  question  must  be  examined  to  determine  whether  it  is  a 
confrontation  that  can  be  considered  a  "critical  stage"^  of  the  prose- 
cution, at  which  counsel's  presence  is  required.  The  suspect's  counsel 
need  not  be  permitted  to  attend  a  photographic  display,  reasoned  the 
Ash  Court,  because  the  suspect  is  not  physically  present  at  such  an 
identification  proceeding. ^°  The  photo  array  witness  interview  is  not  a 
confrontation.  Neither  is  the  array  proceeding  a  critical  stage  of  the 
prosecution.  Because  the  defendant's  attorney  could  examine  the  photo 
array  in  preparing  for  trial,  the  Court  believed  that  such  a  proceeding 
did  not  involve  the  same  dangers  of  suggestiveness  as  the  lineup  and 
was  more  easily  reconstructed  for  the  purpose  of  cross-examination  at 
trial. '^ 

Given  the  Kirby  and  Ash  decisions,  it  can  be  expected  the  police 
will  not  wait  until  after  the  initiation  of  formal  adversarial  proceedings 
to  hold  a  lineup  or  photo  array, '^  thereby  precluding  any  sixth  amendment 
claim  that  counsel  must  be  present.  In  the  typical  case,  they  conduct 
the  lineup  within  twenty-four  hours  after  arrest.*^  The  Wade  case  was 


4.  406  U.S.  682  (1972), 

5.  Id.  at  688. 

6.  Id.  at  691. 

7.  413  U.S.  300  (1973). 

8.  In  a  photographic  display  or  photo  array  proceeding  a  witness  is  shown  a 
group  of  photographs  and  is  asked  whether  the  suspect  is  depicted  therein. 

9.  Ash,  4i3  U.S.  at  303. 

10.  Id.  at  317. 

11.  Id.  at  318-19. 

12.  People  V.  Fowler,  1  Cal.  2d  335,  82  Cal.  Rptr.  363,  461  P.2d  643  (1969);  J. 
Israel,  Y.  Kamisar,  W.  LaFave,  Criminal  Procedure  and  the  Constitution  350  (Rev. 
ed.  1989)  (lineup  before  formal  proceedings  "common  practice"  after  Kirby). 

13.  Whitten  &  Robertson,  Post-Custody,  Pre-Indictment  Problems  of  Fundamental 
Fairness  and  Access  to  Counsel:  Mississippi's  Opportunity,  13  Vt.  L.  Rev.  247,  249 
(1988);  Alschuler,  Failed  Pragmatism:  Reflections  on  the  Burger  Court,  100  Harv.  L. 
Rev.  1436,  1442  (1987).  See  also  United  States  v.  Wade,  388  U.S.  218,  255  (1967)  (White, 
J.,  dissenting)  ("Identifications  frequently  take  place  after  arrest  but  before  an  indictment 
is  returned  or  an  information  is  filed."). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  907 

unusual  in  that  the  suspect  had  been  indicted  before  the  lineup.''*  At 
the  time  of  Foster's  lineup  he  had  not  been  arrested,  let  alone  formally 
charged  or  indicted  for  the  bank  robberies;  he  was  already  in  jail  serving 
a  sentence  on  other  offenses.'^  For  those  reasons  the  Texas  intermediate 
appellate  court  accorded  him  no  sixth  amendment  right  to  counsel  at 
the  lineup,  and  the  court  saw  no  reason  to  recognize  such  a  right  under 
state  lawJ^ 

Of  the  state  courts  that  have  addressed  the  issue  of  the  right  to 
counsel  at  a  lineup  under  state  constitutions  and  statutes,  most  have 
simply  followed  Kirby?^  This  article  will  argue  that  merely  adopting 
formalistic  federal  precedent  is  not  the  proper  way  to  interpret  state 
constitutional  guarantees  of  counsel,  especially  in  light  of  psychological 
research  into  the  dangers  of  eyewitness  and  lineup  identification  conducted 
since  the  Wade  and  Kirby  decisions.  Although  state  right-to-counsel 
provisions  sometimes  may  be  comparable  in  scope  to  the  federal  sixth 
amendment,  "an  independent  examination  of  the  history,  policy,  and 
precedent  surrounding  relevant  state  law  is  necessary  before  that  con- 
clusion can  be  reached."'^  This  article  will  demonstrate  how  a  conclusion 
contrary  to  Kirby  can  be  justified  in  light  of  (1)  new  research  into  the 
dangers  inherent  in  eyewitness  identification  in  general  and  in  lineups 
particularly,  (2)  the  nature  of  the  Kirby  line  of  cases  as  an  aberration 
to  the  sixth  amendment's  rationale,  and  (3)  precedents  from  state  courts. 
The  main  goal  is  to  show  how  a  significant  expansion  of  the  right  to 
counsel  can  rest  on  a  truly  independent  and  adequate  state  constitutional 
ground'^ — on  a  principled  basis  and  not  merely  as  a  result-oriented 
reaction  to  undesirable  federal  precedent. ^^ 

II.     Dangers  Inherent  in  Eyewitness  Identification 

Both  jurists  and  social  scientists  have  observed  that  the  inaccuracy 
of  many  eyewitness  identifications  and  the  resulting  injustices  are  well- 


14.  Wade,  338  U.S.  at  219. 

15.  Foster,  713  S.W.2cl  at  790. 

16.  Id.  at  791. 

17.  406  U.S.  682  (1972);  see,  e.g..  State  v.  Boyd,  294  A.2d  459  (Me.  1972);  People 
V.  Hawkins,  55  N.Y.2d  474,  450  N,Y.S.2d  159,  435  N.E.2d  376  (1982);  People  v.  Delahunt, 
121  R.I.  565,  401  A. 2d  1261  (1979);  State  v.  Taylor,  60  Wis.  2d  506,  210  N.W.2d  873 
(1973). 

18.  Thomas  v.  State,  723  S.W.2d  696,  702  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1986)  (citing  State 
V.  Jewett,  146  Vt.  221,  500  A.2d  233  (1985)). 

19.  Michigan  v.  Long,  463  U.S.  1032  (1983). 

20.  See  State  v.  Jewett,  146  Vt.  221,  224,  500  A.2d  233,  235  (1985)  (recognizing 
the  need  for  principled  bases  for  independent  state  constitutional  analysis);  See  also 
Abrahamson,  Criminal  Law  and  State  Constitutions:  The  Emergence  of  State  Constitutional 
Law,  63  Tex.  L.  Rev.   1141,  1179-80  (1985). 


908  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

known.2'  *'Nor  are  such  statements  vague  speculations;  the  documentation 
is  exhaustive,  explicit  and  vast."^^  Even  a  person  who  eventually  is 
acquitted  of  the  erroneous  criminal  charge  can  be  victimized  by  the 
resulting  trauma  to  his  mind,  emotions,  reputation,  job,  and  family. ^^ 
The  United  States  v.  Wade^'^  opinion,  which  recognized  a  right  to  counsel 
at  a  Hneup,  but  which  involved  a  postindictment  proceeding,  emphasized 
the  dangers  inherent  in  eyewitness  identification.  At  the  time  of  the 
Wade  and  Kirby  decisions,  *'[t]he  unreliability  of  human  perception  and 
memory  and  their  susceptibility  to  suggestive  influence  [were]  well  doc- 
umented in  psychological  and  legal  literature,"  but  there  were  no  scientific 
studies  of  the  behavior  of  the  eyewitness  in  the  context  of  the  lineup. ^^ 
Not  until  the  end  of  the  1970's  did  scientists  hold  the  first  conference 
concentrating  solely  on  the  psychology  of  testimony  by  eyewitnesses. ^^ 
Since  that  time,  much  more  study  has  been  applied  specifically  to  the 
lineup  problem,  and  a  better  understanding  of  eyewitness  memory  has 
developed.  ^^ 

The  results  of  experimental  psychology  suggest  that  many  of  the 
common-sense  assumptions  that  guide  decisions  of  the  participants  in  a 
criminal  trial  may  be  erroneous.  Professor  Yarmey  has  identified  some 
of  those  questionable  assumptions:^^  (1)  Subtle  differences  in  the  wording 
of  questions  (e.g.,  asking  if  the  witness  saw  the  knife  instead  of  asking 
if  she  saw  a  knife)  have  a  great  effect  on  the  responses  of  witnesses,^^ 


21.  A,  Yarmey,  The  Psychology  of  Eyewitness  Testimony  7-10  (1979). 

22.  People  v.  Hawkins,  55  N.Y.2d  474,  491,  450  N.Y.S.2d  159,  168,  435  N.E.2d 
376,  385  (Meyer,  J.,  dissenting)  (citing  fourteen  sources). 

23.  J.  Israel,  Y.  Kamisar,  W.  LaFave,  Criminal  Procedure  and  the  Consti- 
tution 450  (Rev.  ed.  1989);  Twining,  Identification  and  Misidentification  in  Legal  Processes: 
Redefining  the  Problem,  in  Evaluating  Witness  Evidence,  255,  275-77  (S.  Lloyd-Bostock 
&  B.  Clifford  eds.  1983)  (hereinafter  Lloyd-Bostock);  see  also  Wells  &  Loftus,  Eyewitness 
Research:  Then  and  Now,  in  Eyewqtness  Testimony  (G.  Wells  &  E.  Loftus  eds.  1984) 
(citing  P.  Hain,  Mistaken  Identity  (1976)). 

24.  388  U.S.  218  (1967). 

25.  Levine  &  Tapp,  The  Psychology  of  Criminal  Identification:  The  Gap  from 
Wade  to  Kirby,  121  U.  Pa.  L.  Rev.  1079,  1087-88  (1973). 

26.  Wells  &  Lindsay,  How  Do  People  Infer  the  Accuracy  of  Eyewitness  Memory? 
Studies  of  Performance  and  a  Metamemory  Analysis,  in  Lloyd-Bostock,  supra  note  23, 
at  41  (citing  Wells,  Eyewitness  Testimony:  The  Alberta  Conference,  4  Law  &  Hum.  Behav. 
237  (1980)). 

27.  See  Wells  &  Loftus,  Eyewitness  Research:  Then  and  Now,  in  Eyewitness 
Testimony:  Psychological  Perspectives  (G.  Wells  &  E.  Loftus  eds.  1984)  (hereinafter 
Perspectives)  (85%  of  all  published  writings  on  eyewitness  identification  research  have 
emerged  since  1978.  Id.  at  3.). 

28.  A.  Yarmey,  supra  note  20,  at  7-10  (citing  examples  and  authorities). 

29.  Loftus  &  Zanni,  Eyewitness  Testimony:  The  Influence  of  the  Wording  of  a 
Question,  5  Bull.  Psychonomic  Soc.  86  (1975). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  909 

but  many  potential  jurors  fail  to  recognize  the  distinction. ^°  (2)  Testimony 
given  with  an  air  of  certainty  is  treated  by  the  courts  as  accurate,^'  but 
studies  do  not  support  such  an  assumption. ^^  (3)  Courts  do  not  appear 
to  realize  how  quickly  one  forgets  what  has  occurred  and  how  complicated 
the  process  of  forgetting  is."  (4)  Judges  who  believe  that  the  mind 
retains  more  readily  the  memory  of  an  unusual,  startling,  or  stressful 
scene  than  it  does  the  impression  of  an  ordinary  occurrence  are  in  error 
if  they  think  that  memory  works  by  simply  passively  recording,  rather 
than  actively  reconstructing,  events.^"*  The  human  memory  is  not  a 
smoothly  operating  mechanical  device,  **Uke  a  videotape  recorder. "^^  In 
the  pages  that  follow,  this  article  will  deal  with  the  results  of  experiments 
illustrating  these  and  other  misconceptions. 

A.     Power  of  Suggestion 

Exposure  to  new  and  false  information  about  an  event  through 
means  of  questions  containing  presuppositions  can  supplements^  or  even 
transforms"^  memory.  "Memory,  it  appears,  is  extremely  fragile  and  can 
be  supplemented,  altered,  or  even  restructured  by  as  simple  an  instrument 
as  a  strong  verb,  embedded  unnoticed  in  a  question  about  the  event 
concerned. "S8  Experiments  show  that,  if  misleading  information  or 
suggestions  are  given  to  a  witness  a  week  or  more  after  the  event  and 
just  before  testing,  the  accuracy  of  the  witness'  memory  is  drastically 
reduced. S9  Subjects  tend  to  recall  the  erroneous  information,  80%  of 


30.  Yarmey  &  Jones,  Is  the  Psychology  of  Eyewitness  Identification  a  Matter  of 
Common  Sense?,  in  Lloyd-Bostock,  supra  note  22,  at  13,  29. 

31.  Gardner,  The  Perception  and  Memory  of  Witnesses,  18  Cornell  L.  Q.  391 
(1933). 

32.  See  infra  text  accompanying  notes  45-50. 

33.  Gardner,  supra  note  31;  Hutchins  &  Slesinger,  Some  Observations  on  the  Law 
of  Evidence-Memory,  41  Harv.  L.  Rev.  860  (1928). 

34.  U.  Neisser,  Cognitive  Psychology,  279-305  (1967). 

35.  Sanders,  Expert  Witnesses  in  Eyewitness  Facial  Identification  Cases,  17  Tex. 
Tech.  L.  Rev.  1409,  1427  n.62  (1986)  (quoting  testimony  by  Professor  Loftus  in  W.  Loh, 
SocL^  Research  in  the  Judicl\l  Process:  Cases,  Readings  and  Text  at  583  (1984)). 

36.  Loftus  &  Ketcham,  The  Malleability  of  Eyewitness  Accounts,  in  Lloyd-Bostock, 
supra  note  23,  at  159,  160-63. 

37.  Id.  at  163,  168-69;  see  also  Loftus,  Miller,  &  Burns,  Semantic  Integration  of 
Verbal  Information  into  a  Visual  Memory,  4  J.  Exp.  Psychology:  Hum.  Learning  & 
Memory  19,  29  (1978). 

38.  Loftus  &  Ketcham,  supra  note  36,  at  159.  See  also  Loftus,  Miller  &  Burns, 
supra  note  36,  at  160  (citing  Loftus  &  Palmer,  Reconstruction  of  Automobile  Destruction: 
An  Example  of  the  Interaction  Between  Language  and  Memory,  13  J.  Verbal  Learning 
&  Verbal  Behav.  585  (1974)). 

39.  Loftus,  Miller,  &  Burns,  supra  note  36,  at  163. 


910  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

them  performing  incorrectly  when  tested .'^^  Memory  for  faces,  like  other 
memory,  is  affected  by  later  misleading  information/*  Such  studies 
suggest  that  in  criminal  cases,  when  expected  testimony  is  being  reviewed 
(typically  long  after  a  crime  has  been  committed  and  immediately  before 
trial),  witnesses  are  extremely  vulnerable  to  inadvertent  or  intentional 
suggestion  by  prosecutors. 

The  Wade  opinion  stressed  that  eyewitness  accuracy  can  be  adversely 
affected  not  only  by  the  purposeful  scheming  of  police  investigators  but 
also  by  suggestions  given  unintentionally:  *'We  do  not  assume  that  these 
risks  are  the  result  of  police  procedures  intentionally  designed  to  prejudice 
an  accused.  Rather  we  assume  they  derive  from  the  dangers  inherent  in 
eyewitness  identification  and  the  suggestibility  inherent  in  the  context  of 
the  pretrial  identification."'*^  The  studies  suggest  that  courts  have  over- 
simplified the  issue  of  Hneup  fairness  and  accuracy.  Instead  of  being  a 
passive  viewer,  '*the  victim  or  witness  at  a  lineup  is  one  'actor'  in  a 
complex  social  situation.""*^ 

B.     Confidence 

The  most  revealing  findings  that  Professors  Wells  and  Lindsay  drew 
from  a  series  of  experiments  which  they  and  others  performed  over 
several  years  were  that  a  person's  tendency  to  believe  an  eyewitness's 
testimony  is  strongly  related  to  the  confidence  of  the  witness  in  his 
identification,  as  one  would  expect,  but  that,  contrary  to  what  most 
people  ''intuitively  believe, ""^^  the  confidence  of  an  eyewitness  is  prac- 
tically worthless  as  a  cue  to  the  witness's  accuracy."*^  The  latter  finding 
directly  contradicts  the  Supreme  Court's  notion  that  the  degree  of  con- 


40.  Id. 

41.  Id.  at  167  (citing  Loftus  &  Greene,  Warning:  Even  Memory  for  Faces  May 
be  Contagious,  4  Law  &  Hum.  Behav.  323  (1980).  Recognition  of  voices  will  almost 
always  be  less  reliable  than  memory  for  faces.  Clifford,  Memory  for  Voices:  The  Feasibility 
and  Quality  of  Earwitness  Evidence,  in  Lloyd-Bostock,  supra  note  22,  at  189. 

42.  United  States  v.  Wade,  388  U.S.  218,  235  (1967). 

43.  Levine  &  Tapp,  supra  note  25,  at  1110. 

44.  Wells  &  Murray,  Eyewitness  Confidence,  in  Perspectives,  supra  note  27,  at 
159  (citing  Brigham  &  Wolfskiel,  Opinions  of  Attorneys  and  Law  Enforcement  Personnel 
on  the  Accuracy  of  Eyewitness  Identifications  (unpublished  manuscript,  1982);  Deffenbacher 

6  Loftus,  Do  Jurors  Share  a  Common  Understanding  Concerning  Eyewitness  Behavior?, 

7  Law  &  Hum.  Behav.  15  (1982);  Rahaim  &  Brodsky,  Empirical  Evidence  vs.  Common 
Sense:  Juror  and  Lawyer  Knowledge  of  Eyewitness  Accuracy  (unpublished  manuscript, 
1981);  Wells,  Lindsay,  &  Ferguson,  Accuracy,  Confidence,  and  Juror  Perceptions  in 
Eyewitness  Identification,  64  J.  Applied  Psychology  440  (1979));  Yarmey  &  Jones,  supra 
note  30. 

45.  Wells  &  Lindsay,  supra  note  26,  at  51;  Wells  &  Murray,  supra  note  40,  at 
163  ("No  applicable  value"  adheres  to  knowledge  of  eyewitness  confidence). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  911 

fidence  the  witness  shows  in  his  identification  is  an  important  factor  to 
consider  when  deciding  whether  the  identification  is  rehable.'*^  Never- 
theless, the  expression  of  confidence  or  certainty  on  the  part  of  an 
eyewitness  greatly  affects  how  jurors  gauge  the  accuracy  of  the  witness's 
identification/^  In  one  study  of  mock  jury  deliberations  following  a 
reenactment  of  a  trial,  some  jurors  spontaneously  pointed  to  the  con- 
fidence of  an  eyewitness  as  an  indicator  of  the  witness's  accuracy/^ 

Jurors  and  trial  judges  have  no  way  of  learning  that  a  confident 
witness  can  be  wrong.  If,  despite  a  confident  eyewitness,  the  defendant 
has  a  truly  solid  alibi,  the  government  typically  has  the  case  dismissed. 
In  this  and  other  ways,  jurors  and  judges  are  * 'neatly  protected  from 
learning  that  the  confidence  of  an  eyewitness  bears  no  useful  relationship 
to  the  accuracy  of  an  eyewitness."'*^  In  light  of  the  experimental  studies, 
the  common  but  erroneous  notion  that  there  is  a  close  relationship 
between  the  certainty  of  a  witness  and  the  accuracy  of  the  identification 
should  be  expunged  from  our  jurisprudence.^^ 

C.     Passage  of  Time 

The  passage  of  weeks  or  months  may  greatly  reduce  the  accuracy 
of  the  identification.^*  In  one  study,  the  rate  of  false  identification  of 
supposed  armed  robbers  increased  from  48%  at  2  days,  to  62 <%  at  21 
days,  and  to  93%  at  56  days.^^  Yet  some  jurors  think  that  an  eyewitness's 


46.  See,  e.g.,  Manson  v.  Brathwaite,  432  U.S.  98  (1977)  (confidence  of  witness  a 
key  factor);  Neil  v.  Biggers,  409  U.S.  188  (1972). 

47.  Wells  &  Murray,  supra  note  44,  at  155  (citing  Wells,  Ferguson,  &  Lindsay, 
The  Tract  ability  of  Eyewitness  Confidence  and  Its  Implications  for  Triers  of  Fact,  66  J. 
Applied  Psychology  688  (1981));  Wells,  Lindsay,  &  Ferguson,  supra  note  44. 

48.  Wells,  How  Adequate  is  Human  Intuition  for  Judging  Eyewitness  Testimony?, 
in  Perspectives,  supra  note  27,  at  256,  266  (citing  Hastie,  From  Eyewitness  Testimony 
to  Beyond  Reasonable  Doubt  (unpublished  manuscript,  1980)). 

49.  Wells  &  Murray,  supra  note  44,  at  169. 

50.  Deffenbacher,  Eyewitness  Accuracy  and  Confidence:  Can  We  Infer  Anything 
About  Their  Relationship?,  4  Law  &  Hum  Behav.  243  (1980);  Wells  &  Murray,  supra 
note  44  (citing  Leippe,  Effects  of  Integrative  Memorial  and  Cognitive  Processes  on  the 
Correspondence  of  Eyewitness  Accuracy  and  Confidence,  4  Law  &  Hum.  Behav.  261 
(1980)). 

51.  Shepherd,  Identification  After  Long  Delays,  in  Lloyd-Bostock,  supra  note  23, 
at  173. 

52.  Egan,  Pittner  &  Goldstein,  Eyewitness  Identification:  Photographs  vs.  Live 
Models,  1  Law  and  Hum,  Behav.  199  (1977).  Accord,  Malpass  &  Devine,  Eyewitness 
Identification:  Line  Up  Instructions  and  the  Absence  of  the  Offender,  66  J.  Applied 
Psychology  482  (1981);  Malpass  &  Devine,  Guided  Memory  in  Eyewitness  Identification, 
66  J.  Applied  Psychology  343  (1981). 


912  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

memory  remains  accurate  over  long  periods, ^^  and  others  believe  that 
accuracy  may  increase  as  time  passes. ^^ 

D.     Stress 

One  classic  work  described  twenty-nine  convictions  of  innocent  per- 
sons, each  conviction  resulting  from  the  positive  identification  of  the 
accused  by  the  victim  of  a  violent  crime."  One  explanation  for  such 
mistakes  is  that,  because  of  the  extreme  psychological  and  emotional 
arousal  caused  by  an  armed  robbery,  the  victim/witness  of  a  violent 
crime  may  block  out  stimuli  or  focus  on  the  weapon,  rather  than  on 
the  face  of  the  culprit. ^^  Tests  involving  potential  jurors  in  Canada  and 
the  United  States  indicated  that  they  had  some  knowledge  of  the  '* weapon 
focus  problem,"  but  their  responses  also  suggested  that  they  believed 
inaccurate  explanations  of  the  phenomenon. ^^ 

Contrary  to  common-sense  beUefs  about  the  accuracy  of  eyewitnesses 
to  violent  crimes,  "there  is  no  empirical  support  for  the  notion  that 
relatively  high  levels  of  arousal  facilitate  eyewitness  testimony.  "^^  Jurors, 
however,  have  expressed  the  erroneous  opinion  that  stress  enhances  the 
accuracy  of  an  eyewitness. ^^  Lay  persons  apparently  widely  hold  such 
beliefs,  unaware  of  studies  demonstrating  that  the  anxiety  that  witnesses 
feel,  when  they  think  that  their  identification  will  have  serious  results, 
serves  to  destroy  any  accuracy-confidence  relationship. ^° 

E.     Overbelief 

Police  officers,  judges,  and  jurors  often  overestimate  the  accuracy 
of  persons  who  claim  to  have  made  eyewitness  identifications.^'  **Ov- 
erbehef"  of  eyewitnesses  by  judges  and  jurors  is  a  well-recognized  prob- 


53.  Wells,  supra  note  48,  at  259  (15Vo  erroneously  thought  eyewitness's  memory 
for  faces  would  be  90-95 <7o  accurate  several  months  after  first  seeing  the  face). 

54.  Hastie,  supra  note  48. 

55.  E.  BoRCHARD,  Convicting  the  Innocent  (1932)  (describing  total  of  sixty-five 
wrong  convictions).  See  also  Cunningham  &  Tyrrell,  Eyewitness  Credibility:  Adjusting  the 
Sights  of  the  Judiciary,  37  Ala.  Law.  563,  564-65  n.2  &  n.4  (1976)  (citing  other  sources 
and  examples). 

56.  E.  Loftus,  Eyewitness  Testimony  §  2.15  (1987). 

57.  Yarmey  &  Jones,  supra  note  30,  at  21. 

58.  Deffenbacher,  The  Influence  of  Arousal  on  Reliability  of  Testimony,  in  Lloyd- 
BosTOCK,  supra  note  23,  at  247. 

59.  Hastie,  supra  note  48. 

60.  Wells  &  Murray,  supra  note  44, 

61 .  See  Cunningham  &  Tyrrell,  supra  note  55  at  575-85;  K.  Ellison  &  R.  Buckhout, 
Psychology  and  Criminal  Justice  80-82  (1981);  Wells,  Lindsay,  &  Ferguson,  supra  note 
44,  at  441-45  (1979). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  913 

lem,  established  by  many  researchers.^^  ''[M]ost  of  us  do  not  have 
experience  in  trying  to  remember  faces  in  very  stressful  situations  such 
as  being  a  robbery  victim.'*"  Likewise,  jurors  have  no  experience  in 
trying  to  judge  the  accuracy  of  another's  identification.^  Nevertheless, 
*  Visual  identification  of  the  defendant  by  the  victim  or  the  witness  often 
provides  the  most  persuasive  evidence,  which  cannot  be  overcome  by 
contrary  evidence  supporting  the  accused. "^^  Even  after  it  has  been 
proven  false,  eyewitness  testimony  can  continue  to  persuade  a  jury.^ 

The  question  of  how  adequately  the  juror  can  assess  the  credibiHty 
of  eyewitness  testimony  is  an  important  one  since  it  is  the  juror 
or  some  other  intuitive  trier-of-fact  who  runs  the  risk  of  the 
ultimate  error,  namely  believing  an  inaccurate  eyewitness  account 
or  disbelieving  an  accurate  eyewitness  account.  Does  the  lay 
person  understand  the  problems  of  eyewitness  memory?  Many 
judges  seem  to  think  so  as  it  is  common  for  expert  testimony 
on  eyewitness  matters  to  be  prohibited  by  a  judge  on  grounds 
that  the  problem  of  eyewitness  memory  is  something  that  is 
intuitively  appreciated  by  the  jurors.  Data  .  .  .  call  this  as- 
sumption into  question. ^^ 

The  great  degree  of  trust  that  police,  jurors,  and  judges  place  in  hneups 
and  eyewitnesses  is  not  supported  by  the  psychological  experiments  on 
the  subject.^^ 

F.    Police  Officers  as  Witnesses 

In  a  pair  of  studies  two-thirds  of  the  lay  persons, ^^  as  well  as  most 
of  the  legal  professionals  and  law  students, ''^  thought  that  police  officers 


62.  See  Lindsay,  Wells  &  Rumpel,  Can  People  Detect  Eyewitness-Identification 
Accuracy  Within  and  Across  Situations?,  66  J.  Applied  Psychology  79,  83-85  (1981); 
Deffenbacher,  supra  note  50,  at  250-52;  Yarmey  &  Jones,  supra  note  30,  at  13. 

63.  Sanders,  supra  note  35,  at  1439. 

64.  Id.  at  1440  (citing  Saks  &  Kidd,  Human  Information  Processing  and  Adju- 
dication: Trial  by  Hueristics,  15  Law  &  Soc'y  Rev.  123,  126-27  (1980-81)). 

65.  Note,  Did  Your  Eyes  Deceive  You?  Expert  Psychological  Testimony  on  the 
Unreliability  of  Eyewitness  Identification,  29  Stan.  L.  Rev.  969,  970  (1977). 

66.  Loftus  &  Ketcham,  supra  note  36,  at  170,  (citing  Cavoukian,  Eyewitness 
Testimony:  The  Ineffectiveness  of  Discrediting  Information  (paper  presented  at  the  Amer. 
Psychological  Assoc,  annual  meeting,  1980)). 

67.  Wells  «&  Lindsay,  supra  note  26,  at  41. 

68.  A.  Yarmey,  supra  note  21,  at  159  (citing  Goldstein,  The  Fallibility  of  the 
Eyewitness:  Psychological  Evidence,  in  Psychology  in  the  Legal  Process  (B.  Sales  ed. 
1977)). 

69.  Wells,  supra  note  48  (citing  Tickner  &  Poulton,  Watching  for  People  Actions, 
18  Ergonomics  35  (1975)). 

70.  Yarmey  &  Jones,  supra  note  30. 


914  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

make  better  eyewitnesses  than  lay  persons.  Most  officers  themselves 
believe  that  their  training  and  experience  make  them  superior  at  observing 
and  remembering  details,  but  the  psychological  studies  fail  to  confirm 
their  assumptions.^'  To  the  contrary,  "experiments  suggest  that  policemen 
are  more  prone  to  committing  interpretive  errors  in  their  perceptions  of 
people  and  activities. "^^ 

G.    Race 

The  usual  difficulties  inherent  in  eyewitness  identification  may  be 
compounded  when  race  becomes  a  f actor. ^^  Several  reviews  of  the  lit- 
erature on  eyewitnesses  have  concluded  that  cross-race  identifications  are 
less  reliable  than  when  the  witness  and  suspect  are  members  of  the  same 
race.^"*  In  a  well-known  study, ^^  subjects  viewed  a  picture  of  a  white 
man  holding  a  razor  while  arguing  with  a  black  man.  Half  of  the 
observers  later  remembered  the  black  man  as  holding  the  razor.  Some 
said  he  was  brandishing  it  wildly,  and  others  remembered  him  as  threat- 
ening the  white  man. 

At  least  ten  studies  demonstrate  that  white  Americans  are  significantly 
less  able  to  recognize  black  faces  than  they  are  white  faces.^^  The  cross- 
race  phenomenon  may  not  be  Hmited  to  white  observers.  Four  studies 
have  indicated  that  American  black  observers  are  significantly  less  able 
to  recognize  white  faces  than  black  ones.^^  Similar  results  have  been 


71.  A,  Yarmey,  supra  note  21  (citing  Clifford,  Police  As  Eyewitness y  22  New 
Sec.  176  (1976)). 

72.  Id.  (citing  Verinis  &  Walker,  Policemen  and  the  Recall  of  Criminal  Details, 
81  J.  OF  Soc.  Psychology  217  (1970)). 

73.  Luce,  Blacks,  Whites,  and  Yellows:  They  All  Look  Alike  to  Me,  Psychology 
Today  105  (Nov.  1974);  Galper,  'Functional  Race  Membership'  and  Recognition  of  Faces, 
37  Perceptual  &  Motor  Skills  455  (1973). 

74.  E.  LoFTUS,  supra  note  66,  at  §  4.11;  A.  Yarmey,  supra  note  20,  at  130-31; 
B.  Clifford  &  R.  Bull,  The  Psychology  of  Person  Identification  (1978);  Wells,  Applied 
Eyewitness-Testimony  Research:  System  Variables  and  Estimator  Variables,  36  J.  Per- 
sonality &  Soc.  Psychology  1545  (1978);  Ellis,  Recognizing  Faces,  66  Brit.  J.  Psychology 
409  (1975).  But  cf  Lindsay  &  Wells,  What  do  We  Really  Know  About  Cross-Race 
Eyewitness  Identification?,  in  Lloyd-Bostock,  supra  note  23  (arguing  that  such  conclusion 
is  premature). 

75.  K.  Ellison  and  R.  Buckhout,  Psychology  and  Criminal  Justice  101  (1981) 
(citing  Allport  &  Postman,  The  Basic  Psychology  of  Rumor,  8  Trans.  N.Y.  Acad,  of 
Sci.,  Series  11,  147-49  (1945)). 

76.  Johnson,  Cross-Racial  Identification  Errors  in  Criminal  Cases,  69  Cornell  L. 
Rev.  934,  938-39  n.l8  (1984)  (citing  studies). 

77.  Johnson,  supra  note  76,  at  939  n.23,  938-39  n.l8  (citing  Brigham  &  Williamson, 
Cross-Racial  Recognition  and  Age:  When  You're  Over  60,  Do  They  Still  "All  Look 
Alike?",  5  Personality  &  Soc.  Psychology  Bull.  218  (1979);  Galper,  supra  note  73; 
Luce,  The  Role  of  Experience  in  Inter-Racial  Recognition,  1  Personality  &  Soc.  Psy- 
chology Bull.  39  (1974);  Malpass,  Lavigneur,  &  Weldon,  Verbal  and  Visual  Training  in 
Face  Recognition,  14  Perception  &  Psychophysics  285  (1973)). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  915 

obtained  with  African  blacks  viewing  African  and  European  faces.^^ 
Results  have  not  been  uniform,  however,  as  four  studies  failed  to  show 
significant  differences  in  accuracy  for  black  observers  of  white  versus 
black  faces.^^ 

Such  experiments  suggest  that  ''the  differential  recognition  of  black 
faces  by  white  and  black  observers  is  a  highly  probable  event,  and  more 
likely  to  result  in  error  if  the  observer  is  white. "^^  At  present,  however, 
the  studies  do  not  establish  whether  or  to  what  extent  jurors  believe 
cross-race  identifications.^* 

H.     Other  Physical  Characteristics 

Characteristics  other  than  race  may  affect  attitudes  of  observers. 
Two  studies  have  indicated  that,  upon  conviction  for  a  crime,  an  un- 
attractive person  is  likely  to  receive  a  longer  prison  sentence  than  an 
attractive  person  receives.*^  Men  with  dark  complexions  are  more  likely 
to  be  suspected  as  villains, ^^  to  be  regarded  as  dishonest  or  hostile.^"* 

/.     Other  Misconceptions 

Research  has  exposed  other  misconceptions  about  eyewitness  testi- 
mony.^^ The  opportunity  the  witness  had  to  view  the  criminal  is  considered 


78.  Shepherd,  Deregowski,  &  ElUs,  A  Cross-Cultural  Study  of  Recognition  Memory 
for  Faces,  9  Int'l  J.  Psychology  205  (1974). 

79.  Johnson,  supra  note  76,  at  938-39  n.l8  (citing  Barkowitz  &  Brigham,  Recognition 
of  Faces:  Own  Race  Bias,  Incentive,  and  Time  Delay,  12  J.  Applied  Soc.  Psychology 
255  (1982);  Cross,  Cross,  &  Daly,  Sex,  Race,  Age,  and  Beauty  as  Factors  in  Recognition 
of  Faces,  10  Perception  &  Psychophysics  393  (1971);  Malpass  &  Kravitz,  Recognition 
for  Faces  of  Own  and  Other  Race,  13  J.  Personality  &  Soc.  Psychology  330  (1969); 
Chance,  Goldstein,  and  McBride,  Differential  Experience  and  Recognition  Memory  for 
Faces,  97  J.  Soc.  Psychology  243  (1975)). 

80.  A.  Yarmey,  supra  note  21,  at  130  (citing  Malpass,  Racial  Bias  in  Eyewitness 
Identification,  1  Personality  &  Soc.  Psychology  42-44  (1974)). 

81.  Sanders,  supra  note  35,  at  1454  n.l64  (citing  Lindsay  &  Wells,  supra  note  74). 
See  also  Brigham  &  Barkowitz,  Do  'They  All  Look  Alike'?  The  Effect  of  Race,  Sex, 
Experience  and  Attitudes  on  the  Ability  to  Recognize  Faces,  8  J.  Applied  Soc.  Psychology 
306  (1978). 

82.  A.  Yarmey,  supra  note  21  (citing  Landy  &  Aronson,  The  Influence  of  the 
Character  of  the  Criminal  and  His  Victim  on  the  Decisions  of  Simulated  Jurors,  5  J. 
Experimental  Soc.  Psychology  141  (1969);  Efran,  The  Effect  of  Physical  Appearance 
on  the  Judgment  of  Guilt,  Interpersonal  Attraction,  and  Severity  of  Recommended  Pun- 
ishment in  a  Simulated  Jury  Task,  8  J,  of  Res.  in  Personality  45  (1974)). 

83.  A.  Yarmey,  supra  note  21  (citing  Berelson  &  Salter,  Majority  and  Minority 
Americans:  An  Analysis  of  Magazine  Fiction,  10  Pub.  Opinion  Q.  168  (1946)). 

84.  A.  Yarmey,  supra  note  21  (citing  Secord,  The  Role  of  Facial  Features  in 
Interpersonal  Perception,  in  Person  Perception  and  Interpersonal  Behavior  3(X)  (R. 
Tagiuri  &  L.  PetruUo  eds.  1958)). 

85.  See  generally  Perspectives,  supra  note  27  (citing  other  studies). 


916  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

by  courts  to  be  an  important  factor  in  judging  the  accuracy  of  an 
identification.^^  Yet,  two-thirds  of  the  persons  studied  were  not  aware 
that  an  eyewitness  is  prone  to  overestimate  the  time  involved  in  a  crime 
sequence.^''  Such  overestimation  of  time  should  undermine  judicial  con- 
fidence in  the  witness's  depiction  of  the  opportunity  he  had  to  view  the 
crime  and,  in  turn,  reduce  the  value  of  * 'opportunity  to  view''  as  a 
factor  in  judging  eyewitness  reliability. 

A  witness's  identification  of  a  person's  face  in  a  photographic  array 
is  likely  to  produce  an  identification  of  the  same  person  in  a  lineup, 
even  if  the  suspect  is  not  guilty,^^  but  many  people  appear  not  to  know 
that.^^  Some  jurors  seem  to  believe  that  photographic  identifications 
increase  the  accuracy  of  later  lineup  identifications. ^° 

The  consequences  of  mistaken  identification  are  most  harmful  in 
cases  in  which  the  conviction  rested  heavily  on  the  eyewitness  identifi- 
cation. The  danger  of  erroneous  identification  is  made  even  more  acute 
in  cases  like  Wade^^  and  Foster, ^^  in  which  the  perpetrators  were  disguised, 
however  clumsily,  and  the  lineup  participants  were  asked  to  don  similar 
disguises.  As  indicated  by  the  research  conducted  in  the  United  States, 
as  well  as  abroad,  ^^  since  the  Wade  and  Kir  by  decisions,  such  an  iden- 
tification procedure  presents  many  possibilities  for  intentional  or  inad- 
vertent suggestion  and  for  misidentification.^"*  In  general  '*[i]t  may  be 
concluded  on  the  basis  of  experimental  evidence  that  mistaken  identity 
from  lineups  is  often  the  rule  and  not  the  exception. "^^ 


86.  Neil  V.  Biggers,  409  U.S.   188  (1972). 

87.  Wells,  supra  note  48,  at  259  (citing  Shiffman  &  Bobko,  Effects  of  Stimulus 
Complexity  on  Brief  Temporal  Events,  103  J.  Exp,  Psychology  156  (1974)). 

88.  Brown,  Deffenbacher,  &  Sturgill,  Memory  for  Faces  and  the  Circumstances  of 
Encounter,  62  J.  Applied  Psychology  311  (1977). 

89.  Yarmey  &  Jones,  supra  note  30,  at  22;  Wells,  supra  note  48,  at  259  (citing 
Gorenstein  &  Ellsworth,  Effect  of  Choosing  an  Incorrect  Photograph  on  a  Later  Iden- 
tification by  an  Eyewitness,  65  J.  Applied  Psychology  616  (1980)). 

90.  Hastie,  supra  note  48. 

91.  United  States  v.  Wade,  388  U.S.  218  (1967). 

92.  Foster  v.  State,  713  S.W.2d  789  (Tex.  Ct.  App.  (1986)). 

93.  Shepherd,  supra  note  51,  at  173  ("the  fallibility  of  eyewitnesses  has  been 
acknowledged  for  many  years  by  legal  authorities  both  in  the  UK  and  in  the  USA")  See 
also  Watson,  The  Trlal  of  Adolf  Beck  (1924)  (citing  1904  English  committee  of  inquiry 
as  observing  that  "evidence  as  to  identity  based  on  personal  impressions,  however  bona 
fide,  is  perhaps  of  all  classes  of  evidence  the  least  to  be  relied  upon,  and  therefore,  unless 
supported  by  other  facts,  an  unsafe  basis  for  the  verdict  of  a  jury");  P.  Devlin,  Report 
to  the  Secretary  of  State  for  the  Home  Department  of  the  Departmental  Committee  on 
Evidence  of  Identification  in  Criminal  Cases  (1976);  B.  Clifford  &  R.  Bull,  The  Psy- 
chology OF  Person  Identification  (1978). 

94.  E.  LoFTUS,  supra  note  66. 

95.  A.  Yarmey,  supra  note  21,  at  159.  Accord,  Frankfurter,  The  Case  of  Sacco 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  917 

III.    Aberrant  Nature  of  Kirby 

As  noted  above,  in  United  States  v.  Wade^^  the  United  States  Supreme 
Court  first  recognized  a  sixth  amendment  right  to  council  at  a  lineup. 
Two  bank  employees  identified  Wade  in  a  lineup  conducted  after  in- 
dictment but  before  trial.  At  trial  they  again  pointed  out  Wade.  On 
cross-examination,  in  an  attempt  to  counter  the  in-court  identification, 
defense  counsel  asked  the  witnesses  about  the  pretrial  lineup.  Wade's 
counsel  unsuccessfully  asked  the  trial  judge  to  strike  the  courtroom 
identifications  on  the  ground  that  the  lineup  without  counsel  violated 
the  defendant's  sixth  amendment  right. ^^ 

The  court  of  appeals  reversed  the  conviction  and  ordered  a  new 
trial  at  which  the  in-court  identification  was  to  be  excluded. ^^  The 
Supreme  Court  granted  review  and  agreed  that  Wade  had  a  sixth  amend- 
ment right  to  the  presence  of  counsel  at  the  Uneup.^^  The  Court  realized 
that  criminal  procedure  had  changed  dramatically  since  the  adoption  of 
the  federal  Bill  of  Rights.  A  pretrial  confession  or  lineup  can  "settle 
the  accused's  fate  and  reduce  the  trial  itself  to  a  mere  formality."'^ 

Recognizing  that  the  sixth  amendment  spoke  of  the  right  of  the 
accused  to  the  '*[a]ssistance  of  counsel  for  his  defence,''^^^  the  Court 
regarded  the  plain  meaning  of  the  provision  as  guaranteeing  the  right 
to  counsel  * 'whenever  necessary  to  assure  a  meaningful  'defence.'  "^°^ 
Continuing  in  that  vein,  the  Court  emphasized  that  a  central  meaning 
of  the  right  to  counsel  is  that  an  accused  "need  not  stand  alone  against 
the  State  at  any  stage  of  the  prosecution,  formal  or  informal,  in  court 
or  out,  where  counsel's  absence  might  derogate  from  the  accused's  right 
to  a  fair  trial. "^^^  The  Wade  Court  saw  the  accused's  right  to  a  fair 
trial  "as  affected  by  his  right  meaningfully  to  cross-examine  the  witnesses 


AND  Vanzetti  30  (1927)  ("The  identification  of  strangers  is  proverbially  untrustworthy"); 
Frank  &  Frank,  Not  Guilty  61  (1957)  ("[P]erhaps  erroneous  identification  of  the  accused 
constitutes  the  major  cause  of  the  known  wrongful  convictions"). 

96.  388  U.S.  218  (1967). 

97.  Id.  at  220.  Wade  also  made  a  fifth  amendment  self-incrimination  claim,  but 
a  majority  of  the  Supreme  Court  rejected  it. 

98.  United  States  v.  Wade,  358  F.2d  557  (5th  Cir.   1966). 

99.  The  Supreme  Court  held,  however,  that  the  violation  of  the  right  to  counsel 
at  the  lineup  did  not  make  the  in-court  identification  automatically  inadmissible.  On 
remand  the  trial  court  was  to  determine  whether  (1)  the  in-court  identification  was 
independent  of  the  tainted  lineup  or  whether,  in  any  event,  (2)  the  admission  of  the  in- 
court  identification  was  harmless  error.  388  U.S.  at  242. 

100.  388  U.S.  at  224. 

101.  Id.  Bi  225  (quoting  the  sixth  amendment)  (emphasis  by  the  Court). 

102.  Id. 

103.  Id.  at  226. 


918  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

against  him  and  to  have  effective  assistance  of  counsel  at  the  trial 
itself.  "'^^ 

In  analyzing  the  dangers  inherent  in  pretrial  identifications,  the 
Supreme  Court  in  Wade  cited  considerable  authority  for  the  proposition 
that  "the  annals  of  criminal  law  are  rife  with  instances  of  mistaken 
identification. "^°^  The  Court  observed  that,  once  the  witness  has  com- 
mitted himself  to  an  identification,  he  is  unlikely  to  change  his  mind.^^^ 
Because  the  defense  lawyer  is  not  present  at  the  lineup,  counsel  cannot 
reconstruct  the  lineup  at  trial.  That  is  true  because  neither  witnesses  nor 
lineup  participants,  including  the  suspect,  are  likely  to  be  aware  of 
prejudicial  conditions  surrounding  the  lineup. '^"^  The  resulting  'Mnability 
to  effectively  reconstruct  at  trial  any  unfairness  that  occurred  at  the 
lineup  may  deprive  [the  accused]  of  his  only  opportunity  meaningfully 
to  attack  the  credibility  of  the  witness'  courtroom  identification.  "'°^ 
Thus,  the  Court  in  Wade  saw  the  presence  of  counsel  at  a  pretrial  lineup 
as  essential  to  insure  the  right  to  a  fair  trial,  the  right  to  meaningful 
cross-examination  at  trial,  and  the  right  to  effective  assistance  of  counsel 
at  trial. 

A.    Kirby  As  a  Break  from  Wade 

Only  five  years  after  Wade,  however,  in  Kirby  v.  Illinois, ^^  a  plurality 
reinterpreted  the  Wade  opinion,  basing  its  decision  on  the  literal  wording 
of  the  sixth  amendment.  The  police  arrested  Kirby  for  a  robbery,  and 
they  took  him  to  the  police  station.  The  victim  entered  the  station  and 
identified  Kirby,  who  was  seated  at  a  table. '^°  At  trial  the  victim  described 
the  station  confrontation  and  again  identified  Kirby.  The  Court  declined 
to  apply  Wade  to  a  pre-indictment  identification. ''' 

The  plurality  in  Kirby  read  the  sixth  amendment  right  to  counsel 
recognized  in  Wade  as  being  limited  to  postindictment  Hneups,  because 


104.  Id.  at  227. 

105.  Id.  at  228  (citing  E.  Borchard,  supra  note  55;  Frank  &  Frank,  supra  note 
95;  and  other  authorities). 

106.  Id.  at  229  (quoting  WiUiams  &  Hammelman,  Identification  Parades,  Part  I, 
Crim.  L.  Rev.  479,  482  (1963)). 

107.  Id.  at  230. 

108.  Id.  at  232. 

109.  406  U.S.  682  (1972). 

110.  Such  one-on-one  identification  proceedings  are  called  "showups"  and  generally 
are  disfavored  but  are  not  per  se  unconstitutional.  See  Neil  v,  Diggers,  409  U.S.  188 
(1972)  (showup  suggestive  but  identification  reliable). 

111.  Justice  Powell  supplied  the  crucial  fifth  vote  without  explanation  of  his  rationale, 
except  to  say  that  he  would  not  extend  Wade.  406  U.S.  at  691  (Powell,  J.,  concurring). 
The  Kirby  analysis  later  was  adopted  by  a  majority.  Brewer  v.  Williams,  430  U.S.  387 
(1977). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  919 

the  sixth  amendment  begins  with  the  words  "[i]n  all  criminal  prose- 
cutions."'^^ Taking  those  words  literally,  Justice  Stewart's  brief  and 
matter-of-fact  opinion  for  the  plurality  concluded  that  the  sixth  amend- 
ment's guarantee  of  the  right  to  counsel  applies  only  at  or  after  **the 
initiation  of  adversary  judicial  criminal  proceedings, "^'^  or  '*the  onset 
of  formal  prosecutorial  proceedings."*'"*  As  examples  of  such  starting 
points  for  a  "criminal  prosecution,"  the  plurality  opinion  Usted  "formal 
charge,  preliminary  hearing,  indictment,  information,  or  arraignment.'"'^ 

The  Kirby  plurality  attempted  to  distinguish  Wade  on  the  basis  of 
procedural  posture.  The  confrontation  in  Kirby  was  arranged  before  the 
commencement  of  formal  criminal  proceedings,  but  the  Hneup  in  Wade 
was  conducted  after  indictment.  Justice  Stewart,  while  declaring  that 
"[t]he  initiation  of  judicial  criminal  proceedings  is  far  from  a  mere 
formalism,""^  however,  gave  no  practical  reason  for  concluding  that 
the  sixth  amendment  did  not  require  counsel  at  Kirby' s  showup,  to 
protect  his  rights  later  at  trial,  but  did  require  counsel  at  Wade's  lineup, 
to  protect  those  same  trial  rights. 

In  direct  contradiction  to  the  Kirby  plurality,  Justice  Brennan,  the 
author  of  the  Wade  opinion,  denied  that  the  postindictment  wording  in 
Wade  was  anything  but  descriptive.  ''Wade  and  Gilbert, ^^'^  of  course, 
happened  to  involve  post-indictment  confrontations.  Yet  even  a  cursory 
perusal  of  the  opinions  in  those  cases  reveals  that  nothing  at  all  turned 
upon  that  particular  circumstance.""^  Brennan  further  noted  that  even 
the  dissenting  justices  in  Wade  read  his  opinion  in  that  case  as  extending 
to  pre-indictment  confrontations."^  For  example.  Justice  White,  dissenting 
in  Wade,  had  described  Brennan 's  opinion  for  the  majority  as 

[C]reating  a  new  per  se  rule  of  constitutional  law:  a  criminal 
suspect  cannot  be  subjected  to  a  pretrial  identification  process 
in  the  absence  of  his  counsel  without  violating  the  Sixth  Amend- 
ment. .  .  .  The  rule  appUes  to  any  lineup,  .  .  .  regardless  of 
when  the  identification  occurs,  in  time  or  place,  and  whether 
before  or  after  indictment  or  information.'^^ 

Brennan  also  observed  in  his  Kirby  dissent  that  several  state  and  federal 
courts  had  read  Wade  as  applying  to  pre-indictment  lineups. '2'  Academic 


112.  Id.  at  689-90. 

113.  Id.  at  689. 

114.  Id.  at  690. 

115.  Id.  at  689. 

116.  Id. 

117.  Gilbert  v.  California,  388  U.S.  263  (1967). 

118.  Kirby,  406  U.S.  at  704  (Brennan,  J.,  dissenting). 

119.  Id.  n.l3. 

120.  388  U.S.  at  250-51  (White,  J.,  dissenting  in  part  and  concurring  in  part). 

121.  406  U.S.  at  704  n.l4.  See  also  People  v.  Hawkins,  55  N.Y.2d  474,  490  n.3. 


920  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

commentators  had  done  the  same.'^^  Many  commentators  have  been 
"critical  of  the  Kirby  decision  and  have  sided  with  the  four  dissenters 
who  pointed  out  that  the  decision  did  not  square  with  the  rationale  of 
Wade.''^^^  Judicial  and  academic  comments  on  the  Kirby  opinion  have 
demonstrated  the  lack  of  logic  in  its  attempt  to  distinguish  the  holding 
in  Wade}^^  Perhaps  the  most  stinging  academic  criticism  of  the  Kirby 
decision  was  made  by  Professor  Grano,  who  thoroughly  demonstrated 
that  the  Kirby  decision  was  not  faithful  to  Wade,  which  Kirby  purported 
to  follow. ^^^  Grano  concluded  that  **the  plurality  opinion  in  Kirby  seems 
wrong  from  every  perspective.  The  opinion  misreads  precedent  so  badly 
that  it  appears  intellectually  dishonest. ''^^^  Other  critics  have  been  only 
slightly  more   kind  to  the  Kirby  opinion. '^^  The    Wade  majority 

understood  that,  when  an  eyewitness  identifies  a  suspect,  for  all  practical 
purposes  the  case  is  over.  Just  as  Escobedo  v.  Illinois^^^  and  Miranda 
V.  Arizona^^^  recognized  that  a  confession  made  to  a  poUce  officer  is 
an  event  that  really  terminates  the  accused's  chances  for  acquittal.  Wade 
made  it  clear  that  '*[t]he  trial  which  might  determine  the  accused's  fate 
may  well  not  be  that  in  the  courtroom  but  that  at  the  pretrial  con- 
frontation .  .  .  with  little  or  no  effective  appeal  from  the  judgment  there 
rendered  by  the  witness — 'that's  the  man.'  "'^°  The  witnesses  and  the 
suspect  are  not  likely  to  be  alert  to  the  presence  of  any  suggestiveness 
in  the  Uneup.  Unless  he  is  present  at  the  lineup,  defense  counsel  will 
find  it  impossible  to  reconstruct  the  conditions  by  means  of  questioning 
in  court.  The  inability  to  estabHsh  suggestiveness  through  questioning 


450  N.Y.S.2d  159,  167  n.3,  435  N.E.2d  376,  384  n.3  (1982)  (Meyer,  J.,  dissenting)  (''prior 
to  Kirby  a  substantial  majority  of  courts  had  applied  Wade  to  preindictment  identification 
proceedings  and  required  counsel  at  all  lineups.")  Id. 

122.  People  v.  Hawkins,  55  N.Y.2d  at  489  n.2,  450  N.Y.S.2d  at  167  n.2,  435 
N.E.2d  at  384  n.2  (1982). 

123.  W.  LaFave,  Criminal  Procedure  329  (1985). 

124.  Hawkins,  55  N.Y.2d  at  488,  450  N.Y.S.2d  166,  435  N.E.2d  383  (Meyer,  J., 
dissenting). 

125.  Grano,  Kirby,  Biggers,  and  Ash:  Do  Any  Constitutional  Safeguards  Remain 
Against  the  Danger  of  Convicting  the  Innocent?,  72  Mich.  L.  Rev.  717,  725-30  (1974), 

126.  Id.  at  730  {''Kirby  created  a  new,  and  previously  unsupported  limitation  on 
the  right  to  counsel."). 

127.  See,  e.g.,  R.  Young,  Supreme  Court  Report,  58  A.B.A.J.  1092  (1972)  ("perhaps 
the  least  defensible,  from  a  technical  point  of  view,  of  the  court's  criminal  law  holdings 
during  the  term");  Note,  Criminal  Law — The  Lineup's  Lament,  Kirby  v.  Illinois,  22  De 
Paul  L.  Rev.  660  (1972-73)  (exaltation  of  form  over  substance);  Woocher,  supra  note 
65,  at  996  ("removes  the  protective  effects  of  counsel's  presence  precisely  when  the  danger 
of  convicting  an  innocent  defendant  upon  a  mistaken  identification  is  greatest"). 

128.  378  U.S.  478  (1964). 

129.  384  U.S.  436  (1966). 

130.  388  U.S.  at  235-36. 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  921 

results  in  the  denial  of  effective  confrontation  of  the  witnesses  at  trial, 
denial  of  effective  assistance  of  counsel  at  trial,  and  denial  of  a  fair 
trial.  The  literal-language  approach  to  the  interpretation  of  the  sixth 
amendment  right  to  counsel,  highlighted  in  Kirby,^^^  ignores  the  practical 
difficulties  of  recreating  the  lineup  through  cross  examination,  as  well 
as  the  policies  that  the  counsel  guarantee  exists  to  serve. 

B.     Federal  * 'Literal  Language**  Rationale 

As  discussed  above,  in  Kirby,  the  Supreme  Court  employed  a  ''literal 
language,"  "explicit  wording,"  or  "plain  language"  approach  to  the 
interpretation  of  the  scope  of  the  sixth  amendment  right  to  counsel. 
The  opinion  relied  on  the  fact  that  the  sixth  amendment  begins  with 
the  phrase  "[i]n  all  criminal  prosecutions."  Interpreting  that  phrase,  the 
Kirby  plurality  announced  the  following  doctrine:  "The  initiation  of 
judicial  criminal  proceedings  is  far  from  a  mere  formalism.  ...  It  is 
this  point  .  .  .  that  marks  the  commencement  of  the  'criminal  prose- 
cutions' to  which  alone  the  expHcit  guarantees  of  the  Sixth  Amendment 
are  applicable.  "'^^ 

The  Kirby  opinion  thus  began  to  reinterpret  the  Wade  and  Gilbert^^^ 
decisions,  while  emphasizing  that  it  was  relying  on  the  explicit  wording 
of  the  sixth  amendment:  "The  rationale  of  those  cases  was  that  an 
accused  is  entitled  to  counsel  at  any  'critical  stage  of  iht  prosecution.'  "'^'^ 
The  opinion  of  Chief  Justice  Burger,  concurring  in  Kirby,  reiterated  the 
express- wording  rationale:  "I  agree  that  the  right  to  counsel  attaches  as 
soon  as  criminal  charges  are  formally  made  against  an  accused  and  he 
becomes  the  subject  of  a  'criminal  prosecution.'  "'^^ 

Thus,  it  can  be  seen  that  Kirby  articulated  and  relied  upon  a  literal 
reading  of  the  phrase  "criminal  prosecution"  as  restricting  the  scope  of 
the  Wade  sixth  amendment  right  to  counsel.  The  Kirby  plurality  took 
the  simplistic  explicit-wording  approach  over  the  objection  of  Justice 
Brennan,  the  author  of  Wade,  who  observed  in  dissent  as  follows: 

While  it  should  go  without  saying,  it  appears  necessary,  in  view 
of  the  plurality  opinion  today,  to  re-emphasize  that  Wade  did 
not  require  the  presence  of  counsel  at  pretrial  confrontations 


131.  Actually  Wade  also  relied  on  the  "plain  wording"  of  the  sixth  amendment 
when  stressing  that  the  provision  guarantees  "counsel's  assistance  whenever  necessary  to 
assure  a  meaningful  'defence.'"  Id.  at  225. 

132.  406  U.S.  at  689-90. 

133.  Gilbert  v.  CaUfornia,  388  U.S.  263  (1967). 

134.  406  U.S.  at  690  (emphasis  added  by  Justice  Stewart  for  Kirby  plurality)  (quoting 
Simmons  v.  United  States,  390  U.S.  377,  382-83  (1968)). 

135.  A/,  at  691  (Burger,  C.J.,  concurring). 


922  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

for  identification  purposes  simply  on  the  basis  of  an  abstract 
consideration  of  the  words  ''criminal  prosecutions"  in  the  Sixth 
Amendment.  ^^^ 

Only  much  later,  when  the  literal-language  approach  created  logical 
and  doctrinal  difficulties  regarding  the  other  rights  in  the  sixth  amend- 
ment, did  the  Court  begin  to  look  seriously  for  an  alternative  rational, 
examining  the  purposes  of  the  sixth  amendment  guarantees  as  clues  to 
their  scope.  Such  difficulties  appeared  in  United  States  v.  Gouveia,^^'' 
in  which  case  the  defendant  was  a  prisoner  at  a  federal  prison  when  a 
murder  of  another  prisoner  occurred.  Gouveia  was  placed  in  adminis- 
trative detention  for  a  considerable  period  before  he  was  indicted  for 
the  murder.  The  court  of  appeals  held  that  he  had  a  right  to  appointment 
of  an  attorney  during  administrative  detention  and  before  indictment. '^^ 
Noting  that  Kirby  did  not  involve  a  prison  context,  the  court  analogized 
to  the  sixth  amendment  speedy  trial  right. *^^  The  Ninth  Circuit  reasoned 
that,  if  an  arrest  starts  a  ''criminal  prosecution"  for  speedy  trial  cal- 
culations, then  administrative  detention  must  serve  the  same  purpose  for 
the  attachment  of  the  right  to  counsel  in  the  prison  context.'"*^  The  court 
of  appeals  held  that,  even  before  indictment,  an  administratively  detained 
prisoner  must  either  be  given  counsel  within  a  specified  period  or  be 
released  into  the  general  prison  population,  so  that  the  prisoner  or  the 
lawyer  can  conduct  the  pretrial  investigation  necessary  to  acquire  and 
preserve  evidence  for  presentation  of  a  defense  at  trial.  ^'^^ 

The  Supreme  Court  reversed  the  Ninth  Circuit,  holding  the  circuit 
court's  analogy  to  the  speedy  trial  right  to  be  inapt. '"^^  While  recognizing 
that  the  sixth  amendment  speedy  trial  right  attaches  at  the  time  of  arrest, 
the  Supreme  Court  in  Gouveia  reaffirmed  the  Kirby  analysis,  holding 
that  the  sixth  amendment  right  to  counsel  does  not  attach  until  adversarial 
judicial  proceedings  have  begun.  The  Court  reviewed  the  Kirby  line  of 
cases  and  pronounced  it  to  be  "consistent  not  only  with  the  literal 
language  of  the  Amendment,  which  requires  the  existence  of  both  a 
'criminal  prosecutio[n]'  and  an  'accused,'  but  also  with  the  purposes 
which  we  have  recognized  that  the  right  to  counsel  serves. "•'^^  The  Court 
also  reHed  again  on  the  "plain  language  of  the  Amendment  and  its 


purpose. 

"144 

136. 

Id.  at  696  (Brennan,  J.,  dissenting). 

137. 

467  U.S.  180  (1984). 

138. 

704  F.2d  1116  (9th  Cir.   1983). 

139. 

Id.  at  1120. 

140. 

Id.  at  1124. 

141. 

Id. 

142. 

United  States  v.  Gouveia,  467  U.S.  180  (1984) 

143. 

467  U.S.  at  188. 

144. 

Id.  at  189. 

1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  923 

While  reiterating  reliance  on  the  literal  language  or  plain  wording 
of  the  sixth  amendment,  the  Gouveia  Court  shifted  the  focus  to  the 
different  purposes  served  by  the  speedy  trial  right  and  the  counsel  right 
in  order  to  justify  the  difference  in  results  between  speedy-trial  cases 
and  right-to-counsel  cases. '"^^  The  Kirby  plurality  had  rested  its  opinion 
solely  on  the  first  few  words  of  the  sixth  amendment,  '*[i]n  all  criminal 
prosecutions.'''"^^  Justice  Stewart's  opinion  in  that  case  had  not  referred 
to  the  purposes  underlying  the  sixth  amendment  right  to  counsel. 

The  change  to  reliance  on  the  underlying  purposes  of  the  various 
guarantees  of  the  sixth  amendment  was  made  necessary  by  the  fact  that 
the  literal-language  rationale  of  Kirby,  if  applied  in  any  way  but  selectively 
and  arbitrarily  throughout  the  sixth  amendment,  would  be  destructive 
of  well-established  doctrine  regarding  the  right  to  a  speedy  trial.  Brennan, 
dissenting  in  Kirby,  had  pointed  out  that,  for  speedy-trial  doctrinal 
reasons,  the  phrase  "criminal  prosecutions"  in  the  sixth  amendment 
could  not  have  the  restrictive  effect  that  the  Kirby  plurality  proposed. '"^^ 
The  phrase  directly  applied  to  the  speedy  trial  right,  but  doctrine  regarding 
that  guarantee  held  that  the  speedy  trial  right  attached  at  the  time  of 
indictment  or  arrest,  whichever  came  first. '"^^  The  Kirby  plurality,  how- 
ever, chose  to  ignore  the  logical  and  doctrinal  problems  resulting  from 
its  plain-language  approach. 

In  Gouveia,  the  Court  had  to  face  these  shortcomings  of  Kirby  and 
address  them,  because  the  Ninth  Circuit  had  analogized  to  the  speedy 
trial  guarantee  of  the  sixth  amendment,  which,  like  the  right  to  counsel, 
is  preceded  by  the  words  *'[i]n  all  criminal  prosecutions."  However, 
rather  than  employing  sound  analysis  the  Court  resorted  to  sleight  of 
hand,  directing  attention  away  from  the  literal-language  rationale.  The 
Court  recognized  the  doctrine  that  the  right  to  a  speedy  trial  attaches 
at  the  time  of  arrest,  but  the  Court  announced  that  the  difference 
between  the  attachment  points  of  the  speedy  trial  right  and  the  right 
to  counsel  is  "readily  explainable  given  the  fact  that  the  speedy  trial 
right  and  the  right  to  counsel  protect  different  interests. "'"^^  The  former 
protects  a  "liberty  interest,"  while  the  latter  protects  the  accused  "during 
trial-type  confrontations  with  the  prosecutor. "'^^ 

What  the  Court  failed  to  recognize  is  that,  once  one  begins  to  rely 
on  the  purposes  underlying  the  several  guarantees  in  the  sixth  amendment. 


145.  Id.  at  190. 

146.  406  U.S.  at  689-90. 

147.  406  U.S.  at  698  n. 7  (Brennan,  J.,  dissenting). 

148.  Id.;  see  also  United  States  v.  Marion,  404  U.S.   307  (1971);  Dillingham  v. 
United  States,  423  U.S.  64  (1975)  (arrest  activates  speedy  trial  right). 

149.  467  U.S.  at  190. 

150.  Id. 


924  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

in  order  to  justify  distinctions  among  the  points  in  time  at  which  those 
rights  attach,  then  the  literal  language,  '* criminal  prosecutions,"  is  no 
longer  relevant  in  determining  the  scope  of  a  right.  That  same  phrase 
applies  to  every  one  of  the  rights  in  the  sixth  amendment,  but  it  cannot 
have  a  * 'literal"  meaning  that  is  the  same  for  each.  If  the  literal  meaning 
is  not  the  same  for  each  right  in  the  amendment,  then  there  is  no  literal 
meaning.  Once  this  is  recognized,  the  Kirby  rationale  is  lost,  and  the 
courts,  freed  from  the  bankrupt  **plain  language"  approach,  are  called 
upon  to  examine  the  purposes  of  the  right  to  counsel  in  order  to  determine 
the  scope  of  the  right. 

According  to  Wade,  the  right  to  counsel  at  a  lineup  before  trial  is 
essential  for  the  protection  of  rights  that  come  into  play  later  at  trial: 
the  rights  to  meaningful  cross-examination  and  confrontation,  to  effective 
assistance  of  counsel,  and  to  a  fair  trial.  ^^^  Those  same  purposes  exist 
for  the  right  to  counsel  at  a  pretrial  lineup  whether  or  not  formal 
adversarial  judicial  proceedings  have  commenced.'"  As  Justice  Brennan 
made  clear  in  his  Kirby  dissent,  "the  initiation  of  adversarial  judicial 
proceedings  is  completely  irrelevant  to  whether  counsel  is  necessary  at 
a  pretrial  confrontation  for  identification  in  order  to  safeguard  the 
accused's  constitutional  rights  to  confrontation  and  the  effective  assistance 
of  counsel  at  his  trial."'"  Kirby  is  an  aberration  from  Wade,  and  state 
courts  have  struggled  for  years  to  reconcile  the  two  cases. 

IV.     State  Court  Decisions 

In  1974,  only  two  years  after  the  Kirby  decision,  some  state  courts 
began  to  define  a  broader  scope  for  the  right  to  counsel  because  of  the 
interposition  of  state  law.  Others  are  addressing  the  issue  for  the  first 
time  only  now.  The  state  courts  follow  two  approaches.  First,  Penn- 
sylvania and  Mississippi,  Hke  the  Kirby  Court,  restrict  the  right  to  counsel 
to  critical  confrontations  occurring  after  the  initiation  of  judicial  criminal 
proceedings,  but  they  refer  to  state  law  for  the  definition  of  the  initiation 


151.  388  U.S.  at  227. 

152.  See,  e.g..  People  v.  Bustamante,  30  Cal.  3d  88,  95,  177  Cal.  Rptr.  576,  580, 
634  P.2d  927,  931  (1981)  (quoting  People  v.  Fowler,  1  Cal.  3d  335,  342,  82  Cal.  Rptr. 
363,  368-69,  461  P.2d  643,  648-49  (1962)): 

[T]he  presence  or  absence  of  those  conditions  attendant  upon  lineups  which 
induced  the  high  court  to  term  such  proceedings  'a  critical  stage  of  the  pros- 
ecution' at  which  the  right  to  counsel  attaches  ...  is  certainly  not  dependent 
upon  the  occurrence  or  nonoccurrence  of  proceedings  formally  binding  a  de- 
fendant over  for  trial.  A  Hneup  which  occurs  prior  to  the  point  in  question 
may  be  fraught  with  the  same  risks  of  suggestion  as  one  occurring  after  that 
point,  and  may  result  in  the  same  far-reaching  consequences  for  the  defendant. 

153.  406  U.S.  at  697. 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  925 

point.  Because  those  courts  retain  to  some  extent  the  Kirby  requirement 
of  judicial  criminal  proceedings  and  see  the  federal  doctrine  and  state 
constitutions  or  statutes  as  interacting  to  determine  the  attachment  of 
counsel,  they  may  be  referred  to  as  the  "interactive  states."  Second, 
Michigan,  Alaska,  and  California,  on  the  other  hand,  regard  the  at- 
tachment of  the  counsel  right  as  independent  of  the  initiation  of  judicial 
criminal  proceedings.  Because  they  completely  reject  Kirby  and  inde- 
pendently determine  the  attachment  point  of  the  right  to  counsel,  as 
guaranteed  by  the  state  constitution,  those  states  may  be  called  the 
* 'independent  states." 

A.     Interactive  States 

1.  Pennsylvania. — In  1974,  the  Pennsylvania  Supreme  Court  held 
that  the  interplay  of  federal  and  state  law  required  the  presence  of 
counsel  at  a  pre-indictment  lineup.  In  Commonwealth  v.  Richman,^^^ 
several  days  after  the  offense  the  police  arrested  a  suspect  and  placed 
him  in  a  Uneup  at  the  poHce  station,  where  the  victim  identified  him. 
The  Pennsylvania  court  reviewed  the  Wade  and  Kirby  opinions  and 
decided  that  the  later  decision  left  to  state  law  the  question  of  when 
adversary  judicial  proceedings  began  for  sixth  amendment  purposes.  The 
Richman  court  reasoned  that  the  Kirby  plurality  did  not  intend  to  supply 
an  exhaustive  Hst  of  possibilities  when  it  held  that  the  sixth  amendment 
right  to  counsel  attached  to  confrontations  conducted  "at  or  after  the 
initiation  of  adversary  judicial  criminal  proceedings — whether  by  way  of 
formal  charge,  preUminary  hearing,  indictment,  information  or  arraign- 
ment. "^^^ 

Relying  on  an  earlier  decision  interpreting  state  law,^^^  the  Penn- 
sylvania court  held  that  an  arrest  initiates  judicial  proceedings.  The  court 
noted  that  in  Pennsylvania  judicial  approval  of  a  complaint  takes  place 
at  the  issuance  of  an  arrest  warrant, '^^  or  at  the  preliminary  arraignment 
in  the  case  of  a  warrantless  arrest.  The  Richman  court  regarded  mag- 
isterial approval  of  a  complaint  as  equal  in  significance  to  an  indictment 
for  determining  the  commencement  of  adversarial  judicial  proceedings. 
A  person  arrested  pursuant  to  a  warrant,  therefore,  was  entitled  to 
counsel  at  a  resulting  lineup.  The  same  was  true  for  a  person  placed 
in  a  lineup  after  arraignment  following  a  warrantless  arrest. 

In  Richman,  however,  the  Hneup  was  conducted  after  a  warrantless 
arrest  but  before  arraignment.  The  Court  gave  two  reasons  for  not 


154.  458  Pa.  167,  320  A.2d  351  (Pa.   1974). 

155.  Id.  at  171,  320  A.2d  at  353  (quoting  Kirby,  406  U.S.  at  689). 

156.  Id.  (citing  Commonwealth  v.  Whiting,  439  Pa.  205,  266  A.2d  738  (1970)). 

157.  See  United  States  ex  rel.  Robinson  v.  Zelker,  468  F.2d  159  (2d  Cir.   1972) 
(arrest  warrant  commenced  formal  criminal  proceedings  requiring  counsel  at  showup). 


926  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

distinguishing  Richman's  case  from  one  involving  a  lineup  after  arraign- 
ment or  after  arrest  on  a  warrant.  First,  allowing  uncounseled  lineups 
would  undermine  the  Pennsylvania  Court's  ''strong  policy  requiring 
warrants  whenever  feasible.  "^^^  Second,  the  distinction  would  encourage 
police  to  evade  a  state  law  requirement  that  the  suspect  be  brought 
before  a  magistrate  for  the  fiUng  of  a  complaint  "without  unnecessary 
delay.  "^59 

The  Pennsylvania  approach  was  to  require  counsel  at  practically  all 
pre-indictment  Hneups,  as  a  result  of  the  interaction  of  the  sixth  amend- 
ment and  state  law.  The  court  did  not  recognize  a  right  to  counsel 
under  state  law  broader  in  scope  than  the  guarantee  in  the  sixth  amend- 
ment. 

2.  Mississippi. — The  Mississippi  Supreme  Court's  approach  changed 
over  the  years  from  an  embrace  of  the  Kirby  rule,  to  purported  outright 
rejection,  and  later  to  interaction.  Immediately  after  the  Kirby  decision 
the  Mississippi  Supreme  Court  adopted  the  federal  rule  that  "the  right 
to  counsel  did  not  apply  to  a  pre-indictment  Hneup."^^^  By  1984,  however, 
Mississippi  had  begun  to  recognize  the  interplay  between  state  law  and 
the  Kirby  reasoning.  Later  the  Mississippi  court  flirted  with  the  idea  of 
an  independent  standard,  only  to  shift  the  focus  again  to  state  law  as 
the  determinative  component  of  an  interactive  approach. 

In  Cannaday  v.  State, ^^^  looking  to  state  procedure  for  the  deter- 
mination of  when  formal  adversarial  proceedings  have  begun,  as  Penn- 
sylvania had  done  ten  years  earlier, '^^  the  Mississippi  court  held  that 
the  right  to  counsel  may  attach  as  early  as  the  time  when  a  warrant  is 
issued.  Two  years  later  in  Page  v.  State,^^^  the  court  reasoned  that  "[f]or 
purposes  of  our  state  constitutional  right  to  counsel,  we  define  the  advent 
of  the  accusatory  stage  by  reference  to  state  law."^^  Recognizing  that 
state  law  defined  commencement  of  prosecution  as  the  point  when  a 
warrant  was  issued,  or  when  the  person  was  "bound  over"  to  wait  for 
a  grand  jury  to  decide  whether  to  indict, '^^  the  Page  court  concluded 


158.  458  Pa.  at  173,  320  A.2d  at  354.  (As  support  for  that  policy  the  Richman 
court  cited  Wong  Sun  v.  United  States,  371  U.S.  471  (1963)  for  the  proposition  that  "a 
warrantless  arrest  is  justified  only  in  the  face  of  compelling  exigent  circumstances  which 
preclude  the  police  from  going  before  a  detached  magistrate."  458  Pa.  at  172-3,  320  A. 2d 
at  354.  Richman  was  decided  before  United  States  v.  Watson,  423  U.S.  411  (1976) 
(warrantless  public  arrest  may  be  made  in  public  on  probable  cause  without  exigent 
circumstances)). 

159.  Id.  (quoting  Pa.  R.  Crim.  P.  130). 

160.  See  Livingston  v.  State,  519  So.  2d  1218,  1220  (Miss.  1988)  (citing  cases). 

161.  455  So.  2d  713  (Miss.  1984)  cert,  denied,  469  U.S.  122  (1985). 

162.  Commonwealth  v.  Richman,  458  Pa.  167,  320  A.2d  351  (1974). 

163.  495  So. 2d  436  (Miss.   1986). 

164.  Id.  at  439. 

165.  Miss.  Code  Ann.  §  99-1-7  (1972). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  927 

that  it  would  be  '^totally  irrational"  not  to  consider  such  a  person  to 
be  an  accused. '^^  In  light  of  state  law  requiring  speedy  appearance  before 
a  magistrate  after  arrest, '^^  which  would  constitute  the  commencement 
of  judicial  criminal  proceedings,  the  Page  decision  recognized  a  right  to 
counsel  for  a  person  who  has  been  arrested  and  released  on  bond  and 
who  has  obtained  the  services  of  an  attorney.'^* 

In  a  footnote  the  court  expressly  stated  that  it  relied  '^exclusively 
upon  state  law"  and  rejected  Kirby  as  "wholly  unworkable. "^^^  Because 
in  rural  counties  the  meetings  of  grand  juries  to  consider  indictments 
were  held  infrequently,  the  Mississippi  court  thought  that  the  Kirby 
approach  "would  have  the  right  to  counsel  available  to  the  accused  only 
after  many  months  had  passed  following  arrest. "^^^  Later  the  Mississippi 
court  took  an  approach  like  the  one  taken  by  Pennsylvania  in  Richman, 
holding  that  the  attachment  point  of  both  the  federal  and  state  right 
to  counsel  is  determined  by  reference  to  state  law.  Relying  on  Page, 
which  involved  not  a  lineup  but  incriminatory  statements,  the  Mississippi 
Supreme  Court  decided  in  Livingston  v.  State, ^''^  that,  given  state  law 
defining  the  commencement  of  prosecution,'^^  a  person  has  a  right  to 
counsel  at  a  lineup  conducted  after  he  has  been  arrested  on  a  warrant. '^^ 

166.  495  So.  2d  at  439. 

167.  Rule  1.04,  Miss.  Unif.  Crim.  R.  Cm.  Ct.  Prac;  Miss.  Code  Ann.  §  99-3- 
17  (Supp.  1985). 

168.  495  So.  2d  at  439-40. 

169.  Id.  at  440  n.5.  The  court  noted: 

We  are  very  much  aware  of  the  fact  that  a  number  of  recent  federal  cases  have 
held  that  the  right  to  counsel  secured  by  the  Sixth  Amendment  to  the  Constitution 
of  the  United  States  is  available  only  after  the  initiation  of  judicial  criminal 
proceeding[s],  i.e.,  indictment  and  arraignment.  Application  of  this  approach  to 
our  state  constitutional  right  would  be  wholly  unworkable.  .  .  .  [Wle  reject  the 
federal  approach  and  for  purposes  of  today's  decision  rely  exclusively  upon  state 
law. 
(citations  omitted). 

170.  Id.  At  the  time  it  appeared  Mississippi  was  rejecting  the  Kirby  judicial-pro- 
ceedings formulation  of  the  attachment  point  for  the  state  constitutional  right  to  counsel. 
The  Page  Court  actually  disavowed  something  that  Kirby  had  not  held — that  the  right  to 
counsel  attached  only  at  or  after  indictment  and  arraignment.  When  the  Kirby  Court 
spoke  of  arraignment,  however,  it  did  not  mean  only  a  hearing  before  a  magistrate 
occurring  after  indictment  but  also  earlier  proceedings,  like  the  initial  appearance  before 
a  magistrate  after  arrest.  See,  e.g.,  Michigan  v.  Jackson,  475  U.S.  625  (1986)  (initial 
appearance  or  "arraignment"  after  being  arrested  and  formally  charged);  Brewer  v. 
Williams,  430  U.S.  387  (1977)  (arrest  on  warrant,  arraignment,  judicial  commitment  to 
jail). 

171.  519  So.  2d  1218  (Miss.   1988). 

172.  Miss.  Code  Ann.  §  99-1-77  (Supp.  1986). 

173.  519  So.  2d  at  1221.  (The  Court  affirmed  the  conviction  because  of  several 
procedural  problems  concerning  the  preservation  of  error.  Some  of  the  problems  were 
that  (1)  the  record  did  not  show  that  counsel  was  not  present  at  the  Hneup  and  (2)  at 
trial  no  objection  was  made  to  the  admission  of  testimony  about  the  lineup.) 


928  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

The  Livingston  case  involved  counsel  claims  under  both  the  federal  and 
state  constitutions,  but  the  Mississippi  court  did  not  employ  a  different 
test  for  the  state  provision. 

The  latest  refinement  of  the  Mississippi  test,  however,  regards  state 
law,  without  reference  to  or  reUance  on  the  federal  sixth  amendment, 
as  dictating  attachment  of  the  right  to  counsel  at  the  point  after  arrest 
when  the  initial  appearance  before  a  magistrate  '*  ought  to  have  been 
held."'"''^  That  rule  prevents  the  police  from  postponing  the  attachment 
of  the  right  to  counsel  by  delaying  the  arrestee's  appearance  in  court. 

Although  earher  Mississippi  case  law  displayed  **a  trend  toward  rigid 
restriction  of  the  access  to  counsel  to  post-indictment  line-ups,  that  view 
has  clearly  been  supplanted  by  a  more  recent  case  espousing  an  approach 
based  squarely  on  state  law  and  the  initiation  of  judicial  proceedings 
as  defined  by  statute.  "^^^  The  Mississippi  approach  now  resembles  that 
of  Pennsylvania,  the  other  interactive  state,  in  that  it  accepts  the  Kirby 
judicial-proceedings  concept  regarding  the  attachment  point  for  the  right 
to  counsel  but  defines  that  point  by  reference  to  state  law.^"^^  In  one 
context  or  another  those  two  state  courts  have  held  that  the  right  to 
counsel  at  a  Hneup  attaches  when,  as  a  matter  of  statute,  court  rule, 
or  policy,  a  judicial  officer  should  have  become  involved  in  the  case, 
despite  the  fact  that  no  magistrate  had  yet  been  consulted.  The  result 
is  that  in  Mississippi  and  Pennsylvania,  the  right  to  counsel  at  a  Hneup 
attaches  at  a  point  earlier  in  the  criminal  process  than  any  United  States 
Supreme  Court  opinion  has  yet  recognized.  Mississippi  has  gone  beyond 
Pennsylvania  in  recognizing  such  an  early  counsel  right  without  reliance 
on  the  sixth  amendment,  but  Mississippi  has  not  expressly  declared  that 
the  right  under  state  law  is  greater  in  scope. '^^ 


174.  Magee  v.  State,  542  So.  2d  228  (Miss.  1989). 

175.  Whitten  &  Robertson,  supra  note  13,  at  293  n.l82  (citing  statutory  and  case 
authority). 

176.  Some  federal  courts  have  recognized  the  interactive  nature  of  the  Kirby  approach 
to  the  question  of  when  the  right  to  counsel  attaches.  See,  e.g..  United  States  v.  Muzychka, 
725  F.2d  1061  (3d  Cir.),  cert,  denied,  467  U.S.  1206  (1984);  Clark  v.  Jago,  676  F.2d 
1099  (6th  Cir.  1982),  cert,  denied,  466  U.S.  977  (1984);  Lomax  v.  Alabama,  629  F.2d 
413  (5th  Cir.  1980),  cert,  denied,  450  U.S.  1002  (1981);  United  States  ex  rel.  Robinson 
V.  Zelker,  468  F.2d  159  (2d  Cir.  1972),  cert,  denied,  411  U.S.  939  (1973);  United  States 
ex  rel.  Sanders  v.  Rowe,  460  F.  Supp.  1128  (N.D.  111.  1978);  United  States  ex  rel.  Burton 
V.  Cuyler,  439  F.  Supp.  1173  (E.D.  Pa.  1977),  aff'd  without  opinion,  582  F.2d  1278  (3d 
Cir.   1978)  (all  cases  following  interactive  approach). 

177.  Two  other  states  have  moved  close  to  independence  on  the  lineup  issue  without 
quite  crossing  the  line.  See  State  v.  Smith,  547  So.  2d  131  (Fla.  1989)  {ex  parte  order 
compelling  accused  already  in  police  custody  to  participate  in  lineup  violates  due  process 
under  state  constitution);  People  v.  Coates,  74  N.Y.2d  244,  544  N.Y.S.2d  992,  543  N.E.2d 
440  (1989)  (suspect  incarcerated  and  represented  by  attorney  on  other  charge  had  right 
to  counsel  at  lineup  ordered  by  court). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  929 

B.     Independent  States 

1.  Michigan. — The  first  state  high  court  to  reject  Kirby  completely 
on  state  law  grounds  was  the  Supreme  Court  of  Michigan  in  People  v. 
Jackson, ^''^  which  involved  photographic  arrays  and  a  Uneup  apparently 
conducted  without  the  presence  of  counsel.  At  the  time  of  the  identi- 
fication proceedings  Jackson,  a  suspect  in  an  assault  case,  was  in  jail 
under  a  sentence  for  a  related  offense.  For  practical  purposes  he  was 
regarded  as  under  arrest  for  the  assault  in  question. '^^  In  Jackson,  the 
Michigan  court  exercised  its  * 'constitutional  power  to  establish  rules  of 
evidence  appUcable  to  judicial  proceedings  in  Michigan  courts  and  to 
preserve  best  evidence  eyewitness  testimony  from  unnecessary  alteration 
by  unfair  identification  procedures. "'^°  The  Jackson  decision  relied  on 
an  earlier  opinion  by  the  same  court  in  People  v.  Anderson, ^^^  involving 
photographic  identifications. 

Anderson  was  decided  after  Kirby  but  before  United  States  v.  Ash,^^^ 
the  photographic  display  case  discussed  above.  In  Anderson,  the  Michigan 
Supreme  Court  came  to  conclusions  contrary  to  Kirby  and  Ash.  The 
Michigan  court  surveyed  the  legal  and  scientific  writings  on  eyewitness 
identification,'^^  extensively  analyzed  the  competing  interests  of  the  state 
and  the  suspect,  and  concluded  that,  independent  of  federal  constitutional 
doctrine,  a  suspect  is  entitled  to  counsel  at  a  live  or  photographic 
identification  without  regard  to  whether  the  ''judicial  phase  of  a  pros- 
ecution" has  begun. '^"^  In  Jackson,  after  reviewing  Kirby  and  Ash,  the 
Michigan  Supreme  Court  expressly  rejected  those  two  opinions  and  re- 
affirmed the  Anderson  holding  on  the  basis  of  its  supervisory  powers, 
independent  of  federal  constitutional  analysis.'*^  The  Jackson  court  thus 


178.  391  Mich.  323,  217  N.W.2d  22  (1974). 

179.  Id.  Accord,  People  v.  Anderson,  391  Mich.  419,  216  N.W.2d  780  (1974)  (fact 
that  suspect  in  custody  for  different  crime  did  not  diminish  right  to  counsel  at  photo 
lineup).  But  cf.  Foster  v.  State,  713  S.W.2d  789  (Tex.  Ct.  App.  1986)  ("The  fact  that 
the  appellant  was  incarcerated  on  an  unrelated  matter  at  the  time  of  the  lineup  was  not 
relevant  to  a  determination  of  his  sixth  amendment  right  to  counsel  for  the  robbery,  the 
offense  for  which  he  was  identified  at  the  lineup.")  Id.  at  790. 

180.  391  Mich,  at  338-39,  217  N.W.2d  at  27. 

181.  389  Mich.  155,  205  N.W.2d  461  (1973). 

182.  413  U.S.  300  (1973). 

183.  The  court  attached  an  appendix  to  the  Anderson  opinion  displaying  thorough 
research.  See  389  Mich,  at  192-220,  205  N.W.2d  at  479-95. 

184.  Jackson,  391  Mich,  at  339,  217  N.W.2d  at  27  (The  Jackson  court  defined  the 
"judicial  phase  of  a  prosecution"  as  "[f]iling  of  a  complaint/issuance  of  an  arrest  warrant/ 
preliminary  examination/filing  of  an  information  or  indictment.")  Id.  n.ll. 

185.  Id.  391  Mich  at  338,  217  N.W.2d  at  27-28.  The  court  stated: 

[T]he  principles  developed  in  and  following  the  announcement  of  Wade,  as  to 
corporeal  identifications,  and  Anderson,  as  to  photo  showings,  shall  govern  the 


930  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

mandated  that  counsel  be  present  at  pretrial  lineups  unless  exigent  cir- 
cumstances justified  proceeding  without  counsel. 

2.  Alaska. — The  Supreme  Court  of  Alaska  in  Blue  v.  State^^^  was 
the  first  state  court  to  ground  the  rule  requiring  counsel  at  a  pre- 
indictment  lineup  squarely  on  the  state  constitutional  right  to  counsel. 
In  that  case  police  conducted  an  impromptu  lineup  in  a  bar  shortly 
after  an  armed  robbery  had  occurred  in  another  bar  nearby.  A  victim 
identified  Blue  in  the  Hneup.  While  recognizing  that  Kirby  had  rejected 
a  sixth  amendment  claim  to  a  right  to  counsel  at  pre-indictment  lineups, 
and  that  the  "pre-  and  post-indictment  distinction  ha[d]  been  widely 
applied  by  federal  and  state  courts,"'^''  the  Alaska  Supreme  Court  stated 
that  it  "is  not  limited  by  decisions  of  the  United  States  Supreme  Court 
or  by  the  United  States  Constitution  when  interpreting  its  state  consti- 
tution. "^^^  The  Alaska  court  noted  that  the  right  to  counsel  under  the 
state  constitution  already  had  been  given  a  broader  scope  than  its  sixth 
amendment  analogue. ^^^ 

Balancing  the  need  of  the  state  for  prompt  and  efficient  investigation 
of  crimes  against  the  right  of  the  suspect  to  meaningful  cross-examination 
at  a  later  trial,  and  relying  on  Justice  Brennan's  dissent  in  Kirby, ^'^  as 
well  as  California  cases  interpreting  Wade,^^^  the  Blue  court  held  that 
"a  suspect  who  is  in  custody  is  entitled  to  have  counsel  present  at  a 
pre-indictment  lineup  unless  exigent  circumstances  exist  so  that  providing 
counsel  would  unduly  interfere  with  a  prompt  and  purposeful  investi- 
gation. "'^^  The  Alaska  court  found  exigent  circumstances  to  be  present 
in  Blue,  so  that  providing  counsel  would  not  have  been  "practical, 
reasonable  or  mandated  by  [the  Alaska]  constitution. '*^^^ 

3.  California. — In  People  v.  Bustamante,^^"^  the  California  Supreme 
Court  followed  Alaska's  example  and  rested  its  decision  on  an  inde- 


receipt  in  evidence  of  identification  testimony  where  the  witness  has  viewed  or 
seen  photographs  of  the  suspect  without  regard  to  when  the  judicial  phase  of 
the  prosecution  is  commenced, 
(footnotes  omitted). 

186.  558  P.2d  636  (Alaska  1977). 

187.  Id.  at  640  n.5. 

188.  Id.  at  641. 

189.  Id.  (citing  Roberts  v.  State,  458  P.2d  340  (Alaska  1969)). 

190.  Id.  at  641-42  n.8  (quoting  Kirby  v.  Illinois,  406  U.S.  682,  696  (1982)  (Brennan, 
J.,  dissenting)). 

191.  Id.  at  642  n.lO. 

192.  Id.  at  642  (footnotes  omitted).  The  court  noted  that,  although  Blue  had  not 
been  placed  under  formal  arrest,  he  was  in  custody.  Id.  n.9. 

193.  Id.  at  642  n.ll  (The  court  reversed  the  conviction  on  a  different  ground.)  Id. 
at  646. 

194.  30  Cal.  '3d  88,   177  Cal.   Rptr.   576,  634  P.2d  927  (1981).  The  decision  in 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  931 

pendent  state  constitutional  right  to  counsel.  In  reaching  that  decision 
the  California  court  re-affirmed  its  decision  in  People  v.  Fowler, ^"^^  which 
was  decided  after  Wade  but  before  Kirby.  In  the  Fowler  case,  the 
California  court,  like  some  federal  courts  before  Kirby, ^^^  had  held  that 
the  Wade  right  to  counsel  extended  to  pre-indictment  lineups.  In  Bus- 
tamante,  the  court  revisited  Fowler  and  noted  the  intervening  decisions 
in  Alaska,  Michigan,  and  Pennsylvania  discussed  above. '^"^ 

The  Bustamante  court  recognized  the  unreliability  of  eyewitness  iden- 
tification and  the  way  the  witness  becomes  '^unshakable"  once  the  lineup 
identification  removes  his  doubts  and  commits  him  to  the  proposition 
that  the  defendant  is  the  criminal  in  question. '^^  The  California  court 
also  noted  the  extreme  difficulty  of  reproducing  the  lineup  procedure 
at  trial  with  sufficient  precision  to  reveal  improper  suggestion. ^^^  Further 
examining  the  role  of  counsel  at  a  lineup,  the  Bustamante  court  decided 
that  the  counsel  requirement  would  encourage  police  to  adopt  and  to 
follow  fair  procedures. ^^  By  attending  the  lineup,  the  attorney  could 
detect  intentionally  or  inadvertently  suggestive  aspects  of  the  lineup  and 
could  better  prepare  for  cross-examination  of  the  eyewitnesses  and  for 
argument  at  trial. ^^^  In  rejecting  Kirby,  however,  the  California  Court 
again  followed  the  lead  of  Michigan  and  Alaska  and  held  that  exigent 
circumstances  could  justify  proceeding  without  counsel. ^^^ 

C     Retreat  from  Independence 

Texas. — Texas,  the  scene  of  the  bank  robbery  in  Wade,  which  was 
the  starting  point  for  the  right  to  counsel  at  a  lineup,  recently  announced 
a  new  rule  rejecting  the  Kirby  rationale  and  according  counsel  at  any 
critical  pretrial  confrontation,  before  or  after  the  initiation  of  formal 
judicial  proceedings,  as  a  matter  of  state  law.  Within  a  year,  however, 


Bustamante  remains  valid,  despite  Proposition  8,  which  narrowed  the  California  exclusionary 
rule  to  a  scope  identical  to  the  federal  rule,  because  the  conduct  in  Bustamante  occurred 
before  passage  of  the  initiative.  People  v,  Houston,  42  Cal,  3d  595,  600  n.3,  230  Cal. 
Rptr.   141,  142  n.3,  724  P.2d  1166,  1167  n.3  (1986). 

195.  1  Cal.  3d  335,  461  P.2d  643,  82  Cal.  Rptr.  363  (1969). 

196.  Bustamante  at  30  Cal.  3d  at  95,  634  P.2d  at  931,  177  Cal.  Rptr.  at  580  (citing 
Wilson  v.  Gaffney,  454  F.2d  142  (10th  Cir.  1972);  United  States  v.  Greene,  429  F.2d  193 
(D.C.  Cir.  1970)). 

197.  Id.  at  96  n.5,  177  Cal.  Rptr.  at  581  n.5,  634  P.2d  at  932  n.5. 

198.  Id.  at  98,  177  Cal.  Rptr.  at  582,  634  P.2d  at  933. 

199.  Id.  at  99,  177  Cal.  Rptr.  at  583,  634  P.2d  at  934. 

200.  Id. 

201.  Id. 

202.  Id.  at  100,  177  Cal.  Rptr.  at  584,  634  P.2d  at  935.  See  also  Blue  v.  State, 
558  P. 2d  636  (Alaska  1977)  (state  constitution  requires  presence  of  counsel  at  in-custody 
lineup). 


932  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

the  Texas  court  reversed  itself  and  retreated  to  the  Kirby  rule.  Until 
Kirby  came  along,  the  Texas  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals, ^°^  like  the 
California  Supreme  Court, ^^'^  regarded  Wade  as  applying  the  sixth  amend- 
ment right  to  counsel  to  pre-indictment  Uneups,  as  well  as  post-indictment 
confrontations.  In  Martinez  v.  State^^^  in  1969,  the  Texas  court  concluded 
that  Wade  clearly  held  *'that  a  criminal  suspect  cannot  be  subjected  to 
a  pretrial  identification  process  in  the  absence  of  counsel  without  violating 
the  Sixth  Amendment. "^o^ 

Since  Kirby  re-interpreted  the  Wade  decision,  however,  the  Texas 
Court  of  Criminal  Appeals  has  not  directly  re-addressed  the  pre-indict- 
ment lineup  issue  as  a  matter  of  state  law.  In  the  1986  case  of  Foster 
V.  State^^''  discussed  above,^^®  an  intermediate  court  of  appeals  in  Texas 
tersely  rejected  the  appellant's  claim  of  a  right  to  counsel,  saying  that 
it  was  "unable  to  find  any  basis  upon  which  to  interpret  our  state 
constitution's  right-to-counsel  provision  as  giving  a  criminal  defendant 
any  greater  protection  than  is  given  by  the  United  States  Constitution.  "^09 
The  Texas  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals  currently  is  reviewing  Foster  to 
decide  the  question  of  whether  the  Texas  Constitution  guarantees  the 
right  to  counsel  at  a  Uneup  before  indictment. 

Meanwhile,  in  Forte  v.  State,^^^  the  Texas  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals 
appeared  to  open  the  door  to  recognition  of  a  state  constitutional  right 
to  have  counsel  present  at  a  lineup  before  formal  judicial  proceedings 
begin.  Forte  claimed  that  he  had  a  right  to  counsel  at  a  breath  test 
administered  after  his  arrest  for  driving  while  intoxicated.  In  1986,  the 
Court  of  Criminal  Appeals,  following  Kirby,  rejected  his  sixth  amendment 
claim  and  remanded  for  consideration  of  the  state  constitutional  law 
issue. ^'^  On  remand  the  intermediate  court  of  appeals  held  against  the 
state  constitutional  contention, ^^^  and  the  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals 
agreed. ^^^  In  rejecting  the  state  law  claim,  however,  the  Court  of  Criminal 
Appeals  also  unanimously  rejected  the  Kirby  rationale  as  a  ' 'fiction. "^^'^ 
The  court  stated: 


203.  The  Texas  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals  is  the  court  of  last  resort  for  state 
criminal  cases.  The  Texas  Supreme  Court  handles  civil  cases.  Tex.  R.  App.  P.  15,  9, 
respectively. 

204.  People  v.  Fowler,  1  Cal.  2d  335,  82  Cal.  Rtpr.  363,  461  P.2d  643  (1969). 

205.  437  S.W.2d  842  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1969). 

206.  Id.  at  846. 

207.  713  S.W.2d  789  (Tex.  Ct.  App.  1986). 

208.  See  supra  text  accompanying  notes  1-3. 

209.  713  S.W.2d  at  790. 

210.  759  S.W.2d  128  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1988). 

211.  707  S.W.2d  89  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1986). 

212.  Forte  v.  State,  722  S.W.2d  219  (Tex.  Ct.  App.   1986). 

213.  Forte  v.  State,  759  S.W.2d  128  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1988). 

214.  Id.  at  131  (Two  judges  dissented  but  obviously  agreed  with  the  majority  in 
rejecting  Kirby.  See  759  S.W.2d  at  139-40  (Chnton,  J.  and  Teague,  J.,  dissenting)). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  933 

We  believe  that  the  basis  and  rationale  of  the  Wade-Gilbert  rule 
and  the  Kirby  line  of  cases  become  difficult  if  not  impossible 
to  reconcile,  especially  when  one  considers  the  realities  of  the 
criminal  investigatory  procedures  utilized  by  most  law  enforce- 
ment agencies.  That  is,  the  same  dangers  of  prejudice  which 
Wade  and  Gilbert  claimed  concern  will  invariably  exist  at  many 
stages  of  a  criminal  prosecution  prior  to  the  onset  of  formal 
charges;  therefore,  the  demarcation  of  formal  charges  before  the 
right  to  counsel  is  triggered  is  probably  arbitrary  and  capricious.^' ^ 

The  court  surveyed  the  decisions  of  other  states  and  recognized  a 
sharp  division  on  the  issue  of  counsel  at  breath  tests.  Concentrating  on 
the  opinions  of  the  Supreme  Court  of  Oregon,^*^  the  Texas  court  con- 
curred with  the  Oregon  court's  ''repudiation"  of  Kirby  but  declined  to 
follow  the  Oregon  reasoning  that  arrest  automatically  triggers  the  right 
to  counsel  in  breath  test  cases. ^•^ 

The  Texas  Court  did  not  believe  that  the  Kirby  fiction  (i.e.,  the 
right  to  counsel  begins  at  the  time  when  adversarial  judicial  proceedings 
commence)  should  be  replaced  with  another  fiction  that  the  right  to 
counsel  automatically  attaches  at  the  time  of  formal  arrest.  Eschewing 
any  "artificially  created  time  designation, "^'^  the  Court  of  Criminal 
Appeals  insisted  on  a  "more  flexible  standard. "^'^  Holding  that  the  right 
to  counsel  arises  at  "critical  stage [s]"^^^  of  the  criminal  process,  the 
court  directed  that  "each  case  must  be  judged  on  whether  the  pretrial 
confrontation  presented  necessitates  counsel's  presence  so  as  to  protect 
a  known  right  or  safeguard, "^^^  such  as  later  rights  to  a  fair  trial,  to 
meaningful  cross-examination,  and  to  effective  assistance  of  counsel  at 
trial. ^^2  The  Forte  court  thus  accepted  the  Wade  definition  of  "critical 
stages"  but  rejected  the  Kirby  designation  of  formal  adversarial  judicial 
proceedings  as  the  starting  point.  A  critical  stage,  under  the  Forte 
reasoning,  can  occur  before  judicial  criminal  proceedings  begin.  Nev- 
ertheless, the  court  reasoned  that,  under  the  Texas  Implied  Consent 
Statute,^^^  which  provides  that  a  driver  impliedly  consents  to  a  breath 
test  by  the  act  of  driving  on  a  public  road,  Forte  had  no  legal  right 
to  revoke  his  implied  consent  and  to  refuse  a  breath  test.   For  that 


215.  Id.  at  134. 

216.  See,  e.g.,  State  v.  Spencer,  305  Or.  59,  750  P.2d  147  (1988). 

217.  Forte,  759  S.W.2d  at  137. 

218.  Id.  at  138. 

219.  Id. 

220.  Id. 

221.  Id. 

111.  Id.  at  137-38  (quoting  United  States  v.  Wade,  388  U.S.  218  (1967)). 

223.  Tex.  Rev.  Civ.  Stat.  Ann.  §§  67011-15  (Vernon  Supp.  1984). 


934  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

reason  the  suspect  had  no  right  that  needed  protection  at  the  time  of 
the  breath  test  or  at  a  later  trial.  Consequently,  the  Court  held  that  the 
time  at  which  a  driver  is  faced  with  the  decision  whether  to  take  a  test 
is  not  a  ''critical  stage"  of  the  criminal  process  at  which  counsel's 
presence  is  required.  Forte's  right  to  counsel  under  the  Texas  constitution, 
just  Uke  the  sixth  amendment  right,  "did  not  attach  until  the  time  the 
complaint  was  filed. "^^"^ 

The  analysis  employed  by  the  Forte  court  seemed  to  allow  the 
attachment  of  the  right  to  counsel  at  lineups  Hke  the  one  in  Foster. 
While  it  is  true  that  Foster,  who  was  in  jail  serving  a  sentence  for  other 
offenses,  was  not  formally  under  arrest  for  the  robberies  under  inves- 
tigation, ^^^  nothing  in  the  Forte  rationale  suggested  that  the  suspect  must 
be  the  subject  of  an  arrest,  let  alone  a  judicial  warrant,  formal  complaint, 
arraignment,  preliminary  hearing,  information  or  indictment.  The  only 
question  is  whether  the  pretrial  confrontation  itself  is  a  critical  stage, 
in  that  counsel's  presence  is  needed  to  protect  a  known  right  existing 
at  the  confrontation  or  later  in  the  process.  Wade  clearly  regarded  all 
such  pretrial  lineups  to  be  critical  stages.  The  Forte  opinion's  heavy 
reliance  on  Wade's,  rationale,  while  rejecting  Kirby,  appeared  to  make 
it  difficult  for  the  Texas  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals  to  deny  the  claim 
made  in  Foster  that  the  right  to  counsel  attaches  at  a  lineup  for  a  person 
serving  a  sentence  in  jail  for  other  offenses. 

During  the  next  legislative  session,  however,  in  reaction  to  Forte 
and  other  decisions,  opponents  of  independent  state  constitutionalism 
proposed  a  sweeping  amendment  to  the  Texas  Constitution  that  would 
have  stripped  the  courts  of  the  authority  to  construe  state  constitutional 
provisions  more  favorably  to  criminal  defendants  than  the  federal  courts 
have  construed  the  federal  Bill  of  Rights. ^^^  Although  the  amendment 


224.  759  S.W.2d  at  139  (quoting  Forte  v.  State,  707  S.W.2d  89,  92  (Tex.  Crim. 
App.  1986)).  Presumably  the  Texas  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals  in  Forte  merely  meant 
that  the  state  counsel  right  did  not  theoretically  attach  before  the  sixth  amendment  right 
in  that  case.  The  court  adopted  the  federal  critical  stage  analysis,  which  requires  that, 
for  the  right  to  counsel  to  come  into  play,  the  proceeding  at  which  counsel's  presence  is 
requested  must  be  a  "confrontation"  between  the  accused  and  the  state.  Id.  at  133  (quoting 
Wade,  388  U.S.  at  226-27).  Unless  the  filing  of  the  complaint  involved  a  confrontation 
that  is  not  mentioned  in  any  of  the  Forte  opinions,  however,  it  is  difficult  to  see  how 
the  Texas  counsel  right  actually  became  operative  when  the  complaint  was  filed.  See  R. 
Dawson  &  R.  Dix,  Texas  Criminal  Procedure  112  (1984)  (complaint  may  be  filed  before 
defendant's  first  appearance  in  court).  See  also  Lara  v.  State,  740  S.W.2d  823,  834  (Tex. 
Ct.  App.  1987,  pet.  ref'd,  cert,  denied,  Lara  v.  Texas,  110  S.  Ct.  92  (1989)  (right  to 
counsel  can  fail  to  "come  into  play"  even  though  theoretically  it  has  "attached"  by  way 
of  indictment). 

225.  Compare  People  v.  Jackson,  391  Mich.  323,  217  N.W.2d  22  (1974). 

226.  See  generally  Dix,   Judicial  Independence  in  Defining  Criminal  Defendants' 

Texas  Constitutional  Rights,  68  Tex.  L.  Rev.  (1990)  (origin  and  consequences  of 

proposed  amendment)  (draft  of  forthcoming  article). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  935 

died  in  committee,  the  Texas  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals  soon  disavowed 
the  Forte  test  in  McCambridge  v.  State, ^^"^  another  case  involving  the 
right  to  counsel  before  taking  a  breath  test  after  arrest  for  driving  while 
intoxicated.  In  McCambridge  the  court  decided  that  the  Forte  case-by- 
case  approach  was  * 'ambiguous,  vague,  and  thus  unworkable.  "^^*  Al- 
though remaining  critical  of  Kirby  as  irreconcilable  with  Wade  and 
Gilbert, ^^^  the  court  retreated  to  the  Kirby  "bright-line  rule,"  merely  in 
the  interest  of  consistency,  because,  as  the  court  simply  put  it, 
*'[c]onsistency  is  the  objective  of  any  legal  standard. "^^^  The  Mc- 
Cambridge opinion  was  so  lacking  in  rationale  as  "to  strongly  suggest 
that  the  court  was  almost  panicstricken  in  its  haste  to  disavow  what 
had  become  a  politically-damaging  pronouncement. "^^^  The  repudiation 
of  the  Forte  approach  made  no  practical  difference  in  McCambridge 
(the  result  being  that,  just  as  in  Forte,  the  right  to  counsel  did  not 
attach  until  the  filing  of  formal  charges), ^^^  but  the  overall  direction  of 
the  McCambridge  opinion  appeared  to  militate  against  Foster's  claim 
of  the  right  to  counsel  at  a  precharging  lineup  (although  the  McCambridge 
holding  was  limited  to  "the  context  of  this  case").^^^  The  Foster  case 
remains  undecided. 

V.    Conclusion 

In  finding  a  state  law  basis  for  counsel  at  a  lineup,  the  state  court 
decisions  discussed  above  relied  on  the  poUcies  underlying  the  right  to 
counsel  and  the  requirements  of  state  statutes.  Two  of  the  courts  gave 
considerable  attention  to  recent  psychological  and  legal  writings  on  eye- 
witness identification  in  general  and  lineups  in  particular. ^^"^  Recent  re- 


227.  778  S.W.2d  70  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1989). 

228.  Id.  at  75. 

229.  Id.  at  75-76. 

230.  Id.  at  75. 

231.  Dix,  supra  note  226. 

232.  McCambridge  v.  State,  778  S.W.2d  70,  76  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1989). 

233.  Id. 

234.  People  v.  Anderson,  389  Mich.  155,  205  N.W.2d  461  (1973);  People  v.  Bus- 
tamante,  30  Cal.  3d  88,  177  Cal.  Rptr.  216,  634  P.2d  927  (1981);  People  v.  Hawkins, 
55  N.Y.2d  474,  450  N.Y.S.2d  159,  435  N.E.2d  376  (1982)  (Meyer,  J.,  dissenting).  But 
see  the  majority  opinion  in  Hawkins,  at  487  n.7,  450  N.Y.S.2d  at  166  n.7,  435  N.E,2d 
383  n.7: 

I  further  comment  on  the  multiple  nonjudicial  sources  employed  in  the  dissent. 
While  I,  in  no  measure,  intend  disrespect  to  my  dissenting  colleagues,  to  the 
view  they  express,  nor  to  academic  sources  generally,  I  am  constrained  to  note 
that  some  of  these  proffered  authorities  do  not  realistically  or  legally  justify 
the  result  for  which  they  are  advanced.  Thus,  no  item  by  item  response  is 
warranted.  Rather,  I  find  confirmation  and  support  for  the  majority  viewpoint 
in  the  judicial  decisions  and  analyses  of  our  court  and  the  Supreme  Court  of 
the  United  States. 


936  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

search  continues  to  cast  doubt  on  the  fairness  of  lineups,  even  when 
the  subjects  of  the  lineup  appear  to  match  the  general  description  of 
the  suspect. 2^^  State  courts  should  not  follow  the  United  States  Supreme 
Court  in  turning  a  '*deaf  ear*'  to  the  scientific  studies, ^^^  because  they 
indicate  that  the  courts  operate  under  many  misconceptions  about  eye- 
witness identification  and  lineups  in  particular. ^^"^ 

Several  states  have  gone  beyond  discussion  of  policy  or  psychology 
in  analyzing  the  right  to  counsel.  Courts  and  commentators  in  several 
states  have  taken  the  historical  approach  in  interpreting  state  constitu- 
tional rights. ^^^  Despite  the  difficulties  inherent  in  the  search  for  original 
intent,^^^  the  Texas  Court  of  Criminal  Appeals  resorted  to  an  examination 
of  the  history  of  the  state,  as  well  as  its  many  successive  constitutions, ^"^^ 
as  a  clue  to  the  intended  scope  of  the  present  state  constitutional 
provision.^"*^  Where  appropriate  sources  are  available, ^'^^  state  courts  can 


235.  See,  e.g.,  Buckhout,  Rabinowitz,  Alfonso,  Kanellis,  &  Anderson,  Empirical 
Assessment  of  Lineups:  Getting  Down  to  Cases,  12  Law  &  Hum.  Behav.  323  (1988) 
(using  real  case  photo  array  of  six  men,  and  relying  on  eyewitness  description,  58%  of 
mock  witnesses  picked  photo  of  defendant,  whom  they  had  never  seen  before,  although 
only  one  in  six  should  pick  same  photo  if  procedure  unbiased). 

236.  See  Sherwood,  The  Erosion  of  Constitutional  Safeguards  in  the  Area  of  Eye- 
witness Identification,  30  Howard  L.J.  731,  771  (1987)  (U.S.  Supreme  Court's  eagerness 
to  ignore  empirical  and  other  scholarly  authorities). 

237.  See  supra  text  accompanying  notes  28-95. 

238.  See,  e.g..  State  v.  Henry,  302  Or.  510,  732  P.2d  9  (1987)  (obscenity  prosecution 
precluded  by  state  provision  protecting  free  expression);  Harris  v.  State,  645  S.W.2d  447 
(Tex.  Crim.  App.  1983)  (state  doctrine  of  separation  of  church  and  state  overrides 
ecclesiastically-based  rule  against  judicial  proceedings  on  Sunday);  Utter  &  Larson,  Church 
and  State  on  the  Frontier:  The  History  of  the  Establishment  Clauses  in  the  Washington 
State  Constitution,  15  Hastings  Const.  L.Q.  451  (1988);  Ponton,  Sources  of  Liberty  in 
the  Texas  Bill  of  Rights,  20  St.  Mary's  L.J.  93  (1988). 

239.  See,  e.g.,  McCabe,  State  Constitutions  and  the  "Open  Fields"  Doctrine:  A 
Historical-Definitional  Analysis  of  the  Scope  of  Protection  Against  Warrantless  Searches 
of  "Possessions,''  13  Vt.  L.  Rev.  179  (1988)  (discussing  Hmitations  and  citing  criticism 
of  quest  for  original  intent).  See  also  Brest,  The  Misconceived  Quest  for  the  Original 
Understanding,  60  B.U.L.  Rev.  204,  229  (1980)  (relegating  original  intent  to  factor  not 
of  "determinative"  weight). 

240.  See  generally  Eisenhauer  v.  State,  754  S.W.2d  159,  166-76  (Tex.  Crim.  App. 
1988)  (Clinton,  J.,  dissenting)  (early  Texas  constitutional  history). 

241.  Forte  v.  State,  759  S.W.2d,  134  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1988).  In  Forte,  a  majority 
of  the  court  appeared  to  recognize  for  the  first  time  that  the  Texans  who  proposed  and 
ratified  the  present  state  constitution  in  1875-76  may  have  been  more  sensitive  to  police 
abuses  than  were  the  framers  and  ratifiers  of  the  federal  Bill  of  Rights  in  an  earlier  era. 
The  court  noted  that  Texans  had  been  subjected  to  an  "extremely  repressive"  Reconstruction 
government.  Id.  During  that  period,  the  governor  made  "despotic"  use  of  a  state  police 
force  that  he  had  created  and  into  which  he  incorporated  all  local  constabularies.  Id. 
n.ll  (quoting  Thomas,  The  Texas  Constitution  of  1876,  35  Tex.  L.  Rev.  907,  912-13 
(1951)).  See  generally  S.  McKay,  Making  the  Texas  Constitution  of  1876,  424-26  (1968). 


1989]  RIGHT  TO  A  LAWYER  937 

profitably  follow  the  historical  approach  to  the  interpretation  of  the 
right  to  counsel  at  a  lineup. 

Michigan,  Alaska,  and  CaUfornia,  on  the  other  hand,  recognized 
the  exigent  circumstances  exception  as  a  necessary  practical  limitation 
on  the  scope  of  the  counsel  right,  designed  to  safeguard  the  efficiency 
and  effectiveness  of  police  investigations.^"*^  Other  courts  may  be  expected 
to  take  the  same  cautious  approach,  although  it  has  been  observed  that 
over  the  last  twenty  years  little  or  no  evidence  has  been  developed  to 
suggest  that  law  enforcement  has  been  seriously  impeded  by  state  court 
decisions  recognizing  rights  greater  in  scope  than  those  guaranteed  by 
the  federal  Constitution. ^"^ 

The  interactive  states,  while  retaining  the  federal  "formal  adversarial 
judicial  proceedings"  formula  for  the  attachment  of  the  right  to  counsel, 
have  ameliorated  the  Procrustean  nature  of  that  prerequisite  by  identifying 
the  initiation  of  such  proceedings  at  ever-earUer  points  in  the  criminal 
process,  as  a  matter  of  state  law.  Such  an  approach  can,  but  does  not 
necessarily,  result  in  independent  examination  of  the  state  constitution 
or  in  recognition  of  rights  under  state  law  that  are  greater  in  scope  than 
rights  secured  by  the  sixth  amendment. 

The  independent  states  have  rejected  the  federal  judicial  proceedings 
prerequisite,  while  retaining  critical  stage  analysis.  They  have  regarded 
a  pretrial  lineup  as  such  a  stage,  at  which  counsel's  presence  is  required, 
as  a  matter  of  the  court's  supervisory  powers,  state  statute,  or  consti- 
tutional provision.  That  approach  can  culminate  in  recognition  of  a 


In  contrast,  "[w]hen  the  [federal  Bill  of  Rights  was  adopted,  there  were  no  organized 
police  forces  as  we  know  them  today."  United  States  v.  Wade,  388  U.S.  218,  224  (1967) 
(citing  authorities). 

242.  Historical  sources  for  interpreting  state  constitutions  can  be  scarce  for  a  variety 
of  reasons.  For  example,  in  a  typical  fit  of  fiscal  conservatism,  the  delegates  to  the  Texas 
Constitutional  Convention  of  1875  voted  (53-31)  against  efforts  to  authorize  payment  to 
have  a  public  record  made  of  the  debates  during  the  proceedings.  S.  McKay,  supra  note 
218,  at  77. 

243.  See,  e.g.,  P.  Bobbitt,  Constitutional  Fate  (1982)  (explaining  alternative  ap- 
proaches to  constitutional  interpretation),  cited  with  approval  in  State  v.  Ramseur,  106 
N.J.  123,  524  A.2d  188  (1987);  State  v.  Jewett,  146  Vt.  221,  500  A.2d  233  (1985).  See 
also  Utter  &  Pitler,  Presenting  State  Constitutional  Arguments:  Comment  on  Theory  and 
Technique,  20  Ind.  L.  Rev.  635  (1987). 

244.  Marcus,  State  Constitutional  Protection  for  Defendants  in  Criminal  Prosecu- 
tions, 20  Ariz.  St.  L.J.  151,  169  (1988)  (citing  Galie,  State  Constitutional  Guarantees 
and  the  Alaska  Court:  Criminal  Procedure  Rights  and  the  New  Federalism,  1960-81,  18 
GoNZ.  L.  Rev.  221,  259  (1983));  People  v.  Hawkins,  55  N.Y.2d  474,  495,  450  N.Y.S.2d 
159,  171,  435  N.E.2d  376,  388  (1982)  (Meyer,  J.,  dissenting)  (until  real  problems  for  law 
enforcement  have  been  shown  to  stem  from  presence  of  counsel  at  prearraignment  lineups 
in  Alaska,  California,  Michigan,  and  Pennsylvania,  nothing  except  speculation  weighs  in 
constitutional  balance  against  requiring  counsel). 


938  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:905 

broader  scope  for  the  right  to  counsel  under  state  law  than  that  provided 
under  the  sixth  amendment. 

In  light  of  the  psychological  studies  showing  the  dangers  of  lineup 
identifications,  and  the  widespread  legal  criticism  of  the  federal  formula, 
it  is  time  for  more  state  courts  to  examine  the  interplay  between  state 
and  federal  provisions,  or  to  analyze  state  constitutions  independently, 
and  to  '  terminate  the  guardianship  "^"^^  that  the  federal  courts  have 
exercised  over  the  rights  of  criminal  suspects,  especially  the  right  to 
counsel  at  Uneups, 


245.     Duncan,  Terminating  the  Guardianship:  A  New  Role  for  State  Courts,  19  St. 
Mary's  L.J.  809  (1988). 


PARTIAL  SETTLEMENT  OF  MULTIPLE 

TORTFEASOR  CASES  UNDER  THE  INDIANA 

COMPARATIVE  FAULT  ACT 

I.     Introduction 

Indiana  adopted  statutory  comparative  fault  in  1983,  effective  Jan. 
1,  1985.*  Although  Indiana  courts  have  stated  that  settlement  and  com- 
promise are  encouraged  by  the  law^,  the  Indiana  Comparative  Fault  Act 
makes  no  provision  for  settlement.  The  Uniform  Comparative  Fault  Act^ 
and  the  legislation"*  or  judicial  decisions   of  several  other  States^   ac- 

1.  IND.  Code  §§  34-4-33-1  to  34-4-33-14,  effective  Jan.  1,  1985.  Section  2  of 
P.L.  317-1983,  which  enacted  this  statute,  provided  that  the  statute  would  not  apply  to 
any  action  accruing  before  its  effective  date.  See  Bayliff,  Drafting  and  Legislative  History 
of  the  Comparative  Fault  Act,  17  Ind.  L.  Rev.  863,  873  (1984)  for  an  overview  of  the 
amendments  to  the  Act  made  before  its  effective  date. 

2.  See,  e.g.  Kavanaugh  v.  Butorac,  140  Ind.  App.  139,  221  N.E.2d  824,  829 
(1966)  (evidence  of  unsuccessful  settlement  negotiations  excluded  so  as  not  to  penalize  one 
who  has  made  an  effort  to  compromise  a  claim  out  of  court);  Indiana  Insurance  Co.  v. 
Handlon,  216  Ind.  442,  447,  24  N.E.2d  1(X)3,  1005  (1939)  (same  issue  as  above,  stating: 
"Since  it  is  the  policy  of  the  law  to  favor  and  encourage  the  compromise  of  differences, 
one  who  makes  an  unsuccessful  effort  toward  that  end  should  not  be  penahzed.")  The 
courts  of  other  jurisdictions  agree,  one  going  so  far  as  to  state:  "Compromises  are  favored 
by  the  Court.  This  is  such  a  universal  rule  as  to  require  no  citation  of  authority."  State 
Highway  Comm'n  v.  Arms,   163  Mont.  487,  490,  518  P.2d  35,  37  (1974). 

3.  Unif.  Comparative  Fault  Act  §  6,  12  U.L.A.  37  (Supp,  1988),  and  Comment 
thereto.  See  also  Unif.  Contribution  Among  Tortfeasors  Act  §  4,  12  U.L.A.  57  (1975 
&  Supp.  1988).  The  Uniform  Contribution  Among  Tortfeasors  Act  has  been  adopted  by 
eighteen  states,  but  the  Prefatory  Note  to  the  Uniform  Comparative  Fault  Act  states: 

Both  of  [the  Uniform  Contribution  Acts  (1939  and  1955)]  provide  for  pro  rata 
contribution,  which  may  be  suitable  in  a  state  not  applying  the  principle  of 
comparative  fault,  but  is  inappropriate  in  a  comparative-fault  state  apportioning 
ultimate  responsibility  on  the  basis  of  the  proportionate  fault  of  all  the  parties 
involved.  ... 

It  has  .  .  .  been  decided  not  to  amend  the  separate  Uniform  Contribution  Among 

Tortfeasors  Act,  1955,  but  to  leave  the  act  for  possible  use  by  states  not  adopting 

the  principle  of  comparative  fault. 

Unif.  Comparative  Fault  Act,  Prefatory  Note,  12  U.L.A.  37,  38  (Supp.  1988).  For  an 

analysis  of  the  Uniform  Contribution  Among  Tortfeasors  Act,  see  Note,  Settlement  in 

Joint  Tort  Cases,  18  Stan.  L.  Rev.  486  (1966). 

4.  See,  e.g.  N.H.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  §  507:7h  (Supp.  1988),  (makes  provision  for 
effect  of  release  or  covenant  not  to  sue,  settlement  to  reduce  claim  of  plaintiff  by  amount 
of  consideration  given);  Alaska  Stat.  §  09.17.090  (1986)  (provides  that  a  release  or 
covenant  not  to  sue  releases  only  the  agreeing  tortfeasor,  credits  the  remaining  defendants 
with  the  amount  given,  and  discharges  the  tortfeasor  from  any  responsibility  for  contri- 
bution); Ariz.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  §§  12-2501(D),  12-2504(1)  and  (2)  (1984). 

5.  See,  e.g.  American  Motorcycle  Ass'n  v.  Superior  Court,  20  Cal.  3d  578,  146 
Cal.  Rptr.  182,  578  P. 2d  899  (1978)  (providing  for  reduction  of  award  by  amount  of 
settlement);  Giem  v.  Williams,  215  Ark.  705,  222  S.W.2d  800  (1949). 

939 


940  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

knowledge  the  importance  of  compromise  and  settlement  by  providing 
for  it  specifically. 

The  purpose  of  this  Note  is  to  examine  some  of  the  possibilities 
and  problems  of  the  Indiana  Act  in  the  context  of  settlement  by  one 
of  multiple  tortfeasors  under  the  statute.  Since  settlement  does  not  take 
place  in  a  vacuum,  consideration  of  several  corollary  or  threshold  ques- 
tions is  necessary.  Therefore,  the  analysis  will  focus  not  only  on  settlement 
itself,  but  on  the  threshold  issues  to  settlement,  including  joint  and 
several  hability  and  contribution,  and  the  decision  as  to  whose  fault  will 
be  considered  in  any  allocation.  This  will  be  accomplished  by  posing 
questions  which  will  inevitably  arise  under  the  Act  in  the  multiple 
tortfeasor-settlement  context,  and  then  undertaking  an  examination  of 
the  caselaw  and  legislation  of  selected  other  states  with  an  eye  toward 
comparing  and  contrasting  them  to  Indiana's  new  Act  and  its  existing 
caselaw.  This  comparison  will  highlight  the  questions  which  Indiana 
courts  will  be  called  upon  to  answer,  and  will  show  the  potential  problems 
caused  by  omission  of  definite  guidelines  for  the  consequences  of  set- 
tlement in  a  multiple  tortfeasor  context. 

The  primary  states  used  for  comparison  will  be  Kansas  and  Min- 
nesota, with  other  states  illustrating  specific  points.  Kansas  enacted  its 
comparative  fault  act  in  1974.^  The  Kansas  Act  abolishes  joint  and 
several  liability,''  making  each  tortfeasor  responsible  only  for  her^  own 
percentage  of  the  total  award.  Kansas  defendants  may  bring  in  ** ad- 
ditional parties"  or  * 'phantom  tortfeasors,"  the  rough  equivalent  of 
Indiana's  nonparties,  and  have  their  fault  considered  along  with  the 
fault  of  parties  to  the  action.^  Kansas  courts  have  not  allowed  contribution 
among  tortfeasors. '°  These  factors  tend  to  make  Kansas'  comparative 
fault  the  most  analogous  to  Indiana's  at  this  time,  affording  a  wealth 
of  case  law  upon  which  to  predict  how  Indiana  courts  might  react  to 
the  new  Comparative  Fault  Act. 

Minnesota's  Comparative  Fault  Act'^  resembles  the  Uniform  Com- 
parative Fault  Act.^^  However,  the  Minnesota  legislature  has  never  of- 


6.  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-25 8a  (Supp.   1987). 

7.  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-25 8a(cl),  as  interpreted  in  Brown  v.  Kiell,  224  Kan. 
195,  580  P. 2d  867  (1978).  There  is  still  some  question  regarding  whether  or  not  the  Indiana 
Act  has  had  the  effect  of  abrogating  the  common  law  doctrine  of  joint  and  several 
liability.  See  infra y  notes  46-49  and  accompanying  text. 

8.  The  feminine  pronoun  is  used  throughout  to  represent  both  genders,  except 
when  referring  to  parties  whose  gender  is  specified  by  facts. 

9.  Hardin  v.  Manitowoc-Forsythe  Corp.,  691  F.2d  449  (10th  Cir.  1982). 

10.  See,  e.g.  Kennedy  v.  Sawyer,  228  Kan  439,  447,  618  P.2d  788,  797  (1980). 

11.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §§  604.01  to  604.08  (West  1988). 

12.  Unif.  Comparative  Fault  Act,  12  U.L.A.  37  (Supp.  1988).  The  Uniform  Act 
has  been  adopted  by  Iowa  (Iowa  Code  §§  668.1  to  668.14,  adopted  1984)  and  Washington 
(Wash.  Rev.  Code  §§  4.22.005  to  4.22.925,  adopted  1981). 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  941 

ficially  adopted  the  Uniform  Act.  Instead,  it  modeled  its  original  statute 
on  the  Wisconsin  Contributory  Negligence  Act  and  surrounding  caselaw 
in  1969.^^  Later  amendments  brought  it  closer  to  the  Uniform  Act.  The 
Minnesota  statute  provides  for  joint  and  several  liability, ^"^  and  the  case 
law  surrounding  it  allows  contribution.'^  The  Minnesota  Act  does  not 
provide  for  joinder  of  nonparties.  These  factors  make  the  Minnesota 
comparative  fault  system  almost  diametrically  opposed  to  that  of  Kansas 
(and  perhaps  Indiana)  in  the  settlement  context.  Finally,  the  Minnesota 
statute  specifically  provides  for  partial  settlement  of  claims.'^ 

II.     Indiana  Law  Before  and  After  the  Enactment  of 

Comparative  Fault 

A.    Background:  Settlement  in  Indiana  Prior  to  the  Act 

Prior  to  the  enactment  of  comparative  fault,  Indiana  courts  endorsed 
and  allowed  several  different  types  of  settlement  agreements  between 
plaintiffs  and  one  or  more  joint  tortfeasors.  The  intent  behind  the 
agreement  decided  the  form,  which  then  dictated  its  legal  effect.'^  Set- 
tlement agreements  could  take  a  number  of  different  forms,  including 


13.  The  Wisconsin  Act,  enacted  in  1931,  Wis.  Stat.  Ann.  §  895.045  (West  1983), 
is  one  of  the  oldest  in  the  country.  It  provides: 

"Contributory  negUgence  shall  not  bar  recovery  in  an  action  ...  to  recover 

damages  for  neghgence  resulting  in  death  or  injury  ...  if  such  negligence  was 

not  greater  than  the  negligence  of  the  person  against  whom  recovery  is  sought, 

but  any  damages  allowed  shall  be  diminished  in  proportion  to  the  amount  of 

negligence  attributable  to  the  person  recovering." 

Id.  While  the  statute  itself  is  simple  and  sparse,  it  is  supported  by  a  large  amount  of 

caselaw.  The  Minnesota  Supreme  Court  acknowledged  the  Wisconsin  statute  as  the  source 

of  the  Minnesota  Comparative  Fault  Act  in  Busch  v.  Busch  Const.,  Inc.,  262  N.W.2d 

377,  393  (Minn.  1977)  and  Marier  v.  Memorial  Rescue  Service,  Inc.  296  Minn.  242,  207 

N.W.2d  706  (1973),  which  held  that  the  Minnesota  statute's  basis  in  Wisconsin  law  included 

the  caselaw  and  interpretation  of  the  Wisconsin  statute  up  until  the  time  of  adoption. 

See  also  1969  Committee  Comment,  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01  (West  1988). 

14.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.02(1)  (West  Supp.  1989).  See  generally  Steenson, 
Recent  Legislative  Responses  to  the  Rule  of  Joint  and  Several  Liability,  23  Tort  and 
Insurance  Law  Journal  482  (1988). 

15.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.02(2)  (West  1988).  See  also  supra  note  13. 

16.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01,  subparts  (2),  (3),  (4),  and  (5)  (West  1988). 
Wisconsin's  comparative  negligence  scheme  provides  for  the  consequences  of  settlement 
in  the  Wisconsin  evidence  code.  Wis.  Stat.  Ann.  §  885.285(3)  (West  Supp.  1988). 

17.  Fetz  V.  E  &  L  Truck  Rental  Co.,  670  F.  Supp.  261,  263  (S.D.  Ind.  1987); 
Sanders  v.  Cole  Mun.  Fin.,  489  N.E.2d  117,  120  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1986)  (Hsts  settlement 
options  open  to  plaintiff  and  states  that  intent  of  the  parties  is  relevant  to  the  charac- 
terization of  the  settlement);  Northern  Indiana  Public  Service  Co.  v.  Otis,  145  Ind.  App. 
159,  250  N.E.2d  378,  392  (1969). 


942  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

loan  receipt  agreements, ^^  covenants  not  to  sue,*^  and  covenants  not  to 
execute^^.  These  devices  were  not  considered  releases  per  se.^^ 

The  danger  in  any  settlement  agreement  for  the  plaintiff  was  in  the 
common  law  maxim  that  the  release  of  one  joint  tortfeasors^  served  as 


18.  In  a  loan  receipt  agreement,  a  potentially  liable  defendant  advances  funds  to 
a  plaintiff  in  the  form  of  a  no-interest  loan.  In  exchange,  defendant  receives  a  promise 
not  to  pursue  a  cause  of  action  against  that  defendant.  Fullenkamp  v.  Newcomer,  508 
N.E.2d  37  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1987)  (decided  under  contributory  fault  because  the  cause  accrued 
prior  to  the  effective  date  of  the  Comparative  Fault  Act).  Often,  the  loan  is  paid  back 
out  of  recovery  from  the  defendants  remaining  in  the  case.  American  Transp.  Co.  v. 
Central  Indiana  Ry.  255  Ind.  319,  323,  264  N.E.2d  64,  66  (1970).  Courts  approved  of 
these  transactions  because  they  compensated  plaintiffs  without  the  usual  protracted  wait 
for  a  trial,  and  because  they  allowed  plaintiffs  to  acquire  funds  to  pursue  claims  against 
other  defendants.  Ohio  Valley  Gas,  Inc.  v.  Blackburn,  445  N.E.2d  1378,  1382  (Ind.  Ct. 
App.  1983).  See  also  American  Transp.  Co.,  255  Ind.  at  Zll-li,  264  N.E.2d  at  67; 
Northern  Ind.  Pub.  Serv.  Co.,  145  Ind.  App.  at  179-80,  250  N.E.2d  at  392.  The  amount 
given  for  a  loan  receipt  agreement  does  not  diminish  the  ultimate  award  to  plaintiff 
because  it  is  not  considered  to  be  in  partial  satisfaction,  but  is  looked  at  as  subject  to 
repayment.  Sanders,  489  N.E.2d  at  120;  Barker  v.  Cole,  396  N.E.2d  964  (Ind.  Ct.  App. 
1980).  See  also  Strohmeyer,  Loan  Receipt  Agreements  Revisited:  Recognizing  Substance 
Over  Form,  21  Ind.  L.  Rev.  439  (1988). 

19.  Plaintiff  agreed  in  exchange  for  consideration  not  to  pursue  her  claim  against 
a  settling  tortfeasor.  Plaintiff  did  not  release  or  waive  her  claim  against  that  tortfeasor, 
retaining  the  claim  in  order  to  pursue  it  if  the  settling  tortfeasor  reneged,  and  reserving 
her  claim  against  any  other  tortfeasors.  National  Mut.  Ins.  Co.  v.  Fincher,  428  N.E.2d 
1386,  1388,  nn.4-5  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1981).  The  consideration  paid  under  a  covenant  not 
to  sue  was  in  partial  satisfaction  of  the  claim,  and  therefore  diminished  any  award  the 
plaintiff  ultimately  received.  Sanders,  489  N.E.2d  at  120  (citing  cases). 

20.  Plaintiff,  in  exchange  for  consideration,  would  agree  not  to  execute  any  judg- 
ment received  against  the  tortfeasor,  retaining  her  cause  of  action  against  that  tortfeasor 
and  any  other  potentially  liable  persons.  Barker  v.  Sumney,  185  F.  Supp.  298  (N.D.  Ind. 
1960).  The  covenant  not  to  execute  was  not  dispositive  of  the  issue  of  the  settling  tortfeasor's 
negligence,  and  the  plaintiff  could  pursue  her  suit  to  its  conclusion,  as  the  covenant  would 
not  be  effective  until  a  judgment  was  obtained,  at  which  point  the  settling  tortfeasor 
could  raise  it  as  a  defense  if  plaintiff  sought  to  enforce  the  judgment.  Barker,  185  F. 
Supp.  298;  Sanders,  489  N.E.2d  at  120.  Amounts  obtained  by  plaintiff  under  such  a 
covenant  were  in  partial  satisfaction  of  her  claim  and  so  reduced  her  ultimate  award  pro 
tanto.  Sanders,  489  N.E.2d  at  120. 

21.  Fetz,  670  F.  Supp.  at  262-63  (1986)(citing  cases). 

22.  Joint  liability  may  be  incurred  when  the  acts  of  wrongdoers,  through  cooperation 
or  concert,  injure  a  plaintiff.  Also,  independent  acts  of  several  tortfeasors  which  combine 
to  produce  a  single  injury  may  subject  them  to  joint  liability.  Young  v.  Hoke,  493  N.E.2d 
1279,  1280  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1986).  Independent  successive  acts,  e.g.  an  auto  accident  followed 
by  medical  malpractice  in  the  emergency  room,  may  not  lead  to  joint  responsibility  between 
the  tortfeasors.  Wecker  v.  Kilmer,  260  Ind.  198,  294  N.E.2d  132  (1973).  This  Note  will 
not  deal  with  determination  of  the  jointness  of  responsibility  of  tortfeasors,  assuming  that 
aspect  in  dealing  with  settlement  questions. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  943 

a  release  of  all.^^  In  Cooper  v.  Robert  Hall  Clothes, ^'^  the  Supreme  Court 
of  Indiana  vacated  a  Court  of  Appeals  judgment^^  dealing  with  a  doc- 
ument which  was  entitled  "Release,"  but  which  had  reserved  certain 
parts  of  plaintiff's  cause  of  action  against  another  defendant  in  the 
action. 2^  The  Court  of  Appeals  had  attempted  to  abandon  the  common 
law  rule  and  institute  instead  the  Restatement  rule,^''  which  would  allow 
a  plaintiff  to  give  a  release  to  one  joint  tortfeasor  without  releasing  all. 
The  Indiana  Supreme  Court  expressly  rejected  the  Restatement,^^  stressing 
the  difference  between  transactions  such  as  covenants  not  to  sue  and 
releases.  A  release  entirely  waived  a  claim,  rendering  a  reservation  of 
part  of  a  claim  inconsistent  and  void.^^  The  court  stated  that  the  purpose 
of  this  rule  was  to  prevent  a  plaintiff  from  recovering  in  excess  of  her 
actual  damages  by  piecemeal  settlements  with  various  defendants. ^°  Ad- 
ditionally, the  court  stressed  that  because  joint  tortfeasors  constitute  one 
jointly  and  severally  liable  entity,  a  release  of  part  of  that  entity  ac- 
knowledged that  none  of  the  components  of  the  entity  were  liable.^'  A 
plaintiff  also  ran  the  risk  of  having  a  covenant  not  to  sue  or  execute 
held  to  be  a  release  as  to  all  tortfeasors  if  the  consideration  which  a 
settUng  tortfeasor  paid  equaled  all  of  plaintiff's  damages. ^^ 

This  settlement  and  release  regime  inevitably  worked  injustices  on 
various  parties.  Plaintiffs  were  disadvantaged  if  they  executed  a  contract 


23.  Cooper  v.  Robert  Hall  Clothes,  Inc.,  390  N.E.2d  155  (Ind.  1979);  Bedwell  v. 
DeBolt,  221  Ind.  600,  609,  50  N.E.  875,  878  (1943);  Cleveland,  C,  C.  &  St.  L.  Ry.  v. 
Hilligoss,  171  Ind.  417,  422-23,  86  N.E.  485,  487  (1908).  "Release"  is  defined  in  Standard 
Auto  Ins.  Ass'n  v.  Reese,  83  Ind.  App.  500,  149  N.E.  137  (1925):  "A  release  is  the  act 
or  writing  by  which  some  claim  or,  interest  is  surrendered  to  another  person  ....  It  is 
a  species  of  contract,  and  like  any  other  contract,  it  must  have  a  consideration."  Id.  at 
503,  149  N.E.  at  138  (quoting  Jaqua  v.  Shewalter,  10  Ind.  App.  234,  36  N.E.  173  (1893), 
reh'g  denied,  37  N.E.  1072  (1894)).  See  also  Prosser,  Handbook  of  the  Law  of  Torts 
§  49  (1971). 

24.  390  N.E.2d  155  (Ind.   1979). 

25.  Cooper  v.  Robert  Hall  Clothes,  Inc.,  375  N.E.2d  1142  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1978). 

26.  Parts  of  the  release  document  are  reproduced  in  Cooper,  390  N.E. 2d  at  156- 
57. 

27.  Restatement  (Second)  of  Torts  §  885(1)  (1965)  provides:  "A  valid  release 
of  one  tortfeasor  from  liability  for  a  harm,  given  by  the  injured  person,  does  not  discharge 
others  liable  for  the  same  harm,  unless  it  is  agreed  that  it  will  discharge  them." 

28.  Cooper,  390  N.E.2d  at  157. 

29.  Id. 

30.  Id. 

31.  Id. 

32.  Bedwell  v.  Debolt,  221  Ind.  600,  609,  50  N.E.2d  875,  879;  Moffett  v.  Gene 
B.  Click  Co.,  Inc.,  621  F.  Supp.  244,  289  (N.D.  Ind.  1985).  In  Scott  v.  Krueger,  151 
Ind.  App.  479,  514,  280  N.E.2d  336,  357  (1972),  the  court  stated  that  the  amount  paid 
could  be  brought  before  the  jury,  who  would  then  decide  whether  it  had  served  to  satisfy 
all  plaintiff's  damages  and  would  therefore  be  a  release.  Id. 


944  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

believing  it  to  be  a  covenant  and  the  court  found  it  to  be  a  release," 
thereby  denying  plaintiffs  a  full  recovery.  Inequities  to  settling  defendants 
also  resulted  because  the  settUng  joint  tortfeasor  had  no  right  of  con- 
tribution against  the  other  tortfeasors  who  benefitted  when  the  contract 
was  found  to  be  a  release,  or  when  a  covenant  not  to  sue  was  found 
to  fully  satisfy  plaintiff's  damages. ^"^  This  meant  that  the  settUng  de- 
fendant was  released,  but  other,  perhaps  more  blameworthy,  defendants 
paid  nothing  at  all.  The  settling  defendant  could  not  get  any  repayment 
from  other  defendants  for  procuring  their  release  because  contribution 
was  not  allowed. 

When  a  covenant  not  to  sue  or  not  to  execute  was  held  to  be  valid, 
that  is,  it  did  not  release  all  the  tortfeasors,  only  the  one  who  executed 
the  settlement,  the  remaining  defendants  suffered.  Joint  and  several 
liability, ^^  combined  with  the  fact  that  plaintiff's  award  was  diminished 
only  by  the  dollar  amount  of  the  settlement, ^^  meant  that  the  remaining 
defendants  would  pay  the  entire  balance  of  any  award,  regardless  of 
how  faulty  they  were.  The  remaining  defendants  would  have  no  right 
to  seek  contribution  from  the  settHng  tortfeasor.  Indeed,  they  had  no 
right  to  seek  contribution  against  any  of  their  fellow  joint  tortfeasors.^'' 


33.  See  Cooper,  390  N.E.2d  155.  Although  both  the  appellate  court  and  supreme 
court  clearly  found  the  Cooper  settlement  to  be  a  release,  it  is  logical  to  assume  that 
since  the  plaintiff  included  a  reservation  of  rights  against  the  remaining  defendants  she 
thought  that  she  could  do  so  and  have  the  release  operate  as  a  covenant  not  to  sue.  This 
becomes  even  more  obvious  when  the  amounts  given  in  exchange  for  the  release  are 
considered:  plaintiff  originally  stated  her  claim  at  Seventy-Five  Thousand  Dollars,  and 
settled  with  one  defendant  for  One  Thousand  Nine  Hundred  and  Ninety  Nine  Dollars 
and  the  other  defendant  for  Ten  Dollars.  Id.  at  156. 

34.  Sanders  v.  Cole  Mun.  Fin.,  489  N.E.2d  117,  121.  See  Recent  Decisions,  Release 
of  Joint  Tortfeasors — Document  Styled  "Covenant  Not  To  Sue"  Held  to  Amount  to 
Release,  36  Notre  Dame  Lawyer  443  (1960). 

35.  Indiana  followed  the  common  law  doctrine  of  joint  and  several  liability  which 
allowed  a  plaintiff  to  recover  all  her  damages  from  any  one  of  the  named  defendants 
against  whom  she  received  a  judgment.  Barker  v.  Cole,  396  N.E.2d  964,  971  (Ind.  Ct. 
App.  1979) 

36.  Sanders,  489  N.E.2d  117,  120.  Amounts  received  by  a  plaintiff  under  a  loan 
receipt  agreement  did  not  diminish  the  final  award  at  all.  Id.  See  supra  note  18. 

37.  Contribution  is  a  system  by  which  a  tortfeasor  who  has  paid  plaintiff's  full 
damages  or  more  than  that  defendant's  equal  share  is  entitled  to  seek  repayment  from 
the  other  joint  tortfeasors.  The  shares  were  calculated  on  a  pro  rata  basis,  that  is,  the 
full  amount  of  the  judgment  was  divided  by  the  number  of  tortfeasors  liable,  each  defendant 
being  responsible  for  her  equal  share.  This  is  a  traditional  common  law  doctrine.  See 
Prosser,  Handbook  of  the  Law  of  Torts  50.  There  has  never  been  a  right  to  contribution 
among  joint  tortfeasors  in  Indiana.  Barker  v.  Cole,  396  N.E.2d  964,  971;  The  American 
Express  Co.  v.  Patterson,  73  Ind.  430,  436  (1881);  Hunt  v.  Lane,  9  Ind.  248  (1857).  See 
also  Recent  Decisions,  Torts-Joint  Tortfeasors-Contribution-Exceptions,  6  Notre  Dame 
Lawyer  267  (1930-1931). 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  945 

A  loan  receipt  agreement  did  not  diminish  plaintiffs  award  at  all  and 
left  the  remaining  nonprevailing  defendants  to  pay  the  whole  amount, 
with  any  sort  of  repayment  of  the  loan  being  a  contractual  matter 
between  plaintiff  and  settHng  tortfeasor. ^^  These  features  combined  to 
make  settlement  relatively  predictable,  despite  the  technical  risks  to  un- 
wary settlers  (especially  the  release  rule)  characterized  as  '*boobytraps" 
by  the  drafters  of  the  Restatement  rule.^^ 

B.     The  Indiana  Comparative  Fault  Act 

In  1985,  Indiana  joined  the  numerous  states  which  have  adopted 
some  form  of  comparative  fault. '^'^  The  Indiana  Act  strongly  emphasizes 
the  procedural  aspects  of  comparative  fault."*'  The  basic  change  in  the 
law  made  by  this  statute  is,  of  course,  that  contributory  fault  no  longer 
bars  a  plaintiff's  recovery  against  a  tortfeasor  unless  the  plaintiff's  fault 
is  "greater  than  the  fault  of  all  persons  whose  fault  proximately  con- 
tributed to  the  claimant's  damages.'"*^ 

1.  Joint  and  Several  Liability  and  Contribution. — Section  34-4-3-5(b) 
of  the  Indiana  Act  gives  the  jury  explicit  instructions  on  how  to  apportion 
the  fault  of  multiple  parties.'*^  It  makes  no  provision,  however,  for  how 


38.  In  Northern  Indiana  Public  Service  Co.  v.  Otis,  the  court  noted  that  "authorities 
from  Indiana  and  other  jurisdictions  certainly  provide  for  the  use  of  a  loan  receipt 
agreement  and  use  of  the  same  is  neither  contribution  among  joint  tortfeasors  or  [sic] 
an  assignment  of  a  cause  of  action  sounding  in  tort."  145  Ind.  App.  159,  180,  250  N.E.2d 
378,  392-93.  (citing  cases  collected  in  1  A.L.R.  1528,  132  A.L.R.  607,  and  157  A.L.R. 
1261),  A  loan  receipt  agreement  could  be  considered  an  "end  run"  on  the  prohibition 
against  contribution  insofar  as  the  loaning  party  was  paid  back  out  of  the  proceeds  of 
judgments  against  other  parties.  See  Strohmeyer,  supra  note  18. 

39.  Restatment  (Second)  of  Torts  §  885,  Comment  (d)  (1965). 

40.  Ind.  Pub.  L.  317-1983  (which  enacted  most  of  the  provisions  of  Ind.  Code 
§§  34-4-33-1  to  -14  in  1983);  Ind.  Pub.  L.  174-1984  (which  amended  various  sections  of 
the  Act).  Each  provided  that  its  effective  date  was  to  be  January  1,  1985.  For  a  list  of 
the  states  which  had  judicially  or  legislatively  adopted  comparative  fault  or  comparative 
negligence  before  Indiana,  see  Smith  and  Wade,  Fairness:  A  Comparative  Analysis  of  the 
Indiana  and  Uniform  Comparative  Fault  Acts,  17  Ind.  L,  Rev.  969,  n.3  (1984). 

41.  See,  e.g.  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-5  (1988)  (providing  the  procedure  by  which  a 
jury  arrives  at  the  ultimate  allocation  of  fault  and  recovery);  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-6  (1988) 
(providing  for  special  verdict  forms);  and  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-10  (1988)  (providing  for 
nonparty  defense,  including  time  for  pleading  and  burden  of  proof). 

42.  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-4(b)  (1988).  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-3  (1988)  provides:  "In 
an  action  based  on  fault,  any  contributory  fault  chargeable  to  the  claimant  diminishes 
proportionally  the  amount  awarded  as  compensatory  damages  for  an  injury  attributable 
to  the  claimant's  contributory  fault,  but  does  not  bar  recovery  except  as  provided  in 
section  4  of  this  chapter." 

43.  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-5(b)  (1988)  provides: 

In  an  action  based  on  fault  that  is  brought  against  two  (2)  or  more  defendants. 


946  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

a  settlement  might  affect  the  apportionment  of  fault  or  how  any  award 
of  damages  might  be  diminished  by  a  settlement  between  a  plaintiff  and 
one  of  several  defendants.'^  The  Act  is  also  silent  on  the  topic  of  joint 
and  several  Kability,  which  has  sparked  a  debate  among  the  legal  scholars 
of  Indiana  as  to  whether  the  joint  and  several  Hability  doctrine  survived 
the  enactment  of  the  Comparative  Fault  Act/^  Some  of  these  scholars 
and  writers  have  assumed  the  abrogation  of  joint  and  several  liability/^ 
while  others  have  assumed  its  continued  existence  or  argued  in  favor 
of  retention  of  the  doctrine/^ 


and  that  is  tried  to  a  jury,  the  court,  unless  all  the  parties  agree  otherwise, 
shall  instruct  the  jury  to  determine  its  verdict  in  the  following  manner: 

(1)  The  jury  shall  determine  the  percentage  of  fault  of  the  claimant,  of  the 
defendants,  and  of  any  person  who  is  a  nonparty.  The  percentage  of  fault 
figures  of  parties  to  the  action  may  total  less  than  one  hundred  percent  (100%) 
if  the  jury  finds  that  fault  contributing  to  cause  the  claimant's  loss  has  also 
come  from  a  nonparty  or  nonparties. 

(2)  If  the  percentage  of  fault  of  the  claimant  is  greater  than  fifty  percent 
(50%)  of  the  total  fault  involved  in  the  incident  which  caused  the  claimant's 
death,  injury,  or  property  damage,  the  jury  shall  return  a  verdict  for  the 
defendants  and  no  further  deliberation  of  the  jury  is  required. 

(3)  If  the  percentage  of  fault  of  the  claimant  is  not  greater  than  fifty  percent 
(50%)  of  the  total  fault, the  jury  shall  then  determine  the  total  amount  of 
damages  the  claimant  would  be  entitled  to  recover  if  contributory  fault  were 
disregarded. 

(4)  The  jury  next  shall  multiply  the  percentage  of  fault  of  each  defendant  by 
the  amount  of  damages  determined  under  subdivision  (3)  and  shall  enter  a 
verdict  against  each  such  defendant  (and  such  other  defendants  as  are  liable 
with  the  defendant  by  reason  of  their  relationship  to  such  defendant)  in  the 
amount  of  the  product  of  the  multiplication  of  each  defendant's  percentage 
of  fault  times  the  amount  of  damages  as  determined  under  subdivision  (3). 

Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-5(b)  (1988).  See  also  suggested  jury  verdict  forms  in  Indianapolis 
Bar  Association  Young  Lawyer's  Division  Handbook,  Super  Saturday  in  Court  -  Com- 
parative Fault  (April  9,  1988). 

44.  Mr.  BayUff,  one  of  the  drafters  of  the  Act,  states,  "Jurors  will  simply  diminish 
the  claimant's  recovery  by  the  percentage  of  fault  (not  by  the  amount  paid)  of  the 
tortfeasors  who  have  settled."  Bayliff,  Drafting  and  Legislative  History  of  the  Indiana 
Comparative  Fault  Act,  17  Ind.  L.  Rev.  863,  869  (1984).  This  assumes  the  abrogation 
of  joint  and  several  liability. 

45.  See  generally.  Symposium  on  Indiana's  Comparative  Fault  Act,  17  Ind.  L. 
Rev.  (1984).  This  has  been  an  issue  in  other  states  when  comparative  systems  are  adopted 
legislatively  and  judicially.  See  H.  Woods,  Comparative  Fault  §  13:4  (1987). 

46.  See  Bayliff,  supra  note  44,  at  867,  stating  that  the  Act  "implicitly  abrogates 
the  traditional  rule  of  joint  and  several  liability  for  concurrent  wrongs";  Easterday  and 
Easterday,  The  Indiana  Comparative  Fault  Act:  How  Does  It  Compare  With  Other 
Jurisdictions?,  17  Ind.  L.  Rev.  883,  899  (1984);  Eilbacher,  Nonparty  Tortfeasors  in  Indiana: 
The  Early  Cases,  21  Ind.  L.  Rev.  413,  417.  (1988)  (assuming  the  abolition  of  joint  and 
several  liability).  Other  non-Indiana  authors  have  also  assumed  the  abrogation  of  joint 
and  several  liability  by  the  Indiana  statute.  See,  e.g.  2  Matthew  Bender,  Comparative 
Negligence  §  13.20(31  (1984);  H.  Woods,  Comparative  Fault,  app.,  at  587  (1987). 

47.  See  Pardieck,  The  Impact  of  Comparative  Fault  in  Indiana,  17  Ind.  L.  Rev. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  947 

The  importance  of  joint  and  several  liability  to  settlement  lies  in  its 
effect  on  the  ultimate  award  to  a  plaintiff,  who  will  recover  fully  if 
she  can  arrive  at  the  full  award  by  a  combination  of  the  settlement 
amount  and  recovery  from  the  tortfeasors  remaining  in  the  action.  For 
defendants,  the  effect  of  joint  and  several  liability  can  be  that  one 
defendant  ends  up  paying  the  entire  judgment  (because  of  insolvency 
or  unavailability  of  co-tortfeasors)  without  being  able  to  resort  to  con- 
tribution to  recoup  some  of  the  amount  paid.  This  is  problematic  in 
that  the  purpose  of  the  allocation  of  proportional  fault  is  defeated  if 
a  plaintiff  may  recover  more  than  a  defendant's  allocated  share  of  the 
damages  from  that  defendant.  As  Lawrence  Wilkins  points  out  in  his 
article  analyzing  the  Indiana  Act: 

Adoption  of  comparative  fault  signals  the  embrace  of  a  policy 
of  refining  the  compensation  function  of  tort  law  in  order  that 
injured  parties'  needs  may  be  more  widely  and  accurately  served. 
Abolition  of  joint  and  several  liability  operates  against  that 
policy.  At  the  same  time,  the  fairness  element  inherent  in  the 
comparative  fault  system  powerfully  favors  the  interests  of  tort- 
feasors who  rightfully  claim  that  liability  apportioned  to  fault 
is  meaningless  if  they  are  made  to  bear  more  than  their  assessed 
percentage  of  fault. '^^ 

In  Gray  v.  Chacon, "^^  Judge  Barker  of  the  Southern  District  of 
Indiana  cited  the  abrogation  of  joint  and  several  liability  as  one  of  the 
reasons  for  the  demise  of  the  release  rule  under  Indiana's  Comparative 
Fault  Act.^^  Referring  to  the  Indiana  Supreme  Court's  justifications  for 


925,  936-938  (1984)  (arguing  that  the  policies  of  tort  law  and  the  availability  of  insurance 
militate  in  favor  of  the  retention  of  joint  and  several  liability,  especially  in  cases  where 
the  plaintiff  is  fault-free);  Schwartz,  Comparative  Negligence  in  Indiana:  A  Unique  Statute 
That  Will  Reshape  the  Law,  17  Ind.  L.  Rev.  957,  967  (1984)  (assuming  that  the  statute 
has  preserved  joint  and  several  liability).  One  author  notes  the  arguments  of  both  sides 
and  recommends  solutions  that  neither  entirely  abrogate  joint  and  several  liability  nor 
keep  it  intact.  Wilkins,  The  Indiana  Comparative  Fault  Act  at  First  (Lingering)  Glance, 
17  iND.  L.  Rev.  687,  717  (1984). 

48.  Wilkins,  supra  note  47  at  717.  The  polar  policies  mentioned  by  Professor 
Wilkins  are  in  this  Note  termed  "allocation  oriented"  (favoring  the  precise  allocation  of 
fault  and  the  idea  that  each  should  be  responsible  only  for  her  own  share  of  fault)  and 
"compensation  oriented"  (favoring  full  compensation  of  injured  parties,  even  at  the  expense 
of  defendants).  Professor  Wilkins  points  out  that  the  abrogation  of  joint  and  several 
liability  will  curtail  the  use  of  such  devices  as  the  loan  receipt  agreement,  because  if  the 
plaintiff  must  repay  the  loan  from  her  proportional  recovery  from  remaining  defendants, 
she  has  not  only  lost  the  proportional  recovery  from  the  settling  defendant,  but  has  her 
remaining  recovery  from  the  other  defendants  diminished  by  the  amount  of  repayment. 
Id.  at  719,  n.l56. 

49.  684  F.  Supp.   1481  (S.D.  Ind.   1988). 

50.  Id.  at  1485. 


948  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

the  release  rule  set  forth  in  Cooper  v.  Robert  Hall  Clothes,^^  Judge 
Barker  concluded  that  the  Comparative  Fault  Act  removed  any  danger 
of  a  plaintiff  receiving  more  than  her  proven  damages  by  piecemeal 
successive  settlement."  This  is  because  no  defendant  or  nonparty  would 
ever  be  required  to  pay  more  than  her  own  share  of  fault,  and  no 
incentive  exists  under  the  Act  for  a  tortfeasor  to  settle  and  be  released 
for  more  than  her  estimated  proportion  of  fault."  Judge  Barker  further 
stated:  '*[D]ue  to  the  Act's  abolition  of  joint  and  several  liability  multiple 
tortfeasors  can  no  longer  be  properly  considered  as  'one  entity'  in 
Indiana.  .  .  .  [F]ar  from  being  'one  entity,'  joint  defendants  in  Indiana 
are  now  as  separate  and  independent  from  each  other  as  they  are  from 
the  plaintiff  herself.  "^"^  Acknowledging  that  "it  is  possible  to  create  a 
'law  professor's'  argument  in  favor  of  the  notion  that  the  Act  retained 
joint  and  several  liability,  .  .  .  such  an  interpretation  lacks  persuasive 
force  and  is  at  odds  with  the  legislative  motivation  otherwise  evidenced 
throughout  the  Act."^^  It  is  unclear  what  the  effect  of  this  dicta  will 
be  because  no  Indiana  state  court  has  made  a  pronouncement  on  whether 
joint  and  several  liability  has  survived,  whether  intact  or  modified. 

One  result  effected  by  the  Gray  decision  with  regard  to  settlement 
under  the  Comparative  Fault  Act  is  that  the  court  made  it  abundantly 
clear  that  the  common  law  release  rule^^  has  no  place  in  a  comparative 
fault  system  which  does  not  incorporate  joint  and  several  liability."  The 
court  recommended,  instead,  adoption  of  the  Restatement  Section  885 
rule:  release  of  one  tortfeasor  does  not  serve  to  release  all  unless  intended 
to  do  so.^^  This  position  is  in  keeping  with  that  expressed  in  Young  v. 
Hoke,^^  a  case  decided  by  the  Indiana  Court  of  Appeals.  Young  was 
decided  under  the  old  contributory  negligence  scheme  because  the  cause 
of  action  accrued  before  the  1985  effective  date  of  the  Comparative 
Fault  Act.^°  Although  the  result  in  the  case  was  that  the  release  rule 
was  applied,^*  concurring  and  dissenting  opinions  questioned  its  continued 
vitality. 


51.  271  Ind.  63,  390  N.E.2d  155  (1979). 

52.  Gray,  684  F.  Supp.  at  1484.  See  supra  notes  23-32  and  accompanying  text. 

53.  Gray,  684  F.  Supp.  at  1484. 

54.  Id.  at  1485  (footnote  omitted). 

55.  Id.  at  n.6. 

56.  See  supra  text  accompanying  notes  24  -36. 

57.  Gray,  684  F.  Supp.  at  1485. 

58.  Restatement  (Second)  of  Torts  §  885  (1965):  See  supra  note  27. 

59.  493  N.E.2d  1279  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1986). 

60.  Id.  The  Young's  cause  of  action  arose  out  of  an  automobile  accident  which 
took  place  on  December  18,  1981.  Id. 

61.  Id.  at  1280. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  949 

The  concurring  opinion  compared  the  Indiana  Act  to  that  of  Kansas 
and  noted  that  Kansas  courts  reasoned  that  the  release  rule  no  longer 
applied  under  the  Kansas  comparative  fault  system. ^^  The  concurrence 
agreed  that  the  release  rule  should  apply  in  cases  not  within  the  ambit 
of  the  Comparative  Fault  Act,  declining  to  join  the  dissent  in  advocating 
an  abrogation  of  the  release  rule  in  that  particular  case,"  but  stated 
clearly  that  the  release  rule  should  not  apply  to  cases  where  fault  is 
proportioned.  This  reasoning,  like  that  in  Gray,  was  based  on  an  as- 
sumption that  Indiana,  like  Kansas,  left  joint  and  several  liability  behind 
in  enacting  comparative  fault. ^"^  The  effect  of  the  Gray  opinion  and  the 
Young  concurrence  regarding  the  release  rule  will  depend  on  the  decisions 
Indiana  courts  eventually  make  on  the  issue  of  joint  and  several  liability 
and  how  they  interact  with  proportioned  fault. 

These  decisions  will  be  affected  by  the  fact  that  the  Act  unambig- 
uously continues  Indiana's  common  law  bar  against  contribution  between 
tortfeasors:  '*In  an  action  under  this  chapter,  there  is  no  right  of 
contribution  among  tortfeasors."^^  Contribution  has  been  looked  upon 
as  balancing  joint  and  several  liability,  ameliorating  its  harsh  effect  on 
defendants  forced  to  pay  plaintiff's  entire  damages  despite  the  presence 
of  other  defendants  who  should  rightfully  pay  a  share. ^^  With  contribution 
statutorily  circumscribed,  courts  might  feel  constrained  to  abrogate  joint 
and  several  liability  in  order  to  avoid  the  unbalanced,  harsh  effect  on 
defendants  which  would  result  with  joint  and  several  liability  only.^^ 

2.  The  Nonparty  Provisions  of  the  Act. — The  Indiana  Act  makes 
specific  provision  for  consideration  of  the  fault  of  tortfeasors  not  parties 
to  the  action. ^^  According  to  Section  34-4-33-5(b)(l)  of  the  Act,  the  jury 
is  to  be  instructed  to  * 'determine  the  percentage  of  fault  of  the  claimant, 


62.  Id. 

63.  The  dissent,  written  by  Judge  Garrard,  attacked  the  release  rule  on  the  basis 
of  pohcy,  stating  that  the  rule  is  outdated  and  an  anachronism  which  fails  to  give  effect 
to  the  clear  intent  of  the  parties.  Id.  at  1281-1283. 

64.  Id.  at  1280-81. 

65.  IND.  Code  §  34-4-33-7  (1988). 

66.  See  Prosser,  Handbook  of  the  Law  of  Torts  §  50  (1971). 

67.  See  Wilkins,  supra  note  47,  at  718.  Wilkins  notes:  "Why  the  Indiana  legislature 
considered  it  necessary  to  include  the  ban  is  open  to  question,  given  the  Act's  purported 
abolition  of  joint  and  several  liability,  and  the  fact  that  contribution  is  presently  unavailable 
in  Indiana."  Id.  (footnotes  omitted),  Wilkins  states:  "When  joint  and  several  liability  is 
abolished,  the  rule  against  contribution  is  redundant;  no  detriment  is  imposed  against 
defendant's  interests  which  needs  to  be  counterbalanced.  All  of  the  detrimental  effects 
are  borne  on  the  plaintiff's  side  of  the  bar."  Id.  at  720.  See  generally  Comment,  Tort 
Law:  Joint  and  Several  Liability  Under  Comparative  Negligence-Forcing  Old  Doctrines  on 
New  Concepts,  40  U,  Fla.  L.  Rev.  469  (1988)  (disapproving  of  Florida  judicial  retention 
of  joint  and  several  liability  because  detrimental  to  defendants). 

68.  iND.  Code  §§  34-4-33-5(b)(l),  34-4-33-10  (1988). 


950  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

of  the  defendants,  and  of  any  person  who  is  a  nonparty. "^^  Nonparty 
is  defined  as  "a  person  who  is,  or  may  be,  Hable  to  the  claimant  in 
part  or  in  whole  for  the  damages  claimed  but  who  has  not  been  joined 
in  the  action  as  a  defendant  by  the  claimant. "^'^ 

Another  section  provides  for  a  "nonparty  defense,"  made  by  a 
defendant  in  order  to  have  the  fault  of  a  tortfeasor  not  joined  as  a 
defendant  considered. ^^  The  defense  must  be  affirmatively  asserted  in 
order  to  have  the  nonparty's  fault  considered.''^  Finally,  in  providing 


69.  IND.  Code  §  34-4-33-5(b)(l)  (1988).  See  supra  note  44  for  the  full  text  of  Ind. 
Code  §  34-4-33-5(b).  The  section  provides  that  "[tjhe  percentage  of  fault  figures  of  parties 
to  the  action  may  total  less  than  one  hundred  percent  (100%)  if  the  jury  finds  that  fault 
contributing  to  cause  the  claimant's  loss  has  also  come  from  a  nonparty  or  nonparties." 
Id.  While  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-5(b)(l)  may  seem  to  imply  that  juries  may  consider  the 
fault  of  nonparties  spontaneously,  without  having  the  issue  introduced  by  the  court  or  a 
party,  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-10  (1988)  provides  specific  procedural  provisions  for  the 
introduction  of  the  issue,  and  juries  are  apparently  not  allowed  to  consider  nonparty  fault 
unless  it  is  introduced  into  the  case.  See  Wilkins,  supra  note  47,  at  739. 

70.  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-2(a)  (1988).  The  statute  specifies  that  an  employer  may 
not  be  a  nonparty.  Id.  This  Note  does  not  deal  with  the  ramifications  of  the  exclusion 
of  employers  from  nonparty  status. 

71.  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-10  (1988). 

72.  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-10  (1988)  provides  in  pertinent  part: 

(a)  In  an  action  based  on  fault,  a  defendant  may  assert  as  a  defense  that  the 
damages  of  the  claimant  were  caused  in  full  or  in  part  by  a  nonparty.  Such  a 
defense  is  referred  to  in  this  section  as  a  nonparty  defense. 

(b)  The  burden  of  proof  of  a  nonparty  defense  is  upon  the  defendant,  who 
must  affirmatively  plead  the  defense.  However,  nothing  in  this  chapter  relieves 
the  claimant  of  the  burden  of  proving  that  fault  on  the  part  of  the  defendant 
or  defendants  caused,  in  whole  or  in  part,  the  damages  of  the  claimant. 

(c)  A  nonparty  defense  that  is  known  by  the  defendant  when  he  files  his  first 
answer  shall  be  pleaded  as  part  of  the  first  answer.  A  defendant  who  gains 
actual  knowledge  of  a  nonparty  defense  after  the  filing  of  an  answer  may  plead 
the  defense  with  reasonable  promptness.  However,  if  the  defendant  was  served 
with  a  complaint  and  summons  more  than  one  hundred  fifty  (150)  days  before 
the  expiration  of  the  limitation  of  action  applicable  to  the  claimant's  claim 
against  the  nonparty,  the  defendant  shall  plead  the  nonparty  defense  not  later 
than  forty  five  (45)  days  before  the  expiration  of  that  limitation  of  action.  The 
trial  court  may  alter  these  time  limitations  or  make  other  suitable  time  limitations 
in  any  manner  that  is  consistent  with: 

(1)  giving  the  defendant  a  reasonable  opportunity  to  discover  the  existence  of 
a  nonparty  defense;  and 

(2)  giving  the  claimant  a  reasonable  opportunity  to  add  the  nonparty  as  an 
additional  defendant  to  the  action  before  the  expiration  of  the  period  of  limitation 
appUcable  to  the  claim.  .  . 

Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-10  (1988).  The  first  case  to  interpret  the  statutory  nonparty  defense 
was  Walters  v.  Dean,  497  N.E.2d  247  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1986)  (a  single  defendant  case  in 
which  the  defendant  pleaded  a  nonparty  defense  in  his  answer  to  plaintiff's  complaint). 
After  reviewing  some  of  the  case  law  of  other  jurisdictions,  the  court  concluded  that  the 
allocation  of  nonparty  fault  is  to  be  made  "only  in  those  cases  where  the  non-party 
defense  is  specially  pleaded  by  a  named  defendant."  Id.  at  253. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  951 

for  the  forms  of  the  verdicts,  the  legislature  has  required  that  *'[i]f  the 
evidence  in  the  action  is  sufficient  to  support  the  charging  of  fault  to 
a  nonparty,  the  form  of  verdict  also  shall  require  a  disclosure  of  the 
name  of  the  nonparty  and  the  percentage  of  fault  charged  to  the 
nonparty.  "^^  This  effectively  precludes  the  consideration  of  the  fault  of 
unidentified  tortfeasors.  These  provisions  of  the  Act  are  unique  in  com- 
parative fault  jurisdictions,  with  other  states  answering  the  questions 
brought  up  by  nonparty  inclusion  by  means  of  case  law.^"^ 

The  status  of  nonparties  has  an  impact  in  the  area  of  settlement 
with  regards  to  what  happens  to  the  fault  of  a  settling  tortfeasor.  If 
the  settling  tortfeasor  is  considered  a  nonparty,  her  fault  will  be  allocated 
under  the  nonparty  provisions  of  the  Act.  This  result  has  been  assumed 
by  several  Indiana  authors,  one  of  whom  states  that  "[t]he  nonparty 
likely  to  be  encountered  by  the  jury  most  frequently  is  that  tortfeasor 
with  whom  the  plaintiff  has  reached  a  settlement.  "^^  If  so,  Indiana  courts 
will  be  called  upon  to  make  decisions  regarding  whether  juries  should 
be  told  that  a  tortfeasor  is  a  nonparty  rather  than  a  defendant  because 
she  has  settled  with  the  plaintiff.  This  creates  a  potential  problem  if 
unsophisticated  juries  view  settlement  as  evidence  of  admitted  liability, 
allocating  undue  amounts  of  fault  to  nonparty  settling  tortfeasors.  The 
problem  created  if  juries  are  not  told  of  a  settlement  is  the  confusion 
engendered  when  a  clearly  faulty  tortfeasor  is  a  nonparty  who  does  not 
defend  herself.  Besides  being  told  of  the  mere  fact  of  a  settlement,  there 
will  be  questions  as  to  whether  juries  should  be  told  the  amount  of  a 
settlement.  ^^ 

Situations  will  also  arise  where  nonsettling  defendants  bring  settling 
tortfeasors  back  in  as  nonparties  and  attempt  to  heap  fault  on  them. 
This  would,  in  effect,  force  the  plaintiff  to  defend  the  settling  wrongdoer. 


73.  IND.  Code  §  34-4-33-6  (1988). 

74.  Eilbacher,  Comparative  Fault  and  the  Nonparty  Tortfeasor,  17  Ind.  L.  Rev. 
903,  905,  n.2  (1984).  See  also  C.  Heft  &  C.J.  Heft,  Comparative  Negligence  Manual 
§  8.100  (1986);  2  Matthew  Bender  Comparative  Fault  §  13.20[2]  (1989). 

75.  Eilbacher,  supra  note  74,  at  908. 

76.  This  would  also  be  an  evidentiary  question.  Evidence  of  offers  to  compromise 
or  evidence  of  settlements  made  is,  as  a  rule,  inadmissible.  12  R.  Miller,  Indlana  Practice 
§  408.101  (1984).  This  rule  does  not  apply  if  the  evidence  of  settlement  is  offered  for 
some  other  purpose  than  to  prove  liability.  Id.  Also,  "[e]vidence  that  a  party  made  an 
offer  to  settle  a  related  claim  with  a  non-party  is  not  admissible  to  show  the  party's 
behef  in  the  weakness  of  his  case.  If  the  non-party  is  called  as  a  witness,  however,  evidence 
of  the  offer  may  be  admissible  to  show  the  witness'  bias  or  prejudice."  Id.  at  §  408.103. 
See  also  Note,  Knowledge  by  the  Jury  of  a  Settlement  Where  a  Plaintiff  has  Settled  With 
One  or  More  Defendants  Who  Are  Jointly  and  Severally  Liable,  32  Vill.  L.  Rev.  541 
(1987),  which  looks  at  the  problems  involved  in  this  issue  in  a  number  of  jurisdictions, 
including  those  which  control  the  exposure  of  the  jury  to  settlement  agreements  statutorily. 


952  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

who  has  no  incentive  to  defend  herself  because  she  has  been  released. 
On  the  other  side  of  this  is  the  unfairness  to  defendants  if  plaintiffs 
are  allowed  to  keep  settling  tortfeasors  out  of  the  fault  allocation  equation 
entirely,  which  would  force  the  trier  of  fact  to  allocate  the  fault  between 
plaintiff  and  the  nonsettling  defendant,  causing  the  nonsettling  defendant 
to  pay  more  than  her  fair  share  of  the  damages. ^^  The  case  law  involving 
the  Indiana  Act  has  focused  primarily  on  the  nonparty  provisions  of 
the  Act.^^  Several  cases  deal  with  the  question  of  whether  a  tortfeasor 
may  be  a  nonparty  under  the  provision  of  the  statute  defining  a  nonparty 
as  one  who  "is  or  may  be  liable"  to  the  claimant.''^  In  Hill  v.  Metropolitan 
Trucking,^^  the  Northern  Federal  District  Court  of  Indiana  held  that 
fellow  employees  of  the  plaintiff's  decedent  could  not  be  nonparties 
because  the  plaintiff  had  no  right  of  recovery  against  them.^^  Since  the 
would-be  nonparties  were  state  employees  and  no  Tort  Claims  notice 
had  been  filed,  they  were  immune  to  suit;  therefore  they  could  not  be 
liable,  and  further,  could  not  be  named  as  nonparties. ^^  A  different 
result  was  reached  several  months  later  in  the  Southern  District  of  Indiana 
in  Huber  v.  Henley, ^^  in  which  the  court  found  that  the  State  could 
have  been  liable  if  a  Tort  Claims  notice  had  been  filed,  and  as  a  result 
could  be  named  as  a  nonparty  even  though  plaintiff  had  waived  his 
right  to  recover  from  the  State  by  not  filing  the  notice.®'^ 

In  the  settlement  context,  these  cases  bring  up  the  issue  of  whether 
a  setthng  defendant  can  be  considered  a  party  who  is  or  may  be  Hable 
to  the  claimant.  In  the  larger  sense,  a  setthng  tortfeasor  is  still  one  who 
is  liable,  but  that  liability  has  been  dealt  with  by  contract  between  the 
parties.  This  controls  not  necessarily  the  right,  but  the  recovery  (as  in 
a  covenant  not  to  sue).  In  the  narrow  sense,  if  a  release  has  been  given, 
the  settling  party  is  freed.  The  plaintiff  in  this  situation  has  contracted 
away  her  right  to  pursue  that  tortfeasor  any  further,  thereby  precluding 
the  naming  of  that  tortfeasor  as  a  nonparty  who  is  or  may  be  liable 
to  the  plaintiff. 


77.  See  Wilkins,  supra  note  47,  at  732.  See  also  2  Matthew  Bender  Comparative 
Negligence  §  13.20  (breaks  down  the  advantages  and  disadvantages  to  parties  when 
nonparty  tortfeasors  are  brought  in  or  kept  out  in  joint  and  several  liability  or  several 
liability  only  jurisdictions). 

78.  Supra  notes  69-77  and  accompanying  text. 

79.  IND.  Code  §  34-4-33-2  (1988). 

80.  659  F.  Supp.  430  (N.D.  Ind.  1987). 

81.  Id.  at  434-35. 

82.  Id. 

83.  669  F.  Supp.  1474  (S.D.  Ind,  1987),  This  case  had  been  in  the  same  court 
earlier  on  the  same  issue.  Huber  v.  Henley,  656  F,  Supp.  508  (S.D.  Ind.  1987). 

84.  Huber,  669  F,  Supp,  at  1479. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  953 

The  federal  court  in  Moore  v.  General  Motors  Corp.^^  ruled  that 
the  conduct  of  plaintiffs  employer  (who  could  not  be  brought  in  as  a 
nonparty  because  the  statute  specifically  precludes  an  employer  from 
being  a  nonparty)^^  could  be  brought  in  and  considered  under  the  prox- 
imate cause  provisions  of  the  Act.^^  The  court  issued  a  warning  in  the 
opinion  that  the  defendants  must  not  try  to  do  indirectly  what  they 
could  not  do  directly,  that  is,  to  have  the  employer's  fault  considered 
by  the  jury,  but  stated  that  evidence  of  the  employer's  conduct  could 
be  presented  to  defend  against  plaintiffs  claim  of  negligence  on  the 
causation  level  only.^*  The  court's  admonition  made  it  clear  that  the 
employer  was  not  to  be  allocated  any  fault.  However,  consideration  of 
a  wrongdoer's  fault  without  allocation  is  bound  to  be  confusing  to  juries, 
and  begins  to  resemble  the  '^phantom  tortfeasor"  concept  (dealt  with 
later  in  this  Note),  which  also  involves  bending  the  nonparty  provisions 
of  a  statute. ^^ 

Bowles  V.  Tatom,^  decided  in  June  1988  by  the  Indiana  Court  of 
Appeals,  refined  the  interpretation  of  the  nonparty  defense  further  in 
terms  of  how  and  whether  the  defense  is  pleaded.  In  Bowles,  plaintiff 
was  injured  when  he  was  hit  broadside  in  an  intersection  by  the  defendant, 
who  had  run  a  stopsign  obscured  by  foliage. ^^  Plaintiff  Tatom  originally 
named  as  defendants  Bowles,  the  city,  the  mayor,  and  the  adjacent 
property  owners  whose  trees  had  obscured  the  stopsign. ^^  When  Plaintiff 
had  finished  presenting  his  evidence  and  rested,  the  defendants  city, 
mayor,  and  landowners  moved  to  have  the  claims  against  them  dismissed. 
The  court  granted  the  motion  without  objection  by  defendant  Bowles.^^ 


85.  684  F.  Supp.  220  (N.D.  Ind.   1988). 

86.  iND.  Code  §  34-4-33-2(a)  (1988). 

87.  iND.  Code  §  34-4-33-l(b)(l)  and  (2)  (1988). 

88.  Moore,  684  F.  Supp.  at  222: 

Defendants  are  cautioned,  however,  that  in  presenting  evidence  to  refute  the 

elements  of  plaintiff's  negligence  claim,  they  must  be  very  careful  to  structure 

their  arguments  so  as  to  avoid  confusing  the  jury.  .  .  .  The  defendant's  arguments 

cannot  be  used  to  indirectly  accomplish  an  allocation  of  fault  to  unnamed 

defendants  by  the  jury,  a  result  inconsistent  with  the  express  provisions  of  the 

Indiana  Comparative  Fault  Act. 

Id.  The  court  based  its  decision  in  part  on  the  portion  of  the  Act  that  states:  "[N]othing 

in  this  chapter  relieves  the  claimant  of  the  burden  of  proving  that  fault  on  the  part  of 

the  defendant  or  defendants  caused,  in  whole  or  in  part,  the  damages  of  the  claimant." 

Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33- 10(b)  (1988).  This  stricture  appears  in  the  nonparty  defense  portion 

of  the  statute.  Id.  at  221. 

89.  See  infra  notes  151-55  and  accompanying  text. 

90.  523  N.E.2d  458  (Ind.  Ct.  App.   1988). 

91.  Id.  at  460. 

92.  Id. 

93.  Id. 


954  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

This  left  Bowles  as  the  only  defendant,  and  the  trial  judge  assessed  one 
hundred  percent  Uability  against  her.^"^ 

The  appellate  court  found  this  one  hundred  percent  fault  allocation 
inappropriate,  stating  that  while  the  evidence  of  the  obstruction  of  the 
stopsign  did  not  show  that  Bowles  was  not  at  fault,  it  did  estabUsh  that 
she  could  not  be  one  hundred  percent  at  fault.  The  court  also  held: 

Although  the  City,  the  Mayor,  and  the  [landowners]  were  dis- 
missed from  the  lawsuit,  fault  percentage  could  be  allocated  to 
them  even  though  Bowles  did  not  plead  the  empty  chair  defense. 
In  the  present  case,  the  City,  the  Mayor,  and  the  [landowners] 
were  parties  up  until  the  close  of  Tatom's  case-in-chief.  As  such, 
Bowles  was  entitled  to  rely  on  the  fault  allocation  provisions  of 
the  Comparative  Fault  Act  without  specific  pleading,  and  could 
continue  to  rely  on  the  fault  allocation  after  the  other  named 
defendants  were  dismissed.  .  .  .  [T]he  dismissal  did  not  amount 
to  a  zero  percent  (0%)  fault  allocation. ^^ 

This  appears  to  indicate  that  a  defendant  need  not  plead  a  nonparty 
defense  to  assert  it  if  the  nonparties  were  defendants  in  the  action  and 
were  dismissed.  If  a  court  determines  that  the  principles  in  Bowles  apply 
equally  when  the  dismissal  is  by  agreement  between  the  plaintiff  and  a 
settling  defendant,  rather  than  by  the  court,  then  a  defendant  who  settled 
during  trial  and  was  released  and  dismissed  would  automatically  have 
her  fault  allocated  as  though  she  had  remained  in  the  action.  The 
nonsettling  defendants  would  not  have  to  plead  any  nonparty  issues  in 
order  to  have  the  settling  defendant's  fault  allocated. 

The  Bowles  dissent  took  a  different  view,  focusing  on  the  statutory 
definition  of  nonparty,  which  requires  that  the  nonparty  be  one  *'who 
is  or  may  be  liable  to  the  claimant  .  .  .  but  who  has  not  been  joined 
in  the  action  as  a  defendant  by  the  claimant. "^^  The  dissenting  judge 
stated:  *'By  statutory  definition,  parties  in  a  comparative  fault  action 
can  never  revert  to  nonparty  status, "^^  and  thus  the  dismissal  of  the 
city,  the  mayor  and  the  landowners  functioned  as  an  allocation  of  zero 
percent  of  the  fault  to  them.  Under  this  view,  a  defendant  who  settles 
cannot  be  brought  back  in  to  the  action  as  a  nonparty  for  fault  allocation. 
However,  the  dissent  also  focused  on  the  fact  that  the  dismissal  was  by 
the  court  under  T.R.  50(A)  motion, ^^  which  would  distinguish  the  Bowles 


94.  Id. 

95.  Id.  at  461. 

96.  Id.  at  462  (Conover,  J.  dissenting)  (emphasis  in  original). 

97.  Id.  at  462. 

98.  Ind.  Trial  R.  50  provides  for  Judgment  on  the  Evidence  (Directed  Verdict). 
The  trial  court  in  Bowles  dismissed  the  City,  the  Mayor,  and  the  adjacent  landowners 
because  it  determined  that  there  was  no  evidence  of  liability  on  the  part  of  those  defendants. 
523  N.E.2d  at  460. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  955 

case  from  a  case  where  the  dismissal  is  by  agreement  between  a  defendant 
and  the  plaintiff. 

It  is  clear  that  Indiana  courts  will  be  called  upon  to  further  interpret 
the  nonparty  provisions  of  the  Indiana  Act.  Because  the  comparative 
fault  statute  is  unique  in  its  precise,  procedural  nonparty  provisions, 
courts  will  face  the  interpretation  without  much  help  from  the  case  law 
of  other  jurisdictions  such  as  Kansas,  which  has  a  vague  nonparty 
provision  its  courts  have  found  very  malleable. ^^  While  it  is  simple  to 
dismiss  settlement  issues  under  the  nonparty  provisions  by  stating  that 
settUng  parties  will  become  nonparties  for  the  allocation  of  fault,  this 
does  not  necessarily  solve  the  practical  and  policy-oriented  consequences 
of  doing  so.  The  questions  raised  above  can  and  will  be  brought  up  by 
parties,  and  the  courts  will  have  to  balance  the  policies  of  full  com- 
pensation for  claimants  with  fairness  to  defendants  and  the  ideal  of 
completely  proportional  liability. 

III.      Comparison  With  the  Kansas  Act 
A.     Background 

Prior  to  the  enactment  of  the  Kansas  comparative  fault  statute, 
settlement  in  Kansas  was  much  the  same  as  in  Indiana.  Tortfeasors  were 
jointly  and  severally  liable  for  the  injuries  they  caused  concurrently  or 
in  concert. ^^  The  effect  of  a  settlement  document  was  determined  by 
examining  the  intent  of  the  parties  to  the  agreement  as  manifested  by 
the  agreement. ^°^  As  in  Indiana,  a  covenant  not  to  sue  or  a  loan  receipt 
agreement  was  distinguished  from  a  release  and  did  not  release  all  joint 
tortfeasors,  only  those  who  were  parties  to  the  agreement. '^^  The  amount 
received  under  such  a  covenant  or  loan  receipt  reduced  the  recovery  of 
the  plaintiff  by  the  dollar  amount  received. '^^  If  the  amount  received 


99.     See  supra  notes  113-16,  154-59  and  accompanying  text. 

100.  Note,  Multiple  Party  Litigation  Under  Comparative  Negligence  in  Kansas — 
Damage  Apportionment  as  a  Replacement  for  Joint  and  Several  Liability,  16  Washburn 
L.J.  672  (1977). 

101.  Harvest  Queen  Mill  &  Elevator  Co.  v.  Newman,  387  F.2d  1  (10th  Cir.  1967); 
Reynard  v.  Bradshaw,  196  Kan.  97,  409  P.2d  1011  (1966). 

102.  Cullen  v.  Atchison,  Topeka  &  Santa  Fe  Ry.  Co.,  211  Kan.  368,  507  P.2d  353 
(1973)  (loan  receipt  agreement  found  to  be  valid,  and  in  context  of  rule  that  release  of 
one  tortfeasor  releases  all  joint  tortfeasors  was  found  to  constitute  a  covenant  rather  than 
a  release)  Sade  v.  Hemstrom,  205  Kan.  514,  471  P. 2d  340  (1970)  (language  indicating 
that  parties  intended  the  settlement  amount  to  be  full  satisfaction  for  the  injuries  suffered 
by  plaintiff  caused  agreement  to  be  interpreted  as  release  rather  than  covenant  not  to 
sue);  Jacobsen  v.  Woerner,  149  Kan.  598,  601,  89  P.2d  24,  27  (1939). 

103.  Cullen,  211  Kan.  at  220,  507  P.2d  at  362;  Jacobsen,  149  Kan.  at  602,  89  P.2d 
at  28  (judgment  reduced  by  amount  received  under  covenant  not  to  sue  even  though 
settling  defendant  was  not  in  fact  liable). 


956  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

fully  satisfied  plaintiff's  claim  the  settlement,  regardless  of  the  form, 
served  as  a  release  because  plaintiff  was  entitled  to  only  one  satisfaction. 
An  unconditional  release  still  served  to  release  all  joint  tortfeasors.^^ 

Technically,  a  defendant  in  Kansas  had  no  right  to  contribution.  ^^^ 
It  was  plaintiff's  prerogative  to  decide  who  to  sue  and  against  whom 
she  would  collect  any  judgment. ^^  This  meant  that  defendants  had  no 
option  to  bring  in  other  defendants  who  might  be  involved  in  the  incident 
unless  they  were  persons  who  had  a  responsibility  to  indemnify  the 
defendant.  Thus  plaintiff  could  effectively  foreclose  any  chance  of  a 
defendant  receiving  a  joint  judgment.  However,  if  there  were  multiple 
defendants,  once  a  joint  judgment  was  entered  and  paid  in  full  by  one 
of  them  under  joint  and  several  liability,  that  defendant  then  had  a 
statutory  right  to  pursue  contribution  from  other  jointly  liable  defendants 
and  recover  a  pro  rata  amount  of  the  judgment  paid.^^"'  This  gave 
'MmpUcit  expression  to  the  common  law  rule  that  in  the  absence  of  a 
judgment  against  them  there  is  no  right  of  contribution  between  joint 
tortfeasors."^08 

B.    Kansas  Comparative  Fault 
Kansas  enacted  statutory  comparative  fault  in  1974.*^  At  the  time. 


104.  Cullen,  111  Kan.  at  219,  507  P.2d  at  361;  Jacobsen,  149  Kan.  598,  89  P.2d 
24.  Kansas'  release  rule  was  interpreted  much  less  strictly  than  the  Indiana  release  rule. 
Plaintiffs  were  allowed  to  give  a  release  to  one  joint  tortfeasor  which  reserved  a  right 
against  another  joint  tortfeasor,  and  have  the  agreement  found  to  be  valid.  Edens  v. 
Fletcher,  79  Kan.  139,  98  P.  784  (1908).  This  was  because  the  release  rule  was  combined 
with  the  rule  that  the  intent  behind  the  release  determined  its  effect,  and  a  reservation 
of  rights  evidenced  an  intent  not  to  release  all  joint  tortfeasors.  Id.  See  also  Sade  v. 
Hemstrom,  205  Kan.  514,  521,  471  P.2d  340,  347  (1970).  The  reservation  could  be  oral. 
Scott  V.  Kansas  State  Fair  Ass'n,  102  Kan.  653,  171  P.  634  (1918).  A  general  background 
on  the  release  rule  and  the  exceptions  made  to  avoid  its  Procrustean  effect  is  found  in 
Stueve  V.  American  Honda  Motors  Co.,  Inc.,  457  F.  Supp.  740  (D.  Kan.  1978). 

105.  Alseike  v.  Miller,  196  Kan  547,  551,  412  P.2d  1007,  1011  (1966);  Rucker  v. 
Allendorph,  102  Kan.  771,  172  P.  524  (1918).  In  Alseike,  defendant  was  not  allowed  to 
join  a  third  party  defendant  who  she  claimed  was  responsible  for  plaintiff's  injuries  because 
the  third  party  defendant  was  not  liable  to  indemnify  the  defendant.  The  court  decided 
that  allowing  her  to  join  the  third  party  would  amount  to  contribution.  Alseike,  196  Kan. 
at  551,  412  P.2d  at  1011-12. 

106.  Alseike,  196  Kan.  at  552,  412  P.2d  at  1012. 

107.  McKinney  v.  Miller,  204  Kan.  436,  464  P.2d  276  (1970).  The  statute  was  Kan. 
Stat.  Ann.  §  60-2413(b)  (1983),  which  provides:  "Contribution  between  joint  obligors.  .  . 
(b)  Judgment  debtors.  A  right  of  contribution  or  indemnity  among  judgment  debtors, 
arising  out  of  the  payment  of  the  judgment  by  one  or  more  of  them,  may  be  enforced 
by  execution  against  the  property  of  the  judgment  debtor  from  whom  contribution  or 
indemnity  is  sought." 

108.  McKinney,  204  Kan.  436,  439,  464  P.2d  276,  279.  But  see  dissent,  204  Kan. 
at  440,  464  P.2d  at  280.  See  also  Comment,  Civil  Procedure  -  Tort-feasor's  Right  to 
Contribution,  10  Washburn  L.J.  135  (1970)  (casenote  on  McKinney). 

109.  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-258a  (Supp.  1987).  See  Comment,  Comparative  Neg- 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  957 

the  Kansas  Act  was  described  in  much  the  same  terms  that  the  Indiana 
Act  is  presently  being  described: 

In  this  instance  the  pains  and  strains  of  abrupt  change  may 
prove  particularly  acute,  for  the  Kansas  statute  is  of  mixed 
ancestry  and  its  effect  is  more  uncertain  than  if  the  legislature 
had  chosen  as  a  model  an  existing  statute  with  a  history  of 
judicial  construction.  While  the  Kansas  act  borrows  from  the 
laws  of  other  jurisdictions,  it  is  identical  with  none.  The  result 
is  a  truly  unique  version  of  comparative  negligence.  Nothing  can 
be  more  certain  to  breed  uncertainty.  ^'° 

The  Kansas  Act,  Uke  Indiana's,  does  not  provide  specifically  for  settling 
tortfeasors.  It  does  provide  that  in  multiple  tortfeasor  cases, 

[w]here  the  comparative  negligence  of  the  parties  in  any  action 
is  an  issue  and  recovery  is  allowed  against  more  than  one  party, 
each  such  party  shall  be  liable  for  that  portion  of  the  total 
dollar  amount  awarded  as  damages  to  any  claimant  in  the  pro- 
portion that  the  amount  of  such  party's  causal  negligence  bears 
to  the  amount  of  the  causal  negligence  attributed  to  all  parties 
against  whom  such  recovery  is  allowed.^'' 

This  provision  has  been  interpreted  by  the  Kansas  Supreme  Court  to 
eliminate  the  common-law  concept  of  joint  and  several  hability  in  neg- 
ligence actions.  ^'^ 

The  Kansas  Act  provides  for  the  joinder  of  causally  negligent  in- 
dividuals who  have  not  been  made  defendants.  Section  (c)  states:  '*On 


ligence  -  A  Look  at  The  New  Kansas  Statute,  23  U.  Kan.  L.  Rev.  113  (1974)  for  a  basic 
overview  of  the  Kansas  Act  at  the  time  of  enactment. 

110.  Kelly,  Comparative  Negligence  -  Kansas,  43  J.  Kan.  Bar  Ass'n  151,  151  (1974). 
Cf.  Schwartz,  Comparative  Negligence  in  Indiana:  A  Unique  Statute  That  Will  Reshape 
the  Law,  17  Ind.  L.  Rev.  957  (1984). 

111.  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-258a(d)  (Supp.  1987). 

112.  Brown  v.  Keill,  224  Kan.  195,  580  P.2d  867  (1978).  The  abrogation  of  joint 
and  several  liability  in  Kansas  was  subject  to  the  same  criticisms  that  are  being  leveled 
at  that  interpretation  of  the  Indiana  Act.  Compare  Kelly,  Comparative  Negligence  -  - 
Kansas,  43  J.  Kan.  Bar  Ass'n  151,  189-90  (1974)  (suggesting  that  the  Kansas  statute  had 
not  abolished  joint  and  several  liability  but  had  instead  created  a  system  of  comparative 
contribution,  which  would  include  a  retention  of  joint  and  several  liability)  with  Wilkins, 
supra  note  48.  See  also  Vasos,  Comparative  Negligence  Update  -  A  Discussion  of  Selected 
Issues,  44  J.  Kan  Bar  Ass'n  13,  16-17  (1975)  (suggesting  that  the  abrogation  of  joint 
and  several  liability,  throwing  the  risk  of  nonrecovery  totally  on  the  plaintiff,  is  inconsistent 
with  the  aim  of  comparative  fault  to  expand  the  ability  of  injured  persons  to  recover 
fully).  In  Oklahoma,  joint  and  several  liability  was  judicially  abrogated  only  to  have  it 
immediately  reinstated  by  the  legislature.  See  McNichoIs,  Judicial  Elimination  of  Joint 
and  Several  Liability  Because  of  Comparative  Negligence  -  A  Puzzling  Choice,  32  Okla. 
L.  Rev.  1,  (1979). 


958  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  ,  [Vol.  22:939 

motion  of  any  party  against  whom  a  claim  is  asserted  for  negligence 
.  .  .  any  other  person  whose  causal  negligence  is  claimed  to  have  con- 
tributed to  such  death,  personal  injury,  property  damage,  or  economic 
loss,  shall  be  joined  as  an  additional  party  to  the  action. ''^^^  Clearly, 
Kansas'  * 'additional  part[ies]"  are  not  nearly  so  well  defined  and  reg- 
imented as  Indiana's  nonparties.^''*  The  procedural  section  of  the  Kansas 
statute  directs  the  trier  of  fact  to  allocate  percentages  of  fault  among 
the  ''parties,"''^  but  the  Kansas  Supreme  Court  has  recognized  that  the 
comparative  neghgence  statute  is  "silent  as  to  what  position  the  added 
party  occupies  once  that  party  is  joined.""^ 

/.  The  Demise  of  Joint  and  Several  Liability  and  Interpretation  of 
the  Kansas  Additional  Party  Provisions. — The  Kansas  Act,  like  its  Indiana 
counterpart,  was  first  interpreted  by  federal  courts. ''"^  In  Nagunst  v. 
Western  Union  Tel.  Co.,^^^  the  Kansas  District  Court  looked  at  the 
effect  of  the  Kansas  "forced  joinder"  provisions  on  settlement.  The 
plaintiff-passenger  in  Nagunst  settled  with  the  driver  of  the  vehicle  in 
which  she  had  been  injured,  and  then  sued  Western  Union,  lessee  of 
the  other  car  involved."^  Defendant  Western  Union  attempted  to  join 
the  released  party  under  Kansas  Statute  Section  60-25 8a(c),  which  would 
have  destroyed  the  court's  diversity  jurisdiction. '^^  The  court  also  saw 
the  covenant  not  to  sue  given  to  the  settHng  party  by  the  plaintiff  as 
a  potential  bar  to  the  joinder,  because  Kansas  law  held  that  a  covenant 
not  to  sue  barred  a  subsequent  action  although  it  did  not  extinguish 
the  right. '^'  The  court  denied  the  joinder  on  the  basis  that  the  covenant 


113.  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-258a(c)  (Supp.  1987).  See  also  Comment,  Comparative 
Negligence— A  Look  At  the  New  Kansas  Statute,  23  U.  Kan  L.  Rev.  113,  123  (1974). 

114.  IND.  Code  §  34-4-33-10  (1988). 

115.  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-258a(b)  (1983).  This  section  of  the  act  provides: 
(b)  Where  the  comparative  negligence  of  the  parties  in  any  such  action  is  an 
issue,  the  jury  shall  return  special  verdicts,  or  in  the  absence  of  a  jury,  the 
court  shall  make  special  findings,  determining  the  percentage  of  negligence 
attributable  to  each  of  the  parties,  and  determining  the  total  amount  of  damages 
sustained  by  each  of  the  claimants,  and  the  entry  of  judgment  shall  be  made 
by  the  court.  No  general  verdict  shall  be  returned  by  the  jury. 

Id. 

116.  Kennedy  v.  City  of  Sawyer,  228  Kan.  439,  454,  618  P.2d  788,  803  (1980); 
Brown  v.  Keill,  224  Kan.   195,  580  P.2d  867  (1978). 

117.  Beach  v.  M  &  N  Modern  HydrauHc  Press  Co.,  428  F.  Supp.  956  (D.  Kan. 
1977);  Greenwood  v.  McDonough  Power  Equip,,  Inc.,  437  F.  Supp.  707  (D.  Kan  1977); 
Nagunst  v.  Western  Union  Tel.  Co.,  76  F.R.D.  631  (D.  Kan.  1977).  See  Comment,  Torts: 
Damage  Apportionment  Under  the  Kansas  Comparative  Negligence  Statute  -  the  Unjoined 
Tortfeasor,  17  Washburn  L.J.  698  (1978)  (analyzing  Beach,  Greenwood,  and  Nagunst). 

118.  76  F.R.D.  631  (D.  Kan.  1977). 

119.  Id.  at  632. 

120.  Id. 

121.  Id.  at  633. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  959 

precluded  it,  stating  that  *'[d]efendants'  right  to  have  their  proportionate 
habiUty  reduced  by  that  attributable  to  others  should  not  be  defeated 
by  plaintiff's  voluntary  decision  to  settle  with  other  potential  defen- 
dants. "^^^  The  court  explained  this  conclusion  as  follows: 

If  a  plaintiff  voluntarily  chooses  not  to  sue  such  a  person,  as 
by  execution  of  a  covenant  not  to  sue,  he  simply  loses  his  right 
to  recover  against  that  person  the  percentage  of  the  total  award 
which  corresponds  to  the  percentage  of  negligence  attributable 
to  the  party  not  sued.  .  .  .  While  such  a  percentage-crediting 
procedure  may  introduce  an  element  of  risk  into  plaintiff's  set- 
tlement negotiations  with  the  non-party  (that  is,  the  plaintiff  is 
not  guaranteed  of  recovery  of  lOO^o  of  the  jury's  award),  the 
risk  is  certainly  no  greater  than  that  which  would  inure  were 
the  named  defendant(s)  to  join  the  party  as  an  additional  de- 
fendant under  K.S.A.  60-258a(c).'23 

The  court  also  noted  that  allowing  joinder  of  the  nonparty  under  Section 
60-258a(c)  would  serve  to  nullify  part  of  the  consideration  given  for 
entering  the  covenant  not  to  sue,  which  included  freeing  the  released 
party  from  the  expense  and  inconvenience  of  defending  herself  in  the 
action.'^'*  Preventing  the  joinder  was  seen  as  encouraging  settlement  and 


122.  Id.  at  634.  The  court  viewed  this  as  carrying  over  to  the  comparative  fault 
system  the  traditional  common  law  principle  that  mandated  that  the  amount  given  in  a 
covenant  not  to  sue  diminished  the  plaintiff's  recovery  accordingly.  However,  to  continue 
the  dollar  for  dollar  credit  given  to  the  nonsettling  defendant  would  be  to  continue  joint 
and  several  liability,  which  would  defeat  the  allocation  ideal  behind  comparative  fault. 
Id. 

123.  Id.  at  634-35.  The  court  also  cited  Pierringer  v.  Hoger,  21  Wis. 2d  182,  124 
N.W.2d  106  (1963),  which  involved  an  innovative  (at  that  time)  settlement  and  release 
whereby  plaintiff  released  a  defendant  from  his  ultimate  proportion  of  fault  by  agreement, 
regardless  of  what  that  proportion  was  determined  to  be  by  the  trier  of  fact.  The  Nagunst 
conclusion  was  consistent  with  the  one  arrived  at  in  Greenwood  v.  McDonough  Power 
Equip.,  Inc.,  437  F.  Supp.  707  (D.  Kan.  1977),  an  earlier  federal  case  in  products  Hability, 
where  the  court  refused  to  allow  formal  joinder  by  defendant  of  parties  whose  joinder 
would  destroy  diversity  jurisdiction,  but  stated  that  the  negligence  of  those  parties  must 
be  considered  in  allocating  fault.  The  Greenwood  court  achieved  this  by  allowing  the 
negligence  of  the  nonparties  to  be  considered  under  the  provisions  of  Kan.  Stat.  Ann. 
§  60-258a(d),  which  was  characterized  as  substantive  because  it  granted  the  defendant  the 
right  to  have  the  causal  negligence  of  all  involved  parties  considered.  At  the  same  time, 
the  court  refused  to  allow  the  Greenwood  defendants  to  destroy  its  diversity  jurisdiction 
by  joining  the  nonparties  under  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-258a(c),  which  it  characterized  as 
procedural.  This  allowed  the  court  to  retain  its  jurisdiction  while  preventing  plaintiff  from 
getting  unfair  advantage  by  strategic  choice  of  defendants,  who  would  otherwise  end  up 
paying  for  the  fault  of  the  nonparties. 

124.  Nagunst,  76  F.R.D.  at  634.  However,  the  court  specifically  rejected  the  result 
in  Mihoy  v.  Proulx,   113  N.H.   698,   313  A.2d  723  (1973),  where  the  New  Hampshire 


960  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

release.  However,  in  holding  that  fairness  required  the  consideration  of 
the  released  party's  fault,  the  court  failed  to  acknowledge  the  practical 
aspects  of  who  would  plead  and  prove  or  disprove  the  fault  of  the 
released  party  and  what  her  actual  involvement  would  amount  to. 

This  case  is  comparable  to  the  initial  cases  interpreting  the  Indiana 
nonparty  provisions.  Courts  in  both  jurisdictions  are  concerned  with 
ensuring  that  all  fault  is  allocated  properly.  The  Kansas  statute,  being 
rather  inexact,  allowed  the  courts  to  consider  the  fault  of  the  nonparty 
without  formal  joinder,  foreshadowing  the  **phantom  tortfeasor"  con- 
cept. The  procedural  exactitude  of  the  Indiana  statute  would  prevent 
such  a  result  because  it  requires  that  the  defendant  raise  and  plead  the 
nonparty  defense  within  a  specific  timeframe, ^^^  and  that  the  nonparty 
be  named  in  the  verdict  form.^^^  In  Moore  v.  General  Motors, ^^'^  the 
Indiana  court  could  not  allow  plaintiff's  employer  to  be  joined  because 
the  employer  was  statutorily  excluded  from  nonparty  status.  In  Nagunst, 
the  potential  destruction  of  the  court's  diversity  jurisdiction  and  the  fact 
that  the  covenant  was  considered  a  bar  prevented  joinder  as  an  additional 
party.  ^^^ 

The  respective  courts  arrived  at  the  same  solution:  ignore  the  statutory 
nonparty  joinder  provisions  and  allow  the  fault  of  the  nonparty  to  be 
considered  without  formal  joinder.  This  is  a  much  greater  bending  of 
the  Indiana  Act  than  the  Kansas  Act,  because  the  Indiana  Act  is  much 
more  precise  in  its  requirements.  The  restraints  of  the  Indiana  Act  show 
in  that  the  Indiana  federal  court  felt  constrained  to  reinforce  the  idea 
that  fault  would  not  and  could  not  be  allocated  to  the  employer  as  a 
nonparty,  ^^^  although  it  is  not  clear  how  this  was  to  be  communicated 
to  a  jury.  The  Kansas  federal  court  allowed  the  fault  of  the  released 
individual  to  be  considered  and  allocated  along  with  the  fault  of  the 
defendants. 

Nagunst  presaged  the  interpretation  that  the  Kansas  Supreme  Court 
would  adopt  in  Brown  v.  Keill,^^^  the  first  major  state  case  interpreting 
the  Kansas  Act.  In  Brown,  the  plaintiff  sued  for  property  damage  to 
his  Jaguar,  caused  when  plaintiff's  son  was  driving  the  car  and  had  a 


Supreme  Court  decided  that  the  apportionment  of  fault  would  be  only  among  named 
defendants  and  would  not  include  tortfeasors  not  sued  because  of  the  prior  execution  of 
a  covenant  not  to  sue.  See  also  Unef.  Comparative  Fault  Act  §  6,  12  U.L.A.  52,  §  6 
Comment  (Supp.  1989);  infra  note  224. 

125.  IND.  Code  §  34-4-33-10  (1988). 

126.  iND.  Code  §  34-4-33-6  (1988). 

127.  684  F.  Supp.  220  (1988).  See  also  supra  notes  85  -  89  and  accompanying  text. 

128.  Nagunst,  76  F.R.D.  at  634-35. 

129.  Moore,  684  F.  Supp.  at  222. 

130.  224  Kan.  195,  580  P.2d  867  (1978). 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  961 

collision  with  the  defendant. '^*  Prior  to  the  filing  of  this  suit,  the 
defendant  driver  had  settled  with  the  driver  of  the  Jaguar. '^^  The  trial 
court  found  the  defendant  responsible  for  ten  percent  of  the  fault 
involved,  and  the  driver  of  the  Jaguar,  who  had  not  been  joined  by 
either  plaintiff  or  defendant,  responsible  for  ninety  percent  of  the  fault 
involved,  and  the  plaintiff  free  of  fault. •" 

The  Kansas  Supreme  Court  saw  the  issues  as  being  1)  whether  the 
doctrine  of  joint  and  several  Hability  had  been  retained  under  comparative 
fault  and  2)  whether  the  fault  of  all  individuals  involved  in  the  collision 
was  to  be  considered  even  though  one  of  the  negligent  parties  was  not 
joined  or  served  with  process. ^^"^  The  court  perceived  the  legislative  intent 
in  enacting  the  comparative  negligence  statute  as  being  to  * 'equate  re- 
covery and  duty  to  pay  to  degree  of  fault" '^^  and  noted: 

Of  necessity,  this  involved  a  change  of  both  the  doctrine  of 
contributory  negligence  and  of  joint  and  several  liability.  There 
is  nothing  inherently  fair  about  a  defendant  who  is  10%  at  fault 
paying  100%  of  the  loss,  and  there  is  no  social  policy  that 
should  compel  defendants  to  pay  more  than  their  fair  share  of 
the  loss.  Plaintiffs  now  take  the  parties  as  they  find  them.  .  .  . 
Any  other  interpretation  of  K.S.A.  60-258a(d)  destroys  the  fun- 
damental conceptual  basis  for  the  abandonment  of  the  contrib- 
utory negligence  rule  and  makes  meaningless  the  enactment  of 
subsection  (d).^^^ 

The  court  held  that  joint  and  several  liability  no  longer  applied  in  Kansas 
comparative  negligence  actions  and  that  as  a  result,  defendant's  liability 
was  to  be  based  on  her  proportional  fault  alone,  obviating  the  need  for 
contribution  between  joint  judgment  debtors. '^"^ 

The  court's  emphasis  in  this  analysis  was  on  allocation  of  fault 
rather  than  compensation  of  injured  parties. ^^^  It  appears  that  the  intent 


131.  Id.  at  197,  580  P.2d  at  869. 

132.  Id. 

133.  Id.  The  plaintiff  was  free  of  fault  because  the  negligence  of  his  son,  the  driver 
of  the  Jaguar,  could  not  be  imputed  to  him  as  bailor.  Id. 

134.  Id.  at  198,  580  P.2d  at  870. 

135.  Id.  at  201,  580  P. 2d  at  873-74. 

136.  Id.  at  202,  580  P.2d  at  874. 

137.  Id.  See  supra,  notes  107  -  108  and  accompanying  text. 

138.  In  Brown,  this  was  probably  an  equitable  question  as  well,  because  in  reading 
the  case  it  becomes  clear  that  the  owner  of  the  Jaguar,  the  plaintiff,  was  attempting  to 
manipulate  the  system  by  recovering  for  the  damage  to  his  car  when  it  must  have  been 
clear  to  him,  as  it  apparently  was  to  the  jury,  that  his  son  the  driver  was  more  faulty 
than  the  defendant.  Brown,  224  Kan.  195,  580  P.2d  867.  Knowing  that  the  driver's  fault 
would  not  be  imputed  to  him  as  bailor,  and  that  as  a  result  he  would  be  fault  free,  the 


962  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

of  the  legislature  was  perceived  to  encompass  only  the  policy  of  ensuring 
that  every  party,  whether  plaintiff  or  defendant,  be  responsible  only  for 
her  own  fault.  While  this  is  a  valid  policy  stance,  the  policies  inherent 
in  abolishing  the  bar  of  contributory  fault  in  the  first  place  involved 
not  only  a  more  precise  allocation  of  fault,  but  also  an  expanded 
compensation  function. ^^^  The  court  merely  stated: 

The  law  governing  tort  liability  will  never  be  a  panacea.  There 
have  been  occasions  in  the  past  when  the  bar  of  contributory 
negUgence  and  the  concept  of  joint  and  several  liability  resulted 
in  inequities.  There  will  continue  to  be  occasions  under  the  present 
comparative  negligence  statute  where  unfairness  will  result. ^"^^ 

While  it  is  clear  that  the  court  is  correct  in  stating  that  no  system  of 
compensation  can  be  perfectly  and  without  exception  fair,  the  court  did 
not  follow  through  with  an  analysis  of  who  would  suffer  most  of  the 
inequities  caused,  and  why  it  would  be  best  that  those  parties  be  the 
ones  to  bear  that  burden. 

The  result  in  Brown  was  clearly  fair  to  the  parties  involved,  but 
the  ultimate  result,  the  abrogation  of  joint  and  several  liability,  left  the 
comparative  fault  system  in  Kansas  less  flexible  and  more  hostile  to 
plaintiffs.  Defendants  under  the  Kansas  system  pay  only  the  determined 
percentage  of  their  own  fault  or  any  settlement  amount  they  may  negotiate 
with  the  plaintiff.  Plaintiffs,  on  the  other  hand,  absorb  their  own 
percentage  of  fault,  the  percentages  of  any  tortfeasor  they  have  settled 
with,  joined  or  unjoined,  the  percentage  of  any  judgment-proof  defen- 
dant, and  the  percentage  of  any  faulty  nonparty.  The  Kansas  Supreme 
Court  acknowledged  that  ''[t]he  ill  fortune  of  being  injured  by  an  immune 
or  judgment-proof  person  now  falls  upon  plaintiffs  rather  than  upon 
the  other  defendants, "^'^^  and  stated  that  this  risk  was  in  exchange  for 
the  risk  of  total  bar  to  a  plaintiff's  recovery  under  the  contributory 
fault  system. '"'^  The  only  ameliorating  factor  is  that  plaintiffs  are  allowed 
to  keep  any  windfall  resulting  when  a  settlement  amount  represents  more 
than  the  ultimate  percentage  of  fault  of  the  settling  tortfeasor  would 
dictate.  1^3 


plaintiff  apparently  wanted  to  force  the  defendant,  only  ten  percent  at  fault,  to  pay  for 
all  the  damage  to  the  car.  The  court  could  hardly  do  else  than  consider  the  fault  of  the 
driver,  in  fairness.  It  is  possible  that  the  case  was  carried  as  far  as  it  was  specifically  to 
have  the  questions  of  joint  and  several  liability  and  additional  parties  answered. 

139.  Wilkins,  supra  notes  47-48  and  accompanying  text. 

140.  Brown,  224  Kan.   195,  202,  580  P.2d  867,  874. 

141.  Miles  V.  West,  224  Kan.  284,  288,  580  P.2d  876,  880  (1978). 

142.  Id.  See  generally  Comment,  Brown  and  Miles:  At  Last  An  End  To  Ambiguity 
In  The  Kansas  Law  of  Comparative  Negligence,  27  Kan.  L.  Rev.  Ill  (1978)  (critical 
analysis  of  the  two  cases). 

143.  Geier  v.  Wikel,  4  Kan.  App.  2d  188,  190,  603  P.2d  1028,  1030  (1979). 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  963 

The  Indiana  cases  intimating  that  joint  and  several  liability  has  been 
abrogated  are  thus  far  all  federal,  and  no  state  court  has  yet  made  a 
binding  determination  regarding  joint  and  several  liability.  Hopefully 
when  Indiana  state  courts  are  called  upon  to  answer  this  question,  they 
will  consider  both  sides  of  the  policy  question  involved,  considering  who 
is  to  bear  the  most  risk  and  why. 

The  second  issue  presented  in  Brown  was  that  of  allocation  of  fault 
to  actors  not  joined  as  parties,  either  by  the  plaintiff  or  as  "additional 
parties.'*'*^  The  Kansas  federal  court  examined  a  similar  question  in 
Beach  v.  M  &  N  Modern  Hydraulic  Press,, ^'^^  where  the  defendant  tried 
to  join  the  plaintiff's  employer  to  have  the  employer's  fault  determined 
even  though  plaintiff  had  no  right  of  recovery  against  the  employer. '"^^ 

The  Beach  court  focused  on  the  language  of  Section  60-25 8a(d) 
which  specifies  that  a  defendant  is  liable  for  her  fault  in  proportion  to 
the  fault  of  negligent  parties  "against  whom  .  .  .  recovery  is  allowed. ""^^ 
The  court  decided  that  the  immunity  of  the  employer  did  not  prevent 
allocation  of  fault  to  it,^'^^  but  that  the  employer  could  not  be  found 
liable  for  that  fault,  its  liability  instead  falling  on  the  defendant.''*^  This 
was  because  the  plaintiff  had  not  voluntarily  left  out  the  employer  when 
naming  defendants,  but  was  involuntarily  prevented  by  the  employer's 
immunity  from  joining  it  as  a  named  defendant. '^^  The  harshness  of 
this  result,  which  appears  to  impose  a  type  of  joint  and  several  liability 
on  the  named  defendant,  was,  according  to  the  court,  ameliorated  if 
the  defendant  could  prove  negligence  on  the  part  of  both  the  plaintiff 
and  the  employer  in  order  to  reduce  the  plaintiff's   award. ^^'   These 


144.  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-258a(c)  (1983). 

145.  428  F.  Supp.  956  (D.  Kan.   1977). 

146.  Worker's  Compensation  is  an  exclusive  remedy  for  injured  employees  in  Kansas. 
Id.  at  958-59,  963. 

147.  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-258a(d):  See  supra  text  accompanying  note  111. 

148.  Beach,  428  F.  Supp.  at  966.  Apparently  this  was  to  be  done  under  the  "phantom 
tortfeasor"  method  later  elaborated  on  by  the  Greenwood  and  Nagunst  courts:  that  is, 
the  fault  was  to  be  allocated,  but  the  employer  was  not  to  be  formally  joined  either  by 
the  plaintiff  or  under  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-25 8a(c). 

149.  Id. 

150.  Id. 

151.  Id.  2ii  966.  The  Beach  court  stated: 

Under  our  interpretation  of  this  section,  plaintiff's  award  of  damages  is  reduced 
by  the  ratio  which  his  percentage  of  negligence  bears  to  the  total  amount  of 
negligence  allocated  among  the  plaintiff  and  any  third  parties  against  whom  the 
plaintiff  may  recover.  Thus  in  this  case  the  plaintiff's  award  of  damages  is 
reduced  by  a  fraction:  the  numerator  of  which  is  the  plaintiff's  percentage  or 
negligence;  the  denominator  of  which  is  the  combined  percentages  of  negligence 
of  the  plaintiff  and  the  (allegedly  negligent)  third  parties,  M  &  N  and  Monroe. 
Id.  The  reasoning  used  was  later  elaborated  on  in  Greenwood  v.   McDonough  Power 


964  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

ponderings  were  on  issues  similar  to  the  Indiana  cases  of  /////'"  and 
Huber.^^^  In  Kansas,  the  issue  of  whether  an  ** additional  party''  or 
''phantom  tortfeasor"  had  to  have  actual  or  potential  liability  to  plaintiff 
was  rendered  moot  by  the  Brown  opinion.  The  Brown  court  stated: 

[W]ill  proportionate  liability  be  defeated  when  a  party  joined 
under  subsection  (c)  has  a  vahd  defense  such  as  interspousal 
immunity,  covenant  not  to  sue  and  so  forth?  The  added  party 
in  such  case  would  not  be  a  party  ''against  whom  such  recovery 
is  allowed"  and  if  subsection  (d)  is  taken  literally  such  a  party's 
percentage  of  fault  should  not  be  considered  in  determining  the 
judgment  to  be  rendered.  It  appears  after  considering  the  intent 
and  purposes  of  the  entire  statute  that  such  a  party's  fault  should 
be  considered  in  each  case  to  determine  the  other  defendant's 
percentage  of  fault  and  liability,  if  any.  .  .  .  [W]e  conclude  the 
intent  and  purpose  of  the  legislature  in  adopting  K.S.A.  60-258a 
was  to  impose  individual  liability  for  damages  based  on  the 
proportionate  fault  of  all  parties  to  the  occurrence  .  .  .  even 
though  one  or  more  parties  cannot  be  joined  formally  as  a 
litigant  or  be  held  legally  responsible  for  his  or  her  proportionate 
fault. '5^ 

Although  the  nonparty  in  question  had  not  been  joined  under  Section 
60-25 8a(c),  the  court  found  that  the  pleadings  and  evidence  were  sufficient 
to  have  his  fault  considered,  thus  initiating  the  "phantom  tortfeasor" 
concept. '^^  This  encompasses  tortfeasors  not  joined  for  whatever  reason, 


Equip.,  437  F.  Supp.  707  (D.  Kan.  1977),  where  the  court  distinguished  between  plaintiff's 
voluntary  choice  not  to  sue  an  involved  entity  or  individual  (as  when  plaintiff  settles  with 
a  potential  defendant)  and  an  involuntary  non  joinder  by  plaintiff.  See  Nagunst  v.  Western 
Union,  76  F.R.D.  631  (D.  Kan.  1977).  The  Greenwood  court  stated  that  plaintiff  should 
not  be  able  to  use  a  voluntary  choice  not  to  sue  in  order  to  avoid  a  damaging  allocation 
of  fault  to  immune  or  insolvent  tortfeasors,  but  notes  that  a  different  result  obtains  in 
a  situation  such  as  in  Beach,  where  the  plaintiff's  inabihty  to  sue  the  employer  was 
involuntary.  Greenwood,  437  F.  Supp.  at  713. 

152.  Hill  v.  Metro.  Trucking,  659  F.  Supp.  430  (N.D.  Ind.  1987). 

153.  Huber  v.  Henley,  669  F.  Supp.  1474  (S.D.  Ind.  1987).  See  supra  notes  79  - 
84  and  accompanying  text. 

154.  Brown  v.  Kiell,  224  Kan.   195,  204,  580  P.2d  867,  876  (1978). 

155.  Id.  The  Kansas  District  Judges  Association  Committee  on  Pattern  Jury  In- 
structions has  provided  an  instruction  to  be  used  in  directing  the  jury  in  the  consideration 
of  the  fault  of  a  nonparty  or  phantom: 

In  this  case  it  is  claimed  that  [namel  was  at  fault  in  the  (collision)  (occurrence) 
in  question.  Even  though  (he)  (she)  has  (they  have)  not  appeared  or  offered 
evidence,  it  is  necessary  that  you  determine  whether  [namel  was  at  fault  in  the 
(collision)  (occurrence)  and  determine  the  percentage  of  fault,  if  any,  attributable 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  965 

whose  fault  is  still  presented  to  and  allocated  by  the  jury:  "Under 
[Section]  60-258a  all  tortfeasors  may  be  made  parties  to  a  lawsuit  and 
even  if  they  are  not  made  parties  their  percentage  of  fault  may  be 
determined.  "'^^ 

With  Brown,  the  Kansas  Supreme  Court  summarily  disposed  of 
common  law  joint  and  several  liability  in  favor  of  totally  proportionate 
liability,  which  then  paved  the  way  for  an  interpretation  of  the  Kansas 
"additional  party"  provisions  of  section  60-258a(c)  designed  to  prevent 
plaintiff  from  circumventing  proportional  allocation. ^^^  The  interpretation 
of  the  additional  party  portion  of  the  statute  apparently  included  en- 
dowing courts  with  a  discretionary  power  to  create  "phantom  parties," 
whose  fault  was  evaluated  without  their  being  joined  by  a  named  de- 
fendant, as  was  done  in  Brown.  The  feasibility  of  such  a  solution  to 
allocation  questions  is  questionable  in  Indiana  because  the  nonparty 
defense  must  specifically  be  asserted  by  a  named  defendant,  and  ap- 
parently may  not  be  raised  sua  sponte  by  the  court. '^^  If  defendants 
desire  to  spread  the  fault  among  nonparties,  they  must  plan  ahead  and 


to  (him)  (her)  (them). 

Pattern  Instructions  for  Kansas,  Civil,  PIK  20.05  (Supp.   1975).  The  Comment  to  PIK 

20.05  states: 

Where  the  evidence  warrants  it,  the  court  must  add  that  person  as  a  party  solely 
for  the  purpose  of  determining  and  allocating  fault  on  a  one  hundred  percent 
basis.  .  .  .  This  situation  may  exist  where  a  contributing  tortfeasor  was  given  a 
release  with  reservations,  a  covenant  not  to  sue,  or  may  be  unavailable  as  a 
party  for  lack  of  jurisdiction  or  unidentif lability,  such  as  a  phantom  driver.  A 
settling  tortfeasor  or  absent  tortfeasor  is  a  party  only  for  the  purpose  of  allocation 
of  percentage  of  fault. 

Id.,  Comment  to  PIK  20.05.  The  Comment  then  cites  Pierringer  v.  Hoger,  21  Wis. 2d 

182,  124  N.W.2d  106  (1963)  for  the  "reason  and  procedure  in  accounting  for  the  fault 

of  a  setthng  tortfeasor  who  was  not  joined  as  a  party."  Id. 

156.  Miles  v.  West,  224  Kan.  284,  287,  580  P.2d  876,  879  (1978).  Miles  was  decided 
four  days  after  Brown,  and  served  to  reaffirm  the  conclusions  reached  in  Brown.  Cf.  V. 
Schwartz,  Comparative  Negligence  §  16.5  (1986),  stating:  "A  result  .  .  .  compatible 
with  the  goals  of  comparative  negligence  is  reached  by  determining  the  negligence  of  all 
concurrent  tortfeasors  irrespective  of  whether  they  are  parties  to  the  suit."  Id. 

157.  Plaintiff  was  not  allowed  to  circumvent  proportional  allocation  by  carefully 
choosing  whom  to  name  as  defendant.  This  hearkens  back  to  the  concerns  aired  by  the 
federal  court  in  Beach  v.  M  &  N  Modern  Hydraulic  Press,  428  F.  Supp.  956  (D.  Kan. 
1977)  and  Greenwood  v.  McDonough  Power  Equip.,  437  F.  Supp.  707  (D.  Kan.  1977), 
both  of  which  refused  to  allow  plaintiff  to  circumvent  total  allocation,  whether  the 
circumvention  was  purposeful  on  plaintiff's  part  (not  joining  a  settled  party)  or  involuntary 
(due  to  immunity  on  the  part  of  a  tortfeasor).  See  supra  notes  117  -  124  and  accompanying 
text;  Wilkins,  supra  note  47,  at  732-33. 

158.  IND.  Code  §  34-4-33-10(b)  (1988).  See  Walters  v.  Dean,  497  N.E.2d  247  (Ind. 
Ct.  App.  1986);  supra  notes  70-80  and  accompanying  text. 


966  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

carefully  follow  the  Act,  and  may  name  only  identified  or  identifiable 
nonparties. '^^ 

The  Kansas  cases  evidence  a  strong  orientation  toward  the  fair 
allocation  poHcies  of  tort  systems,  which  tend  to  favor  defendants, 
without  consideration  of  the  compensation  oriented  policies.  The  Indiana 
Act,  with  its  emphasis  on  precise  allocation,  has  the  potential  to  be  very 
similar  to  the  Kansas  system  as  interpreted  in  Brown  if  the  state  courts 
decide,  as  the  Kansas  court  did,  that  joint  and  several  liability  has  been 
displaced  by  comparative  fault. 

2.  Kansas  Settlement  Cases. — As  contemplated  in  Indiana's  Gray  v. 
Chacon,^^^  the  abolition  of  joint  and  several  liability  in  Kansas  resulted 
in  the  concomitant  abolition  of  the  release  rule.  Again,  the  issue  first 
came  up  in  federal  court.  In  Stueve  v.  American  Honda  Motors  Co.,^^^ 
the  plaintiff  settled  with  the  other  party  involved  in  a  coUision,  and 
then  pressed  suit  against  the  manufacturer  of  plaintiffs  decedent's  mo- 
torcycle. ^^^  Predicated  on  the  Brown  opinion,  the  court  decided  that  the 
abolition  of  joint  and  several  liability  made  any  release  irrelevant  as  far 
as  the  manufacturer  was  concerned,  because  each  defendant  could  be 
held  Uable  '*only  for  that  percentage  of  injury  attributable  to  his  fault, 
[and]  a  release  of  [one]  defendant  cannot  inure  to  the  benefit  of  potential 
co-defendants."'" 

A  state  court  decided  this  question  in  Geier  v.  Wikel,^^  where  plaintiff 
gave  a  release  to  a  railroad  company,  whose  train  had  been  involved 
in  an  accident  which  injured  plaintiff,  and  then  sued  the  driver  of  the 
car  involved.'"  The  court  of  appeals  decided  that  because  all  the  fault 
was  to  be  allocated  to  the  persons  involved  regardless  of  immunity  or 
whether  they  had  been  joined,  and  because  the  abrogation  of  joint  and 
several  liability  prevented  the  plaintiff  from  collecting  anything  but  a 
defendant's  assigned  portion  of  liability  from  that  defendant,  the  release 
rule  was  no  longer  appHcable.'^^  The  court  stated: 


159.  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-6  (1988)  requires  that  the  name  of  the  nonparty  appear 
on  the  verdict  form. 

160.  684  F.  Supp.  1481  (S.D.  Ind.  1988).  See  supra  notes  50-59  and  accompanying 
text. 

161.  457  F.  Supp.  740  (D.  Kan.  1978). 

162.  Id.  at  745.  The  court  established  that  it  believed  that  Kansas  state  courts  would 
find  the  comparative  fault  act  apphcable  to  products  Uability  cases.  Id.  at  750-56.  See 
also  3  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  167  (Vernon  Supp.  1988). 

163.  Stueve,  457  F.  Supp.  at  748-49.  The  court  also  decreed  the  effect  that  the 
covenant  not  to  sue  should  have  on  the  overall  award:  "(DJefendant  should  receive  a  pro 
rata  credit  against  any  award  calculated  with  reference  to  the  percentage  of  fault  attributed 
to  [the  releasee]."  Id. 

164.  4  Kan.  App.  2d  188,  603  P.2d  1028  (1979). 

165.  Id.  at  1030. 

166.  Id. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  967 

An  injured  party  whose  claim  is  exclusively  subject  to  the  Kansas 
comparative  negligence  statute  may  now  settle  with  any  person 
or  entity  whose  fault  may  have  contributed  to  the  injuries  without 
that  settlement  in  any  way  affecting  his  or  her  right  to  recover 
from  any  other  party  liable  under  the  act.  The  injured  party  is 
entitled  to  keep  the  advantage  of  his  or  her  bargaining,  just  as 
he  or  she  must  Uve  with  an  inadequate  settlement  should  the 
jury  determine  larger  damages  or  a  larger  proportion  of  fault 
than  the  injured  party  anticipated  when  the  settlement  was 
reached.  ^^"^ 

This  decision  clearly  shows  the  effect  of  Brown  and  the  federal  decisions 
on  partial  settlements  under  the  Kansas  comparative  negligence  scheme. 
The  fault  of  the  settHng  tortfeasor  will  be  considered  with  the  fault  of 
named  defendants,  regardless  of  whether  the  settUng  party  was  joined 
as  an  "additional  party"  or  had  her  fault  considered  in  the  "phantom" 
mode.  Plaintiff  is  free  to  settle  with  any  party  she  chooses,  but  her 
award  will  be  diminished  by  the  settHng  tortfeasor's  proportion  of  fault. 

Geier  made  it  clear  that  plaintiffs  must  accurately  estimate  the 
defendant's  proportion  of  fault  and  get  the  absolute  best  bargain  they 
can,  in  order  to  offset  the  potential  loss  of  large  percentages  of  their 
damages.  Defendants  must  estimate  accurately  in  order  to  avoid  a  set- 
tlement which  would  allow  plaintiff  a  windfall.  However,  under  this 
system,  a  defendant  who  does  not  settle  need  not  worry  about  paying 
more  than  her  proportion  of  fault,  and  need  not  worry  that  she  will 
be  responsible  for  the  fault  of  unjoined  tortfeasors.  Plaintiff,  on  the 
other  hand,  knows  that  she  will  have  to  be  concerned  with  the  pro- 
portionate fault  of  all  involved  tortfeasors,  and  may  not  control  from 
whom  she  will  recover.  This  means  that  the  flexibility  of  the  Kansas 
system  is  minimal  and  that  it  does  not  particularly  encourage  partial 
settlement  unless  the  defendant  is  convinced  that  she  is  settling  for  much 
less  than  her  proportionate  fault  and  unless  the  plaintiff  is  sure  she  is 
settling  for  more  than  the  settling  defendant's  proportion  of  fault. 

3.  '^Comparative  Implied  Indemnity'*. — Settling  tortfeasors  had  no 
right  of  contribution  in  Kansas  under  contributory  fault,  ^^^  and  it  ap- 
peared that  the  same  finality  would  be  true  of  settlement  under  com- 


167.  Id. 

168.  Settlements  were  final,  contractual  matters  between  plaintiff  and  the  settling 
defendant.  Statutory  contribution  was  reserved  for  joint  judgment  debtors,  and  had  to 
be  triggered  by  the  payment  of  the  entire  judgment  by  one  of  the  jointly  Uable  defendants, 
who  could  then  pursue  other  defendants  for  contribution.  See  supra  notes  106-09  and 
accompanying  text. 


968  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

parative  negligence  until  the  case  of  Kennedy  v.  City  of  Sawyer .^^^  In 
Kennedy,  plaintiff  sued  the  city,  which  had  had  weedkiller  sprayed  near 
plaintiff's  land,  killing  plaintiff's  cattle. '^°  The  city  filed  a  third  party 
complaint  against  the  chemical  company  that  had  sold  the  weedkiller  to 
the  city;  the  chemical  company  in  turn  filed  a  third  party  petition  against 
the  manufacturer  of  the  weedkiller. '^^  The  trial  court  found  against  the 
city  and  dismissed  both  third  party  complaints. ^^^  While  the  city's  appeal 
was  pending,  plaintiff  and  the  city  settled,  using  a  document  which 
released  the  entire  claim. ^"^^ 

The  City  of  Sawyer  persisted  in  its  appeal,  objecting  to  the  dismissal 
of  the  third  party  defendants  against  whom  it  sought  indemnification.  ^^^ 
The  Kansas  Supreme  Court  decided  that  although  the  chemical  company 
and  manufacturer  had  not  been  brought  in  as  additional  parties  under 
Section  60-25 8a(c),  the  pleadings  were  complete  enough  to  consider  them 
in  that  light. '^^ 

The  court  determined  that  traditional  indemnity  shifted  one  hundred 
percent  of  the  loss  from  the  indemnitee  to  the  indemnitor,  ^"'^  where 
contribution  shifted  only  a  portion  of  the  responsibility.  Finding  that 
the  release  given  to  the  City  of  Sawyer  had  reheved  the  third  party 
defendants  of  any  possible  liability  to  the  plaintiff, ^'^'^  the  court  held: 

[I]n  comparative  negligence  cases  when  full  settlement  of  all 
liability  to  an  injured  party  has  been  accomplished  and  a  release 
obtained,  proportionate  causal  responsibility  among  the  tortfea- 


169.  228  Kan.  439,  618  P.2d  788  (1980).  See  Note,  Torts  -  Indemnification,  Set- 
tlement, and  Release  in  Strict  Products  Liability  in  the  Wake  of  Kennedy  v.  City  of 
Sawyer,  30  Univ.  Kan.  L.  Rev.  131  (1981)  for  an  exploration  of  some  of  the  issues 
brought  up  in  Kennedy,  which  was  procedurally  both  awkward  and  complex. 

170.  Kennedy,  228  Kan.  at  442,  618  P.2d  at  791. 

171.  Id.  at  793-94,  (The  third  party  joinder  provisions  appear  at  Kan.  Stat.  Ann. 
§  60-214  (1983)). 

172.  Id.  at  792.  The  trial  court  had  not  considered  comparative  fault  in  this  decision. 
Id. 

173.  Id.  at  791-93. 

174.  Id. 

175.  Id.  at  794-95.  This  included  a  determination  that  the  comparative  negligence 
act  was  applicable  in  strict  products  liability  cases.  Id.  at  797-98. 

176.  The  court  distinguished  between  express  indemnity  (by  contract)  and  implied 
indemnity,  where  one  is  made  to  pay  a  loss  that,  by  rights,  another  was  responsible  for, 
e.g.,  respondeat  superior.  The  indemnity  claimed  in  Kennedy  was  implied  indemnity.  Id. 
at  801-2. 

177.  The  court  distinguished  the  release  from  the  one  used  in  Geier  v.  Wikel,  4 
Kan.  App.  2d  188,  603  P. 2d  1028,  because  the  Geier  release  had  indicated  an  intent  to 
pursue  the  claim  further  against  other  tortfeasors,  whereas  the  Kennedy  release  had  indicated 
an  intent  to  completely  release  all  parties  involved.  Kennedy,  228  Kan.  at  450,  618  P. 2d 
at  799. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  969 

sors  should  be  determined  and  indemnity  should  be  decreed 
based  on  degree  of  causation  of  the  respective  tortfeasors. ^^^ 

This  scheme  was  christened  ^'comparative  implied  indemnity,"  and  was 
triggered  when  one  party  with  actual  legal  liability  obtained  a  full  release 
in  exchange  for  a  reasonable  amount,  and  then  continued  the  action 
against  the  nonsettHng  defendants  under  an  indemnity  theory. •'^^  While 
the  court  called  this  solution  indemnity,  it  is  clear  that  the  proportionate 
nature  of  the  repayment,  and  the  overtones  of  joint  and  several  liability 
evident  in  one  tortfeasor's  paying  the  entire  obligation  (albeit  voluntarily), 
have  more  the  flavor  of  contribution  than  indemnity.  The  court  itself 
described  indemnity  as  a  one  hundred  percent  reallocation,  proportional 
reallocation  being  the  mark  of  contribution. '^°  Judge  Woods  of  the 
Eastern  District  of  Arkansas  stated:  "This  form  of  'comparative  implied 
indemnity'  is  nothing  more  than  contribution  according  to  proportionate 
fault.  "'81 

The  Kansas  Supreme  Court  appeared  to  regret  this  broad  holding, 
and  narrowed  and  explained  itself  in  Ellis  v.  Union  Pacific  Railroad 
Co. '8^  Following  a  car-train  collision,  plaintiffs  sued  the  railroad  company 
which  then  joined  certain  governmental  entities  for  a  determination  of 
their  proportion  of  fault  pursuant  to  Section  60-258a(c).i8^  Plaintiffs  did 


178.  Kennedy,  228  Kan.  at  455,  618  P.2d  at  804. 

179.  Id.  at  803.  The  court  was  very  specific  on  the  procedures  to  be  used:  plaintiff's 
fault  was  to  be  determined  only  insofar  as  to  establish  that  actual  legal  liability  had 
existed  (i.e.,  that  plaintiff  was  not  forty-nine  percent  or  more  at  fault);  defendant  had 
the  responsibility  to  bring  in  all  parties  it  considered  causally  negligent;  the  apportionment 
was  to  be  made  in  the  pending  action,  or  a  separate  action  if  suit  had  not  been  filed; 
the  court  would  determine  a  reasonable  settlement  figure  if  the  action  had  not  progressed 
as  far  as  the  jury  for  determination  of  damages;  and  the  maximum  amount  to  be 
redistributed  was  to  be  the  amount  of  the  settlement.  Id. 

180.  In  Note,  supra  note  169,  the  author  describes  this  innovation  in  his  conclusion 
as  comparative  contribution.  The  dissenting  opinion  took  issue  with  the  majority's  cavalier 
treatment  of  the  fact  that  the  chemical  company  and  the  manufacturer  were  in  the  action 
as  third-party  defendants  under  Kan.  Stat.  Ann.  §  60-214  (1983)  for  indemnity  rather 
than  being  in  the  action  as  joint  tortfeasors,  and  preferred  that  the  action  be  treated  as 
one  for  one  hundred  percent  indemnity  on  a  contractual  theory.  Id.  at  805-07.  The 
comparative  implied  indemnity  concept  not  only  differed  from  traditional  indemnity  (which 
could  be  sued  for  post-settlement,  Cason  v.  Geis  Irrigation  Co.,  211  Kan.  406,  507  P. 2d 
295  (1973),  if  the  proposed  indemnitee  could  prove  that  she  was  legally  liable)  but  also 
from  Kansas'  limited  statutory  contribution  under  contributory  fault,  which  was  not  allowed 
for  mere  settlement,  but  required  that  one  defendant  pay  an  entire  joint  judgment.  See 
supra  notes  107-08. 

181.  H.  Woods,  Comparative  Fault  §  13:20,  at  293  (1987). 

182.  231  Kan.  182,  643  P.2d  158,  affd  on  rehearing,  232  Kan.  194,  653  P.2d  816 
(1982)  (with  dissenters  also  affirming  their  dissents). 

183.  Id.  The  governmental  entities  were  the  county,  township,  and  city  in  which 
the  accident  occurred. 


970  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

not  amend  their  complaint  to  assert  any  claims  against  the  governmental 
entities,  and  the  governmental  entities  specifically  forbade  the  defendants 
to  settle  the  case  on  their  behalf.  The  railroad  defendants  then  settled 
with  the  plaintiffs  in  a  form  which  specifically  released  the  governmental 
entities  and  pledged  the  plaintiffs'  assistance  to  the  railroad  in  obtaining 
indemnity  for  the  settlement.  The  trial  court  dismissed  the  indemnity 
claims  and  the  railroad  appealed. ^^"^ 

The  Kansas  Supreme  Court  analyzed  Ellis  in  terms  of  its  decision 
in  the  Kennedy  case.^^^  Comparative  impHed  indemnity  was  seen  as  a 
method  to  encourage  complete  settlements:  for  plaintiffs  because  they 
could  achieve  full  compensation  in  one  transaction,  for  defendants  be- 
cause they  could  get  proportional  repayment  for  settling  the  entire  claim 
if  the  consideration  given  was  reasonable. ^^^ 

The  pivotal  point  in  distinguishing  Ellis  from  Kennedy  was  the 
position  occupied  by  and  the  liability  of  the  additional  parties.'®^  The 
court  perceived  the  purposes  of  Section  60-258a(c)  to  be  to  reduce  the 
defendant's  potential  liability  by  allocating  fault  to  other  causally  re- 
sponsible persons  and  to  prevent  the  plaintiff  from  circumventing  the 
allocation  procedures  by  strategic  choice  of  defendants. '^^  The  provision 
benefitted  defendants  only,  not  affecting  plaintiff's  case  by  the  possibility 
of  greater  recovery  from  the  additional  parties. ^^^  This  led  to  the  con- 
clusion that  although  defendant  had  followed  the  procedures  laid  down 
in  Kennedy,  its  joinder  of  the  governmental  entities  by  use  of  Section 
60-25  8a(c)  had  not  asserted  a  claim  against  those  entities  that  would 
subject  them  to  monetary  liability,  and  plaintiff  had  not  asserted  any 
claim  against  them.'^^ 

The  upshot  of  this  was  that  the  Kennedy  decision  was  strictly  limited: 
if  the  proposed  indemnitor  could  not  have  had  any  actual  Uability  to 


184.  Id.  The  dismissal  was  because  plaintiffs  had  never  asserted  a  valid  claim  against 
the  governmental  entities,  although  they  had  had  the  opportunity  to  do  so  before  the 
statute  of  limitations  ran.  Id. 

185.  Id.  at  186,  643  P. 2d  at  162.  The  court  noted  that  the  new  comparative  implied 
indemnity  concept,  which  it  compared  to  the  "partial  indemnity"  concept  of  American 
Motorcycle  Ass'n  v.  Superior  Court,  20  Cal.  3d  578,  146  Cal.  Rptr.  182,  578  P.2d  899 
(1978),  had  the  potential  to  be  confused  with  the  traditional  concept  of  contribution.  The 
court  stated  that  this  confusion  should  be  avoided,  and  that  the  concept  was  a  modernization 
to  bring  the  traditional  all  or  nothing  indemnity  concept  into  accord  with  the  principles 
of  comparative  negligence.  Id. 

186.  Ellis,  231  Kan.  at  186,  643  P.2d  at  162. 

187.  Id.  at  188,  643  P.2d  at  164. 

188.  Id. 

189.  Id. 

190.  In  contrast,  the  court  found  that  the  settling  defendant  in  Kennedy  had  asserted 
a  third  party  claim  against  the  additional  parties  which  would  have  subjected  them  to 
monetary  Uability.  Id.  at  189,  643  P.2d  at  165. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  971 

plaintiff,  then  the  proposed  indemnitee  could  not  call  for  comparative 
implied  indemnity.  The  court  would  not  allow  the  settling  defendant  to 
''broaden  another  defendant's  liability  beyond  what  it  would  have  been 
had  the  case  gone  to  trial.  "^^^ 

Two  dissents  to  the  Ellis  majority  opinion  vociferously  contested  the 
analysis  leading  to  this  holding.  The  first  stated  that  a  joinder  under 
Section  60-258a(c)  should  be  a  joinder  for  all  purposes. ^^^  The  other 
stated  that  not  treating  Section  60-258a(c)  as  a  joinder  for  all  purposes 
also  had  the  effect  of  rendering  it  useless,  as  the  apportionment  of  fault 
to  parties  not  named  by  plaintiff  could  just  as  easily  be  accomplished 
by  defendant's  naming  the  nonparties  in  her  answer,  the  "phantom 
tortfeasor"  concept,  as  was  approved  in  Brown. ^^^ 

Indiana  has  always  forbidden  contribution,  ^^"^  and  the  Comparative 
Fault  Act  perpetuates  this  in  Section  34-4-33-7:  "In  an  action  under  this 
chapter,  there  is  no  right  of  contribution  among  tortfeasors.  However, 
this  section  does  not  affect  any  rights  of  indemnity.  "'^^  Proportional 
repayment  between  joint  tortfeasors  is  usually  a  remedy  aimed  at  evening 
out  the  effects  of  joint  and  several  liability,  and  so  is  not  considered 
necessary  in  the  absence  of  joint  and  several  Hability.  The  Kansas  court 
found  this  to  be  untrue  in  a  context  where  one  defendant  settles  on 
behalf  of  all,  and  in  Kennedy  attempted  to  make  this  settlement  situation 
more  fair  to  the  defendant  who  has  settled. 

However,  questions  arose  out  of  Kennedy  relating  to  the  finality  of 
settlements  and  releases  in  the  one  defendant-full  settlement  context.  The 
Kennedy  decision  muddied  the  water  on  the  issue  of  whether  contribution 
was  or  was  not  allowed  after  a  full  settlement,  who  would  have  to 
contribute,  and  what  their  liability  to  plaintiff  had  to  be.  Ellis,  in 
attempting  to  refine  "comparative  impHed  indemnity,"  further  confused 


191.  Id.  "The  plaintiff  may  choose  to  forgo  any  recovery  from  other  tort-feasors. 
In  that  event,  a  settUng  defendant  has  no  claim  to  settle  but  his  own."  Id.  at  190,  643 
P.2d  at  166.  See  also  Teepak,  Inc.  v.  Learned,  237  Kan.  320,  699  P.2d  35  (1985)  (later 
case  in  which  Ellis  was  followed). 

192.  Ellis,  231  Kan.  at  190,  643  P.2d  at  166.  (Herd,  J.,  dissenting)  Justice  Herd 
noted  that  a  distinction  had  been  made  in  Brown  between  parties  formally  joined  and 
those  who  were  not  formally  joined  but  had  their  fault  allocated  anyway,  stating:  "This 
distinction  indicates  formal  joinder  with  service  of  process  can  impose  Habihty  independant 
of  a  formal  assertion  of  a  claim."  Id. 

193.  Id.  at  192,  643  P. 2d  at  168  (Fromme,  J.,  dissenting).  Fromme,  J.,  who  had 
authored  the  Brown  and  Kennedy  opinions,  joined  in  Herd's  dissent  and  elaborated  further 
in  his  own,  stating  that  he  saw  "no  vaUd  reason  for  the  court  to  set  up  a  different  rule 
in  cases  based  on  ordinary  negligence,"  Id.  at  167,  and  that  he  felt  that  the  majority 
had  limited  the  Kennedy  opinion  to  products  hability  cases,  thus  discouraging  settlement 
of  plaintiff's  entire  claim  by  defendants.  Id. 

194.  See  supra  note  38  and  accompanying  text. 

195.  IND.  Code  §  34-4-33-7  (1988). 


972  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

the  issue,  and  the  court's  distinction  between  indemnity  and  contribution 
(made  with  the  intent  of  assuring  that  comparative  impUed  indemnity 
was  not  to  be  confiised  with  contribution)  remains  unclear. 

Despite  the  fact  that  indemnity  is  specifically  permitted  by  the  Indiana 
Act,  given  Indiana's  tradition  of  barring  contribution  between  tortfeasors, 
even  if  Indiana  follows  the  case  law  of  Kansas  in  interpreting  its  own 
Act,  it  is  unlikely  that  Indiana  courts  will  take  the  path  that  Kansas 
courts  took  in  this  settlement  situation.  This  is  so  regardless  of  the  fact 
that  Indiana  encourages  full  settlement  by  defendants  early  in  the  pro- 
ceedings. The  cases  illustrate,  however,  the  awkwardness  of  the  solutions 
to  the  problems  caused  by  the  inflexibility  of  the  Kansas  system,  which 
should  warn  Indiana  courts  to  avoid  the  pitfalls  of  interpreting  the  Act 
in  a  haphazard  fashion. 

Apparently  the  Kansas  court  felt  the  need  to  reinstate  some  sort  of 
allocation  between  wrongdoers  in  the  full  settlement  context.  In  doing 
so,  it  hit  upon  * 'comparative  implied  indemnity,"  which  is  remarkably 
similar  to  the  joint  judgment  obligor  statutory  system  of  contribution 
which  had  been  used  under  contributory  fault  in  Kansas. '^^  The  difference 
between  the  two  is  that  the  reallocation  is  proportional  (which  means 
that  the  fault  must  be  allocated  in  court)  rather  than  in  equal  shares, 
and  that  * 'comparative  implied  indemnity"  apparently  applies  only  in 
the  full  settlement  context,  whereas  statutory  contribution  applied  only 
if  a  joint  tortfeasor  paid  an  entire  judgment. 

The  Kennedy  and  Ellis  cases  continue  the  emphasis  of  the  Kansas 
system  on  proper  allocation  of  fault  so  that  no  defendant  pays  more 
than  her  fair  share  of  a  plaintiff's  damages.  The  Kansas  Act  has  as  its 
main  focus  the  proper  proportional  allocation  of  fault  between  tortfea- 
sors, leaving  plaintiff  to  bear  the  possibility  of  insolvent  or  immune 
tortfeasors  and  the  risks  involved  in  settlement.  Other  states,  specifically 
Minnesota,  demonstrate  that  a  system  which  has  the  opposite  emphasis, 
that  is,  a  compensation-oriented  system,  can  achieve  the  fairness  sought 
by  the  Kansas  courts. 

IV.     Minnesota  Comparative  Fault 
A.     Background:  Prior  to  Comparative  Fault 

Under  contributory  fault,  Minnesota  differentiated  between  covenants 
not  to  sue  and  releases. ^^"^  Prior  to  the  enactment  of  Minnesota's  com- 
parative fault  act  in  1969,  the  courts  had  arrived  at  a  system  whereby 


196.  See  supra  notes  107-08  and  accompanying  text. 

197.  See,  e.g.,  Gronquist  v.  Olson,  242  Minn.   119,   123,  64  N.W.2d  159,   163-64 
(1954). 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  973 

the  intent  behind  a  settlement  determined  whether  it  constituted  a  cov- 
enant not  to  sue  or  a  release,  regardless  of  what  the  document  was 
called. ^^^  While  a  release  of  one  joint  tortfeasor  released  all,'^^  several 
factors  were  considered  in  determining  whether  a  compromise  was  a 
release  or  merely  a  covenant  not  to  sue,  the  first  being  the  intent  of 
the  parties  to  the  agreement. ^^  If  by  its  terms  the  release  only  appHed 
to  some  of  the  joint  tortfeasors,  it  was  not  a  release  unless  it  plainly 
said  so,  a  reservation  of  rights  being  unnecessary  to  retain  those  rights, 
but  indicative  of  the  intent  behind  the  settlement. ^^^ 

The  second  determinative  factor  was  whether  or  not  the  plaintiff 
had  received  full  compensation  under  the  agreement. ^^^  Plaintiff  was 
entitled  to  only  one  recovery,  and  a  full  satisfaction  amounted  to  a 
release. ^°^  However,  if  plaintiff  received  a  partial  satisfaction  not  intended 
to  be  a  release  of  the  entire  claim,  she  was  free  to  pursue  her  claim 
among  the  other  tortfeasors  and  was  not  barred  on  her  claim  until  she 
received  full  satisfaction.^^  Any  partial  satisfaction  served  to  diminish 
plaintiff's  ultimate  award  pro  tanto.^^^ 

Joint  and  several  Uability  balanced  by  contribution  among  tortfeasors 
was  the  rule  in  Minnesota. ^°^  The  courts  imposed  a  strict  requirement 
that  in  order  to  garner  contribution  from  codefendants  after  having  paid 
more  than  her  equal  share  of  a  joint  judgment,  the  proposed  contributee 
must  show  that  there  was  common  Uability,  not  merely  common  neg- 
ligence, between  herself  and  the  co-defendants. ^°^ 

B.     Comparative  Fault 

Minnesota  initially  adopted  comparative  negligence  based  on  the 
Wisconsin  statute  in  1969.^°^  The  system  was  refined  over  the  years  and 


198.  Id.  at  163  (citing  Musolf  v.  Duluth  Edison  Elect.  Co.,  108  Minn.  369,  122 
N.W.  499  (1909);  Joyce  v.  Massachusetts  Real  Estate  Co.,  173  Minn.  310,  217  N.W.  337 
(1928)). 

199.  Joyce,  173  Minn,  at  311,  217  N.W.  at  338. 

200.  Gronquist,  242  Minn,  at  124,  64  N.W.2d  at  165. 

201.  Joyce,  173  Minn,  at  311,  217  N.W.  at  338. 

202.  Gronquist,  242  Minn,  at  124,  64  N.W.2d  at  165. 

203.  Philips  V.  Aretz,  215  Minn  325,  10  N.W.2d  226  (1943). 

204.  Gronquist,  242  Minn,  at  124,  64  N.W.2d  at  164-65  (citing  Musolf  v.  Duluth 
Edison  Elect.  Co.,  108  Minn.  369,  122  N.W.  499). 

205.  Id. 

206.  See  Underwriters  at  Lloyd's  of  Minneapolis  v.  Smith,  166  Minn.  388,  208 
N.W.  13  (1926);  American  Auto  Ins.  Co.  v.  Moiling,  239  Minn.  74,  57  N.W.2d  843 
(1953).  See  also  Note,  Contribution  and  Indemnity  -An  Examination  of  the  Upheaval 
in  Minnesota  Tort  Loss  Allocation  Concepts,  5  Wm.  Mitchell  L.  Rev.  109,  118  (1979). 

207.  American  Auto  Ins.,  239  Minn.  74,  57  N.W. 2d  847;  Lunderberg  v.  Bierman, 
241  Minn.  349,  63  N.W.2d  355  (1954). 

208.  See  supra  notes  11-16  and  accompanying  text. 


974  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

in  1978  was  revised  to  resemble  the  Uniform  Comparative  Fault  Act.^^^ 
Section  604.01  of  the  Minnesota  Act  provides  for  the  abolition  of 
contributory  fault  and  its  replacement  with  comparative  fault, ^'°  defines 
fault, ^^^  and  specifically  makes  provision  for  the  effects  of  settlement  in 
subdivisions  (2),  (3),  (4),  and  (5).^'^ 

Section  604.04(5)  of  the  Minnesota  Act  requires  that  settlements 
made  "shall  be  credited  against  any  final  settlement  or  judgment," 
provided  only  that  if  the  settlement  is  for  more  than  the  settling  party's 
liability,  if  any,  the  plaintiff  is  not  required  to  refund  any  part  of  it.^'^ 
The  subdivision  further  provides  that  the  plaintiff's  proportion  of  fault 
shall  first  be  measured  against  the  defendant's  and  if  the  defendant's 
is  greater,  the  plaintiff's  proportion  of  fault  shall  be  subtracted  (pursuant 


209.  See  supra  notes  11-16  and  accompanying  text. 

210.  Contributory  fault  shall  not  bar  recovery  in  an  action  by  any 
person  ...  to  recover  for  fault  resulting  in  death  or  injury  to  person  or  property, 
if  the  contributory  fault  was  not  greater  than  the  fault  of  the  person  against 
whom  recovery  is  sought,   but  any  damages  allowed  shall  be  diminished  in 
proportion  to  the  amount  of  fault  attributable  to  the  person  recovering. 

Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01(1)  (West  1988).  It  should  be  noticed  that  this  statute  requires 
that  the  plaintiff's  fault  be  measured  against  that  of  each  defendant  individually,  as 
opposed  to  the  fault  of  all  the  defendants  in  aggregate  as  is  done  in  Kansas  and  apparently 
Indiana.  See  H.  Woods,  Comparative  Fault,  Appendix  (1987).  This  became  an  issue  in 
several  cases  involving  settlement  and  contribution  issues  because  a  defendant  with  less 
fault  than  the  plaintiff  is  considered  not  liable  to  the  plaintiff,  and  hence  has  no  common 
liability  with  the  defendant  seeking  contribution.  See  Hosley  v.  Armstrong  Cork  Co.,  364 
N.W.2d  813,  817  (Minn.  App.  1985),  rev'd  on  other  grounds,  383  N.W.2d  289  (Minn. 
1986). 

211.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01(l)(a)  (West  1988). 

212.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01(2),  (3),  (4),  and  (5).  Subdivisions  (2)  and  (3)  provide 
that  any  settlement  or  payment  for  personal  injury,  death  or  damage  to  property  shall 
not  be  considered  admissions  of  liability.  Subdivision  (4)  states:  "Except  in  an  action  in 
which  settlement  and  release  has  been  pleaded  as  a  defense,  any  settlement  or  payment 
referred  to  in  subdivisions  2  and  3  shall  be  inadmissible  in  evidence  on  the  trial  of  any 
legal  action."  Subdivision  (5): 

All  settlements  or  payments  made  under  subdivisions  2  and  3  shall  be  credited 
against  any  final  settlement  or  judgment;  provided  however  that  in  the  event 
that  judgment  is  entered  against  the  person  seeking  recovery  or  if  a  verdict  is 
rendered  for  an  amount  less  than  the  total  of  any  such  advance  payments  in 
favor  of  the  recipient  thereof,  such  person  shall  not  be  required  to  refund  any 
portion  of  such  advance  payment  voluntarily  made.  Upon  motion  to  the  court 
in  the  absence  of  a  jury  and  upon  proper  proof  thereof,  prior  to  entry  of 
judgment  on  a  verdict,  the  court  shall  first  apply  the  provisions  of  subdivision 
1  and  then  shall  reduce  the  amount  of  the  damages  so  determined  by  the  amount 
of  the  payments  previously  made  to  or  on  the  behalf  of  the  person  entitled  to 
such  damages. 
Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01(5)  (West  1988). 

213.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.04(5)  (West  1988). 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  975 

to  section  604.04(1))  before  the  award  is  diminished  by  the  settlement 
amount. ^•'^ 

Despite  the  fact  that  the  Minnesota  statute  provides  for  the  effect 
of  a  settlement  on  the  allocation  process  and  result,  elaboration  was 
required  and  was  forthcoming  from  the  Minnesota  courts.  The  statute 
does  not,  for  example,  specify  whether  the  amount  subtracted  from  the 
overall  award  is  proportionate  to  the  settling  party's  fault,  or  is  a  straight 
subtraction  of  the  amount  given  in  settlement.  Logically,  under  joint 
and  several  hability,  with  its  compensation  orientation,  only  the  dollar 
amount  would  be  subtracted,  thus  guaranteeing  plaintiff  a  full  recovery 
under  joint  and  several  liability  but  no  more.^'^  However,  the  appor- 
tionment orientation  of  modern  comparative  fault  statutes  would  dictate 
that  the  subtraction  be  based  on  the  proportional  amount. 

In  Rambaum  v.  Swisher,^^^  the  Minnesota  Court  of  Appeals  plainly 
endorsed  the  proportional  credit  in  the  settlement  context,  diminishing 
the  award  to  plaintiff  not  by  the  settlement  amount  but  by  the  settling 
party's  percentage  of  fault. ^'^  Other  methods  discouraged  settlements  by 
plaintiff  because  she  would  gain  no  benefit  from  a  good  bargain  if  the 
settlement  amount  were  subtracted  regardless  of  proportion,  but  would 
still  be  disadvantaged  by  a  bad  bargain. ^^^  Defendants  would  be  dis- 


214.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.04(5).  The  order  in  which  the  plaintiff's  fault  and 
the  settlement  amount  are  subtracted  from  the  total  award  can  make  a  difference  in  the 
amount  of  plaintiff's  ultimate  recovery.  See  examples  given  and  analysis  made  in  Note, 
A  Dollars  and  Sense  Approach  to  Partial  Settlements:  Judicial  Application  of  the  Gross 
Damages  Method,  72  Iowa  L.  Rev.   1147  (1987). 

215.  See  Lanning,  Settlement  and  Liability  in  Montana:  State  Ex  Rel  Deere  &  Co. 
V.  District  Court,  48  Mont.  L.  Rev.  401,  408-13  (1987),  for  a  concise  description  of  the 
"dollar  credit  rule"  (nonsetthng  defendant  credited  with  the  dollar  amount  of  the  settlement) 
and  the  "percent  credit  approach"  (nonsettling  defendant  credited  with  the  settling  party's 
percentage  of  the  judgment  based  on  her  percentage  of  the  fault).  Mr.  Lanning  states: 
"[T]he  percent  credit  rule  merely  places  the  plaintiff  in  a  multiple-defendant  action  on 
an  equal  basis  with  the  plaintiff  in  a  single-defendant  action.  In  the  latter,  the  plaintiff 
takes  a  chance  when  setthng:  he  may  receive  more  through  settlement  than  through  trial, 
or  he  may  receive  less."  Id.  at  410.  See  also  Scwartz,  Comparative  Negligence  §  16.5 
(1986). 

216.  423  N.W.2d  68  (Minn.  App.  1988)  (citing  Anunti  v.  Payette,  268  N.W.2d  52 
(Minn.  1978)).  In  Anunti,  the  settlement  was  effected  during  the  trial,  after  the  jury  had 
begun  deliberating  but  before  the  verdict  was  returned.  The  court  interpreted  the  word 
"settlement"  in  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01(2)  and  (5)  to  refer  to  payments  made  "prior 
to  the  determination  of  the  case,"  and  found  that  since  the  settlement  between  plaintiff 
and  a  third  party  defendant  had  been  effected  during  trial  and  the  settling  defendant  was 
found  to  be  without  fault,  the  nonsettling  tortfeasor  should  not  benefit  by  the  agreement. 
The  court  refused  to  reduce  the  judgment  against  the  nonsettling  defendant  at  all.  Anunti, 
268  N.W.2d  at  56. 

217.  Rambaum,  423  N.W.2d  at  77. 

218.  Id.  The  settlement  agreement  released  the  settling  defendant's  proportion  of 


976  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

couraged  from  settling  if  they  received  a  credit  in  the  dollar  amount  of 
the  settlement  because  as  soon  as  one  tortfeasor  settled,  defendants 
would  know  that  they  would  get  the  benefit  of  plaintiffs  bargain  if  she 
settled  for  more  than  the  settling  party's  proportion  of  fault.  Also,  if 
plaintiff  settled  for  less  than  the  settling  party's  proportion  of  fault,  the 
nonsettling  defendant  would  still  be  Uable  for  only  her  own  percentage 
of  fault.^'^  The  parties  in  Rambaum  had  used  a  Pierringer  release, 
designed  to  have  the  effect  of  giving  the  nonsettling  party  a  credit  based 
on  the  settling  party's  proportion  of  fault. 

The  Minnesota  legislature  wisely  avoided  a  furor  over  how  the  statute 
affected  joint  and  several  hability  by  specifically  providing  in  Section 
604.02(1)  that  joint  and  several  liability  was  retained,  with  certain  Hmits 
added  in  1988.^^°  The  caselaw  interpreting  this  section  of  the  statute  has 


fault  and  indemnified  him  against  contribution  claims  by  the  nonsettling  defendant.  This 
means  that  plaintiff  could  get  no  more  than  the  settlement  amount  from  the  settling  party 
and  if  the  settlement  amount  were  much  less  than  the  settling  party's  percentage  of  liability, 
she  could  apply  joint  liability  to  collect  the  rest  from  the  nonsettling  defendant,  but  if 
the  nonsettling  defendant  pressed  a  contribution  action  against  the  settling  party,  plaintiff 
would  have  to  pay  that  proportional  contribution  under  the  agreement.  See  infra  notes 
225-35  and  text  accompanying  for  further  explanation  of  this  particular  type  of  release, 
widely  used  in  Minnesota. 

219.  Id.  2X  16.  The  nonsettling  defendant  would  be  liable  only  for  her  percentage 
of  fault  despite  joint  and  several  liability  because  a  Pierringer  release  was  used.  This 
released  the  settling  party's  percentage  of  fault  and  indemnified  the  settling  party  for  any 
contribution  claims.  This  means  that  even  if  plaintiff  pressed  for  the  payment  of  any 
shortfall  between  the  settlement  amount  and  the  settUng  party's  percentage  of  fault  under 
joint  and  several  liability,  the  nonsettling  defendant  could  still  sue  the  settling  party  for 
contribution  of  the  amount  paid  over  her  proportional  liability,  and  plaintiff  would  be 
required  to  pay  that  contribution  amount.  The  effect  of  this  rather  convoluted  path  is 
that  the  nonsettling  defendant  ends  up  paying  no  more  than  her  proportional  liability 
dictates. 

220.  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.02  (West  1988  and  Supp.  1989): 

When  two  or  more  persons  are  jointly  liable,  contributions  to  awards  shall  be 
in  proportion  to  the  percentage  of  fault  attributable  to  each,  except  that  each 
is  jointly  and  severally  liable  for  the  whole  award.  Except  in  cases  where  liabihty 
arises  under  [naming  certain  environmental  and  pollution  statutes]   .  .  .  envi- 
ronmental or  public  health  law,  ...  a  person  whose  fault  is  15  percent  or  less 
is  liable  for  a  percentage  of  the  whole  award  no  greater  than  four  times  the 
percentage  of  fault. 
Minn.   Stat.  Ann.   §  604.02(1)  (West  Supp.    1989).  This  Note  will  not  deal  with  the 
limitation  "a  person  whose  fault  is  15  percent  or  less"  because  it  has  been  added  very 
recently  and  impinges  on  settlement  issues  only  in  a  peripheral  way. 

Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.02(2)  also  provides  a  procedure  whereby  uncollectible  portions 
of  a  judgment  are  reallocated  among  all  faulty  parties,  including  plaintiff,  in  proportion 
to  their  fault.  See  Hosley  v.  Pittsburg  Corning  Corp.,  401  N.W.2d  136  (Minn.  App.  1987) 
for  a  discussion  of  the  reallocation  statute.  Subdivision  (3)  of  the  same  Section  provides 
for  reallocation  in  products  hability  actions  and  also  that  in  a  products  action  "a  person 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  977 

balanced  the  retention  of  joint  and  several  liability  with  the  retention 
of  Minnesota's  common  law  right  to  contribution  between  joint  tort- 
feasors. ^^^ 

The  effect  of  the  retention  of  joint  and  several  liability  and  con- 
tribution has  occupied  much  of  the  caselaw  interpreting  the  settlement 
provisions  of  the  Minnesota  Act.  Part  of  this  preoccupation  stems  from 
the  problem  of  finality  of  settlements.  A  settling  party  wishes  to  be 
freed  entirely  of  any  worry  of  having  to  pay  further  and  enters  a 
settlement  agreement  to  achieve  this.  However  in  Minnesota,  a  settlement 
does  not  necessarily  offer  this  finality.  Nonsettling  defendants  subject 
to  a  joint  judgment  (that  is,  one  which  includes  the  settling  party's  fault) 
may  pursue  contribution  from  the  settling  party  if  the  nonsettling  party 
has  paid  more  than  her  percentage  share  of  the  judgment  under  joint 
and  several  liability. ^^^  This  means  that  a  settlement  and  release  under 
Minnesota's  Comparative  Fault  Act  does  not  truly  release  the  settling 
tortfeasor,  which  can  be  a  disincentive  to  settlement  since  the  settling 
tortfeasor  will  end  up  responsible  for  her  percentage  of  any  judgment 


whose  fault  is  less  than  that  of  the  claimant  is  liable  to  the  claimant  only  for  that  portion 
of  the  judgment  which  represents  the  percentage  of  fault  attributable  to  the  person  whose 
fault  is  less."  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.02(3)  (West  1988).  This  seems  to  change,  for 
products  liability  purposes,  the  provision  of  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01(1)  (West  1988) 
which  mandates  the  comparison  of  plaintiff's  fault  with  each  defendant  individually, 
barring  plaintiff  if  her  fault  is  more.  The  products  provision  makes  a  defendant  whose 
fault  is  less  than  plaintiffs  pay,  but  only  to  the  extent  of  their  proportion.  Cases  commenting 
on  the  retention  of  joint  and  several  Hability  are  Maday  v.  Yellow  Taxi  Co.,  311  N.W,2d 
849  (Minn.  1981)  (when  acts  concur  to  cause  injury  or  when  injury  is  indivisible,  joint 
liability  results);  Ruberg  v.  Skelly  Oil  Co.,  297  N.W.2d  746  (Minn.  1980)  (if  the  injury 
is  indivisible  and  the  defendant  against  whom  joint  and  several  liability  is  asserted  is 
indeed  liable  to  the  plaintiff,  that  defendant  is  liable  for  the  whole  award). 

221.  See,  e.g.  Lange  v.  Schweitzer,  295  N.W.2d  387  (Minn.  1980).  The  court  specified 
that  the  contribution  was  to  be  only  for  those  amounts  the  nonsettling  defendant  paid 
that  exceeded  his  proportional  liability.  This  was  regardless  of  the  dimunition  of  plaintiff's 
award  due  to  the  execution  of  a  settlement  agreement  in  which  plaintiff  agreed  to  indemnify 
the  settling  defendant  for  all  contribution  claims,  as  that  dimunition  was  forseeable  at 
the  time  of  execution  of  the  agreement.  Id.  at  390.  The  Uniform  Act  also  retains  both 
joint  and  several  liability  and  contribution: 

The  common  law  rule  of  joint  and  several  liability  continues  to  apply  under 
this  Act.  .  .  .  The  plaintiff  can  recover  the  total  amount  of  his  judgment  against 
any  defendant  who  is  liable.  The  judgment  for  each  claimant  also  sets  forth, 
however,  the  equitable  share  of  the  total  obligation  to  the  claimant  for  each 
party,  based  on  his  established  percentage  of  fault.  This  indicates  the  amount 
that  each  party  should  eventually  be  responsible  for  as  a  result  of  the  rules  of 
contribution.  Stated  in  the  judgment  itself,  it  makes  the  information  available 
to  the  parties  and  will  normally  be  a  basis  for  contribution  without  the  need 
for  a  court  order  arising  from  motion  or  separate  action. 
Unif.  Comparative  Fault  Act,  Comment  to  §  2,  12  U.L.A.  37,  44  (Supp.  1988). 

222.  See,  e.g.  Lange,  295  N.W.2d  387. 


978  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

and  will  not  get  the  benefit  of  any  bargain  she  may  strike. ^^^  The  plaintiffs 
and  defendants  of  Minnesota  have  reached  a  middle  ground  regarding 
joint  and  several  liability,  contribution,  and  finality  of  settlement  through 
the  use  of  a  ''Pierringer  release. "^^^  This  is  a  settlement  device  whereby 
plaintiff  releases  the  settling  joint  tortfeasor's  proportion  of  fault  and 
agrees  to  indemnify  her  for  any  contribution,  plaintiff  retaining  her  right 
to  pursue  the  remainder  of  her  recovery  from  the  other  tortfeasors 
involved. ^^^  The  setthng  party  is  included  in  the  allocation  of  fault,  but 
is  not  required  to  remain  a  party  to  the  action. ^^^ 

The  Minnesota  Supreme  Court  pronounced  Pierringer  releases  ac- 
ceptable in  Minnesota  and  laid  down  guideUnes  for  their  use  in  Frey 
V.  SnelgroveP''  Frey  involved  a  car  accident  in  which  plaintiff,  a  pas- 
senger, was  injured  due  to  the  alleged  neghgence  of  the  driver  and  the 
manufacturer  of  the  tires  on  the  car.^^^  On  the  sixth  day  of  trial,  the 
plaintiff  settled  and  executed  a  Pierringer  release  with  the  driver  and 
the  owner  of  the  car,  informed  the  court  of  the  settlement,  and  continued 
against  the  manufacturer. ^^^  The  settling  co-defendants  were  not  dismissed 
and  the  jury  was  not  informed  of  the  settlement. ^^^  The  tire  manufacturer 
appealed  the  trial  court's  ruling  permitting  the  settled  co-defendants  to 
continue  as  parties. ^^^ 


223.  This  is  in  contrast  to  the  Uniform  Act,  which  provides: 

A  release,  covenant  not  to  sue,  or  similar  agreement  entered  into  by  a  claimant 

and  a  person  liable  discharges  that  person  from  all  liability  for  contribution, 

but  it  does  not  discharge  any  other  persons  liable  on  the  same  claim  unless  it 

so  provides.  However,  the  claim  of  the  releasing  person  against  other  persons 

is  reduced  by  the  amount  of  the  released  person's  equitable  share  of  the  obligation. 

Unif,  Comparative  Fault  Act  §  6  12  U.L.A.  37,  50  (Supp.   1988).  The  Comment  to 

§  6  of  the  Uniform  Act  explains  why  this  configuration  was  chosen:  if  a  release  does  not 

free  the  released  person  from  Uability  for  contribution,  then  there  exists  no  incentive  for 

tortfeasors  to  settle,  as  they  will  end  up  paying  their  percentage  of  fault  anyway.  This 

is  the  problem  that  Minnesota  defendants,  plaintiffs,  and  courts  faced  under  their  statute 

and  the  existing  caselaw.  Unif.  Comparative  Fault  Act  Comment  to  §  6,   12  U.L.A. 

37,  50  (Supp.  1988). 

224.  Based  on  Pierringer  v.  Hoger,  21  Wis.  2d  182,  124  N.W.2d  106  (1963).  See 
V.  Schwartz,  Comparative  Negligence  §  16.5  (2d  ed.  1986);  C.  Heft  &  C.J.  Heft, 
Comparative  Negligence  Manual  §  4.140  (1987). 

225.  Pierringer,  21  Wis.  2d  at ,  124  N.W.2d  at  108.  The  Wisconsin  Supreme 

Court  upheld  and  enforced  the  agreement. 

226.  Id.  at  ,  124  N.W.2d  at  111-12. 

227.  269  N.W.2d  918  (Minn.  1978).  "The  use  of  a  so-called  Pierringer  release  is 
in  accord  with  Minnesota  practice  and  our  law  of  comparative  negligence  in  tort  actions." 
Id.  at  921. 

228.  Id.  at  920. 

229.  Id. 

230.  Id.  at  920-21. 

231.  Id.  at  920. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  979 

.The  court  listed  the  elements  of  a  Pierringer  release: 

(1)  The  release  of  the  settling  defendants  from  the  action  and 
the  discharge  of  a  part  of  the  cause  of  action  equal  to  the  part 
attributable  to  the  settling  defendant's  causal  negligence;  (2)  the 
reservation  of  the  remainder  of  plaintiff's  causes  of  action  against 
the  nonsettUng  defendants;  and  (3)  plaintiff's  agreement  to  in- 
demnify the  settling  defendants  from  any  claims  of  contribution 
made  by  the  nonsettling  defendants  to  the  extent  the  settling 
defendants  have  been  released. ^^^ 

Mr.  John  Simonett,  in  his  article  on  Pierringer  releases  in  Minnesota,^" 
notes  that  the  Pierringer  release  is  ''designed  to  operate  in  a  jurisdiction 
which  has  comparative  negligence  to  apportion  liability  between  defen- 
dants, uses  the  special  verdict  form.^^"*  and  allows  contribution  between 
joint  tortfeasors, "^^^  making  it  the  ideal  form  of  settlement  for  Minnesota. 
The  Frey  court  held  that  defendants  settling  under  a  Pierringer  release 
should  usually  be  dismissed  from  the  action,  "but  their  negligence  should 
nevertheless  be  submitted  to  the  jury."^^^  Nonparties  and  phantom  parties 


232.  Id.,  n.l.  The  court  notes  that  the  release  in  Frey  contained  two  unusual 
provisions:  "The  indemnity  clause  covered  cross-claims  for  indemnity  as  well  as  contribution 
and  the  amount  paid  for  the  settlement  was  contingent  upon  the  amount  recovered  from 
the  nonagreeing  party  at  trial  rather  than  a  sum  certain,"  Id. 

233.  Simonett,  Release  of  Joint  Tortfeasors:  Use  of  the  Pierringer  Release  in  Min- 
nesota, 3  Wm.  Mitchell  L.  Rev.  1  (1977). 

234.  That  is,  each  defendant  is  assigned  a  specific  percentage  of  fault,  rather  than 
having  an  overall  percentage  assigned  to  all  the  defendants  together.  Special  verdict  forms 
are  necessary  to  the  comparison  contemplated  in  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  604.01(1)  (West 
1988).  Ind.  Code  §  34-4-33-6  (1988)  provides  for  special  verdict  forms. 

235.  Simonett,  supra  note  233,  at  11. 

236.  Frey,  269  N.W.2d  at  922.  The  Uniform  Act  would  have  the  percentage  of 
fault  of  released  parties  considered: 

In  all  actions  involving  fault  of  more  than  one  party  to  the  action,  including 
third-party  defendants  and  persons  who  have  been  released  .  .  .  the  court  .  .  . 
shall  instruct  the  jury  to  answer  special  interrogatories  .  .  .  indicating: 

(1)  the  amount  of  damages  each  claimant  would  be  entitled  to  recover  if 
contributory  fault  is  disregarded;  and 

(2)  the  percentage  of  the  total  fault  of  all  the  parties  to  each  claim  that  is 
allocated  to  each  claimant,  defendant,  third-party  defendant,  and  person  who 
has  been  released  from  liability  under  Section  6. 

(emphasis  added)  Unif.  Comparative  Fault  Act  §  2,  12  U.L.A.  43,  (Supp.  1988).  The 
Comment  to  §  2  goes  on  to  explain  why  causally  negligent  but  unjoined  tortfeasors  are 
not  considered: 

The  limitation  to  parties  to  the  action  means  ignoring  other  persons  who  may 
have  been  at  fault  with  regard  to  the  particular  injury  but  who  have  not  been 
joined  as  parties.  This  is  a  deliberate  decision.  It  cannot  be  told  with  certainty 
whether  that  person  was  actually  at  fault  or  what  amount  of  fault  should  be 


980  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

are  not  dealt  with  in  the  Minnesota  Act,  but  Frey^^''  and  Lines  v.  RyarP-^^ 
make  it  clear  that  the  settling  party's  fault  is  to  be  considered  in  the 
allocation  process.  The  Minnesota  District  Judges  Association,  citing 
Lines y  supplies  a  jury  instruction  directing  the  jury  to  consider  the  fault 
of  all  causally  involved  persons,  whether  parties  or  not.^^^  This  puts 
Minnesota  in  Hne  with  Kansas  on  the  nonparty  issue,  with  the  crucial 
difference  being  that  the  plaintiff  has  the  incentive  to  join  all  tortfeasors 
because  under  joint  and  several  liability  she  will  not  be  penalized  for 
doing  so  by  having  fault  allocated  to  one  who  cannot  pay,  which  fault 
is  absorbed  by  plaintiffs  under  the  Kansas  regime.  This  is,  however, 
hard  on  defendants  because  they  absorb  the  fault  of  such  persons  under 
joint  and  several  Hability  and  must  seek  contribution,  which  is  costly 
and  time  consuming.  For  this  reason,  defendants  are  encouraged  to  settle 
by  means  of  a  Pierringer  release,  thereby  freeing  themselves  of  this 
possibility. 


attributed  to  him,  or  whether  he  will  ever  be  sued,  or  whether  the  statute  of 
limitations  will  run  on  him,  etc.  An  attempt  to  settle  these  matters  in  a  suit  to 
which  he  is  not  a  party  would  not  be  binding  on  him. 
Id.,  Comment  to  §  2.  This  Comment  acknowledges  the  practical  problems  of  a  the  inclusion 
of  nonparties  in  the  allocation  process,  but  the  Kansas  courts  would  rightly  note  that  this 
allows  plaintiffs  to  circumvent  the  allocation  procedure  by  strategic  choice  of  which 
tortfeasors  to  sue  and  which  to  let  go. 

237.  Frey,  269  N.W.2d  at  922-23. 

238.  272  N.W.2d  896  (Minn.  1978). 

It  is  established  without  doubt  that,  when  apportioning  negligence,  a  jury  must 

have  the  opportunity  to  consider  the  negligence  of  all  parties  to  the  transaction, 

whether  or  not  they  be  parties  to  the  lawsuit  and  whether  or  not  they  can  be 

liable  to  the  plaintiff  or  to  the  other  tort-feasors  either  by  operation  of  law  or 

because  of  a  prior  release. 

Connar  v.  West  Shore  Equip.,  68  Wis.  2d  42,  45,  227  N.W.2d  660,  662  (1975).  See  also 

Hosley  v.  Armstrong  Cork  Co.,  383  N.W.2d  289  (Minn.  1986),  where  the  fault  of  fourteen 

asbestos  manufacturers  was  allocated  even  though  twelve  had  settled  prior  to  trial. 

239.  JIG  149  instructs: 

During  the  trial  evidence  has  been  presented  concerning  the  involvement  in  the 

(accident)  (injury)  (collision)  (occurrence)  of  persons  who  are  not  parties,  that 

is,  not  plaintiffs  or  defendants,  to  this  lawsuit.  Even  though  [name  of  person] 

is  not  a  party,  you  will  still  be  asked  to  determine  whether  [name  of  person] 

was  (negligent)  (at  fault)  and  whether  [name  of  person]  (negligence)  (fault)  was 

a  direct  cause  of  the  (accident)  (injury)  (collision)  (occurrence).  That  is  to  ensure 

that  the  apportionment  of  (negligence)  (fault)  you  make  in  answering  question 

[number]  is  fair  and  accurate. 

4  Minn.  Prac.  Jury  Instruction  Guides  Civil  127,  JIG  149  (1986).  The  Comment  to  the 

instruction  advises  that  "[i]f  the  fault  of  an  absent  person  is  considered,  it  may  be  desirable 

to  explain  to  the  jury  why  the  fault  of  an  absent  person  is  being  considered."  Id. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  981 

C.     Practical  Matters:  Informing  the  Jury  and  the 
Problem  of  Secret  Settlements 

The  Frey  court  also  addressed  the  practical  point  of  what  the  jury 
is  to  be  told  when  a  party  has  settled  but  her  fault  must  still  be  allocated. ^^^^ 
In  this  situation  the  settled  party,  if  she  has  executed  a  Pierringer  release, 
has  no  incentive  to  further  defend  herself  because  she  will  not  have  to 
pay  any  more,  due  to  the  plaintiff's  indemnification  in  case  of  contri- 
bution claims.  However,  a  settlement  may  give  the  impression  of  admitted 
liability  to  the  jury,  causing  them  to  put  undue  amounts  of  fault  on 
the  settling  defendant,  which  would  be  absorbed  by  plaintiff  under  a 
Pierringer  release.  If  the  settling  party  is  dismissed,  as  is  recommended 
in  Frey,^"^^  the  jury  may  be  puzzled  by  her  absence  and  possibly  attribute 
undue  fault  to  the  remaining  parties. 

The  Frey  court  suggests  guidelines  which  include  a  notification  of 

the  court  and  the  other  parties  and  making  the  settlement  agreement 

part  of  the  record. ^"^^  ''Where  the  settlement  and  release  agreement  is 

executed  during  trial,  the  court  should  usually  inform  the  jury  that  'there 

has  been  a  settlement  and  release  if  for  no  other  reason  than  to  explain 

the  settling  tortfeasor's  conspicuous  absence  from  the  courtroom.'  "^'^^ 

The  court  notes  that  a  settlement  agreement  would  be  admissible  to 

prove  bias  or  prejudice  of  a  witness,  and  leaves  the  admissibility  of  the 

actual  agreement  to  the  trial  court's  discretion.^^  The  court  last  specifies 

that  "as  a  general  rule  the  amount  paid  in  settlement  should  never  be 
submitted.  "2^5 

/.  *'Mary  Carter'*  Agreements, — The  question  of  who  should  be 
informed  of  a  settlement  is  most  fiercely  argued  in  relation  to  secret 
settlements,  also  referred  to  as  ''Mary  Carter  agreements "^"^^  or  ''Gal- 
lagher agreements. "^'^'^  These  agreements  typically  have  the  following 
features:  the  guarantee  of  a  certain  amount  of  recovery  for  plaintiff  if 
she  does  not  prevail  or  recovers  less  than  expected  from  the  remaining 


240.  Frey,  269  N.W.2d  at  923-24. 

241.  Id.  at  923. 

242.  Id. 

243.  Id.  (quoting  Simonett,  supra  note  233,  at  30).  See  generally  Note,  Knowledge 
by  the  Jury  of  a  Settlement  Where  a  Plaintiff  Has  Settled  With  One  or  More  Defendants 
Who  Are  Jointly  and  Severally  Liable,  32  Vill.  L.  Rev.  541  (1987). 

244.  Frey,  269  N.W.2cl  at  923. 

245.  Id.  This  is  because  the  settlement  amount  is  arrived  at  through  the  use  of 
factors  not  appropriately  put  before  the  jury,  such  as  estimations  of  liability  and  com- 
promise. Also,  the  settlement  figure  may  have  little  relation  to  the  plaintiff's  actual  damages. 
Id. 

246.  Named  after  Booth  v.  Mary  Carter  Paint  Co.  202  So.  2d  8  (Fla.  Dist.  Ct. 
App.  1967).  See  generally  H.  Woods,  Comparative  Fault  §  13:21  (1987). 

247.  Named  for  City  of  Tucson  v.  Gallagher,  108  Ariz.  140,  493  P.2d  1197  (1972). 


982  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

defendants;  a  limit  on  the  settling  defendant's  liability  to  that  amount;  a 
requirement  that  the  settling  defendant  stay  in  the  case  as  a  defendant; 
and  finally,  they  are  secret  from  the  court,  the  opposing  parties,  and 
the  jury.^*^  This  is  obviously  unfair  to  defendants  who  remain  in  the 
action  unaware  that  such  an  agreement  has  been  made.  It  also  does 
nothing  to  encourage  true  settlement  because  if  plaintiff  is  aware  that 
one  or  more  defendants  will,  sub  rosa,  be  ''on  her  side,"  giving  her 
the  advantage  over  the  remaining  defendant(s),  she  need  not  be  vitally 
interested  in  compromising  with  those  remaining  defendants. 

Ethical  considerations  aside,  these  features  make  such  agreements 
very  appealing  in  jurisdictions  which  have  aboUshed  joint  and  several 
liabihty  and  contribution. ^"^^  This  is  because  plaintiff  has  a  guaranteed 
minimum  recovery  and  assistance  from  the  settling  defendant  in  putting 
maximum  blame  on  the  nonsettling  defendants,  with  the  result  that 
plaintiff's  and  settling  defendant's  fault  is  small  and  nonsettling  defen- 
dant's proportional  fault  is  large.  This  lessens  the  need  on  plaintiff's 
part  for  joint  and  several  liability  to  attain  full  recovery,  and  the  settling 
defendant  need  not  worry  about  contribution. ^^^ 

The  courts  which  have  dealt  with  such  agreements  have  objected 
not  to  the  agreements  themselves  but  to  the  secrecy  which  is  one  of 
their  main  elements. ^^^  The  agreement  itself,  without  the  secrecy  and 
cooperation  between  the  plaintiff  and  the  settling  defendant,  somewhat 
resembles  a  Pierringer  release.  In  Johnson  v.  Moberg,^^^  the  Minnesota 
Supreme  Court  dealt  with  a  secret  settlement  made  minutes  before  final 


248.  Mullins  and  Morrison,  Who  is  Mary  Carter  and  Why  is  She  Saying  All  Those 
Nasty  Things  About  My  Pre-trial  Settlements?,  23  For  the  Defense  14,  15  (1981).  The 
Mary  Carter  agreement  was  described  as  "basically  a  contract  by  which  one  co-defendant 
secretly  agrees  with  the  plaintiff  that,  if  such  defendant  will  proceed  to  defend  himself 
in  court,  his  own  maximum  liability  will  be  diminished  proportionately  by  increasing  the 
liabihty  of  the  other  co-defendants."  Ward  v.  Ochoa,  284  So.  2d  385,  387  (Fla.  1973). 

249.  Entman,  Mary  Carter  Agreements:  An  Assessment  of  Attempted  Solutions,  38 
Univ.  Fla.  L.  Rev.  521,  557  (1986).  The  author  notes  that  the  commentary  on  these 
agreements  arises  mostly  from  non-contribution  jurisdictions,  but  that  they  are  unfair  in 
all  jurisdictions.  Id.  at  524.  See  also  Eubanks  and  Cocchiarella,  In  Defense  of  Mary 
Carter,  26  For  the  Defense  14  (February  1984),  stating  that  when  the  nonsetthng  defendant 
is  not  making  a  realistic  attempt,  commensurate  with  her  share  of  fault,  to  settle  plaintiff's 
case,  a  Mary  Carter  agreement  is  fair  to  the  parties  and  may  encourage  settlement.  The 
authors  recommend  disclosure  to  minimize  any  adverse  effects.  Id.  at  21. 

250.  Eubanks  and  Cocchiarella,  supra  n.249,  at  19. 

251.  See,  e.g.  Johnson  v.  Moberg,  334  N.W.2d  411,  415  (Minn.  1983),  citing  cases 
which  have  required  disclosure  of  Mary  Carter  agreements.  However,  one  court  has  held 
that  such  agreements  are  void  as  a  matter  of  public  policy,  finding  that  they  are  unethical 
and  encourage  champerty  and  maintenance,  as  well  as  make  it  impossible  for  the  nonsettling 
defendant  to  get  a  fair  trial.  Lum  v.  Stinnett,  87  Nev.  402,  488  P.2d  347  (1971). 

252.  334  N.W.2d  411  (Minn.  1983). 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  983 

arguments  in  a  ** dram-shop"  case,  where  the  settling  defendant  continued 
and  made  a  closing  argument.^" 

The  court  held  that  Mary  Carter  agreements  must  be  disclosed  to 
the  court  and  the  other  litigants  immediately  when  made,  stating:  "This 
kind  of  settlement  can  affect  the  motivation  of  the  parties,  and,  indeed, 
the  credibility  of  witnesses,  and  only  by  bringing  these  settlements  into 
the  open  can  a  trial  proceed  in  a  fair  and  proper  adversarial  setting. ''^^'^ 
The  court  recommended  that  on  remand  the  guidelines  laid  down  in 
Frey  regarding  revelation  of  settlement  agreements  be  followed. ^^^ 

Disclosure  of  settlements  does  not  afford  a  final  solution  to  the 
problem  of  Mary  Carter  settlements,  because  revealing  a  self-serving 
agreement  containing  protestations  of  innocence  and  condemnation  of 
the  nonsettling  defendant  can  be  just  as  damaging  to  the  nonsettling 
defendant  as  secret  cooperation  between  the  plaintiff  and  the  settling 
defendant  to  achieve  the  same  end.^^^  Prejudice  results  also  if  the  dis- 
closure leads  the  jury  to  think  that  the  nonsettling  defendant  did  not 
settle  because  she  was  more  at  fault  or  that  plaintiff  has  received  a 
recovery  through  settlement  and  does  not  deserve  any  more.^^^  Further, 
if  the  agreement  is  entirely  secret,  nonsettling  defendants  will  not  even 
know  to  ask  for  revelation  of  the  agreement. ^^^ 

It  is  probable  that  Indiana  courts  will  face  this  problem  as  com- 
parative fault  is  refined  with  the  passage  of  time.  This  is  because  if  a 
plaintiff  is  faced  with  the  prospect  of  no  joint  and  several  liability  and 
the  knowledge  that  the  fault  of  a  settUng  party  will  be  considered  and 
allocated,  then  she  will  join  as  many  defendants  as  possible  and  enlist 
as  many  as  possible  to  her  cause.  This  may  be  done  through  the  use 
of  agreements  which  require  defendants  to  stay  in  the  case  post-settlement 
and  defend  themselves  rather  than  leave  plaintiff  to  defend  an  absent 
nonparty  tortfeasor. ^^^ 

253.  Id.  at  414. 

254.  Id.  at  415. 

255.  Id.  See  supra  notes  240-45  and  accompanying  text  for  the  Frey  guidelines. 

256.  Entman,  supra  note  249,  at  559. 

257.  Note,  Appellate  Decisions  -  Evidence  -  Disclosing  Gallagher  Agreements  to  The 
Jury,  22  Ariz.  L.  Rev.  1135,  1141  (1980) 

258.  Entman,  supra  note  249,  at  561-62.  Mullins  and  Morrison,  supra  note  248,  at 
18,  refer  to  Mary  Carter  agreements  as  "Typhoid  Mary"  and  recommend  using  discovery 
requests  to  discover  agreements  when  they  seem  Ukely. 

259.  Professor  Wilkins,  in  his  article  describes  the  "empty  chair"  defense  as  a 
weapon  in  the  plaintiff's  arsenal,  which  it  was  when  plaintiff  had  control  over  whose 
fault  was  to  be  considered.  This  was  because  the  trier  of  fact  had  no  choice  but  allocate 
one  hundred  percent  of  the  involved  fault,  and  if  the  "empty  chair"  tortfeasor  was  not 
in  court,  the  only  place  to  put  that  fault  was  on  the  defendants  in  court.  Under  a 
comparative  fault  regime  where  the  fault  of  all  parties  is  considered,  the  "empty  chair" 
becomes  a  tool  of  use  to  the  defense,  in  that  fault  may  be  allocated  to  the  "empty  chair" 
tortfeasor.  Wilkins,  supra  note  47,  at  732-33. 


984  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

Although  ethical  considerations  will  hopefully  prevent  most  attorneys 
from  entering  secret  agr cements, ^^°  Indiana  courts  and  legislators  will 
have  to  consider  the  temptations  that  will  arise  under  the  comparative 
fault  system.  This  consideration  will  lead  to  putting  in  place  a  requirement 
that  settlement  agreements  be  timely  revealed  to  the  court  and  the  other 
litigants,  as  has  been  done  in  other  jurisdictions. ^^^  Such  a  requirement 
would  serve  to  keep  honest  lawyers  honest. 

To  counterbalance  the  possible  bad  effects  of  revealing  and  admitting 
an  agreement  condemning  a  nonsettling  defendant,  the  trial  court  should 
be  given  the  discretion  to  decide  which  parts  can  be  revealed  without 
prejudice  to  any  party.  This  is  recommended  in  Frey}^^  Minnesota  courts 
also  have  Jury  Instruction  Guides  tailored  to  the  settlement  situation 
described  above,  telling  the  jury  that  a  defendant  has  settled  and  that 
the  jury  is  not  to  concern  itself  with  why  the  settlement  occurred,  warning 
them  not  to  draw  conclusions  from  the  settlement,  and  telUng  them  that 
they  will  be  required  to  allocate  the  settling  party's  fault. ^^^ 

2.  Reasonableness  Hearings. — The  Washington  comparative  fault 
statute  includes  a  provision  requiring  that  the  court  and  other  parties 
to  the  action  be  informed  of  any  contemplated  settlement  agreement 
and  that  the  agreement  be  subject  to  approval  by  the  court. ^^  This 


260.  Eubanks  and  Cocchiarella,  supra  note  249,  at  22,  stress  that  such  agreements 
are  doubtful  ethically. 

261.  See,  e.g.  Johnson  v.  Moberg,  334  N.W.2d  411  (Minn.  1983),  and  cases  cited 
Id.  at  415.  Frey  v.  Snelgrove,  269  N.W.2d  918,  923-24  makes  it  clear  that  the  court  is 
to  be  informed  of  Pierringer  releases. 

262.  Frey,  269  N.W.2d  at  923-24. 

263.  Jury  Instruction  Guide  148: 

[Defendant]  is  no  longer  a  party  to  this  lawsuit,  because  [defendant]  and  [plaintiff] 
have  entered  into  a  settlement  agreement.  You  are  not  to  concern  yourselves 
with  the  reasons  for  the  settlement  agreement.  You  are  not  to  draw  any  con- 
clusions from  the  fact  of  settlement  or  from  the  fact  that  other  defendants 
remain  in  the  lawsuit.  The  settlement  agreement  between  [plaintiff]  and  [defen- 
dant] should  in  no  way  influence  your  judgment  about  the  (negligence)(fault) 
of  [defendant],  the  remaining  defendant(s)  or  the  plaintiff(s).  Even  though 
[defendant]  is  no  longer  a  party  to  this  lawsuit,  you  will  still  be  asked  to 
determine  whether  [defendant]  is  (negligent)  (at  fault)  and  whether  that  (neg- 
ligence) (fault)  was  a  direct  cause  of  the(accident)  (injury)  (collision)  (occurrence). 
This  is  to  ensure  that  the  apportionment  of  (negligence)  (fault)  you  make  in 
answering  question  [number]  is  fair  and  accurate. 
4  Minn.  Prac.  Jury  Instruction  Guides  Civil  125,  JIG  148,  (1986). 

264.  Wash.  Rev.  Code.  §  4.22.060(1)  (1987).  The  section  provides: 

(1)  A  party  prior  to  entering  into  a  release,  covenant  not  to  sue,  covenant  not 
to  enforce  judgment,  or  similar  agreement  with  a  claimant  shall  give  five  days' 
written  notice  of  such  intent  to  all  other  parties  and  the  court.  The  court  may 
for  good  cause  authorize  a  shorter  notice  period.  The  notice  shall  contain  a 
copy  of  the  proposed  agreement.  A  hearing  shall  be  held  on  the  issue  of  the 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  985 

section  provides  for  a  hearing  on  the  proposed  settlement,  including 
evidentiary  presentations,  and  also  that  settlements  entered  into  before 
the  action  was  filed  may  be  subject  to  hearing  upon  motion  by  a  party. ^^^ 
This  portion  of  the  Washington  statute  serves  several  purposes.  First, 
it  guarantees  that  any  settlement  is  brought  to  the  attention  of  the  court, 
thereby  avoiding  the  collusion  and  prejudice  of  a  Mary  Carter  agreement. 
Second,  it  assures  both  parties  of  a  fair  settlement,  as  judged  by  the 
court.  Third,  it  assists  the  parties  in  realistically  assessing  the  amount 
of  fault  for  which  each  is  responsible. ^^^ 

The  reasonableness  hearing  requirement  was  examined  in  Glover  v. 
Tacoma  General  Hosp.,^^^  where  the  court  was  attempting  to  determine 
how  much  credit  a  remaining  defendant  should  receive  for  settlements 
with  other  defendants. ^^*  The  court  noted  that  the  legislature  had  not 
set  out  factors  or  guidelines  for  courts  to  use  in  determining  reasona- 
bleness.^^^ The  factors  which  the  court  decided  upon  included  a  balance 
of  plaintiff's  damages,  the  merits  of  the  party's  cases,  ability  to  pay, 


reasonableness  of  the  amount  to  be  paid  with  all  parties  afforded  an  opportunity 
to  present  evidence.  A  determination  by  the  court  that  the  amount  to  be  paid 
is  reasonable  must  be  secured.  If  an  agreement  was  entered  into  prior  to  the 
filing  of  the  action,  a  hearing  on  the  issue  of  the  reasonableness  of  the  amount 
paid  at  the  time  it  was  entered  into  may  be  held  at  any  time  prior  to  final 
judgment  upon  motion  of  a  party.  The  burden  of  proof  as  to  the  reasonableness 
of  the  settlement  offer  shall  be  on  the  party  requesting  the  settlement. 

Id.  Washington  has  adopted  the  Uniform  Act,  Unif.  Comparative  Fault  Act,  12  U.L.A. 

37  (Supp.  1988),  but  the  reasonableness  requirement  for  settlements  is  a  variation  on  the 

Uniform  Act's  §  6,  Cahfornia  has  a  similar  "good  faith"  requirement  for  settlements. 

See  River  Garden  Farms,  Inc.  v.  Superior  Court,  26  Cal.  App.  3d  986,  103  Cal.  Rptr. 

498  (1972). 

265.  Wash.  Rev.  Code  §  4.22.060(1)  (1987). 

266.  Accurately  assessing  the  percentages  of  fault  attributable  to  the  various  parties 
will  always  be  a  major  practical  headache.  See  Handbook  for  Indianapolis  Bar  Ass'n, 
Super  Saturday  in  Court  -  -  Comparative  Fault,  6  (April  9,  1988);  Heft  &  Heft, 
CoMPARATFVE  NEGLIGENCE  MANUAL  §§  4.40  -  4.110  (1987),  Suggesting  various  percentages 
of  fault  to  be  used  in  settlement  negotiations,  according  to  the  type  of  accident  involved. 

267.  98  Wash.  2d  708,  658  P.2d  1230  (1983). 

268.  Id.  at  713,  658  P.2d  at  1235. 

269.  Id.  at  714,  658  P. 2d  at  1236.  The  court  quoted  the  Senate  Select  Committee 
on  Tort  and  Product  Liabihty  Reform  Final  Report  at  54:  "The  bill  does  not  establish 
any  standards  for  determining  whether  the  amount  paid  for  the  release  was  reasonable 
or  not.  It  is  felt  that  the  courts  can  rule  on  this  issue  without  specific  guidance  from 
the  Senate."  Stating  that  "sweetheart  deals"  (Mary  Carter  agreements)  were  one  of  the 
concerns  of  the  legislature  in  enacting  the  provision,  the  court  refused  to  allow  total 
discretion  in  the  lower  court.  Id.  at  713,  658  P. 2d  at  1235.  The  court  also  refused  a  test 
which  strictly  reflected  the  remaining  defendant's  relative  liabihty,  on  the  basis  that 
determining  the  liability  would  entail  a  mini-trial  or  waiting  until  the  jury  had  allocated 
all  the  fault.  Id. 


986  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:939 

collusion  or  fraud,  good  faith,  the  cost  and  timeframe  of  the  litigation, 
and  the  interests  of  the  parties  not  being  released. ^^^ 

This  system  would  not  be  as  efficient  as  allowing  the  parties  to 
work  out  their  settlements  under  comparative  fault  without  the  inter- 
ference of  the  court,  but  would  encourage  fair  settlement.  It  would  also 
serve  the  purpose  of  discouraging  unfair  Mary  Carter  agreements  and 
assist  the  parties  in  their  negotiations. 

The  Minnesota  system  embodies  a  concern  for  the  compensation 
aspects  of  the  tort  system  which  tend  to  favor  plaintiffs.  It  is  interesting 
to  note  that  given  a  system  with  joint  and  several  liability  which  guar- 
antees plaintiff  a  full  recovery,  and  contribution  to  assure  that  no 
defendant  pays  more  than  her  full  share,  the  bar  and  courts  of  Minnesota 
have  favored  Pierringer  settlements  which  approximate  a  completely 
allocation-oriented  system. ^^'  The  difference  lies  in  that  it  is  plaintiff's 
choice  to  bear  the  risks  associated  with  Pierringer  releases,  and  if  she 
chooses  not  to,  she  can  pursue  a  judgment  and  have  any  of  the  jointly 
and  severally  liable  defendants  pay.  In  such  a  case,  it  is  the  defendant 
who  bears  the  risk  of  insolvency  or  immunity  of  one  of  the  other 
defendants.  In  Kansas  this  is  impossible,  and  the  plaintiff  bears  all  the 
risks,  both  of  an  unwise  settlement  and  of  the  immunity  or  insolvency 
of  a  defendant. 

Clearly  the  Minnesota  legislature  and  courts  considered  carefully 
both  policy  and  practicality  in  enacting  the  Minnesota  statute.  The  statute 
created  is  detailed  enough  that  courts  could  interpret  it  in  a  logical  and 
consistent  fashion,  giving  litigants  some  certainty,  yet  flexible  enough 
that  parties  are  given  the  most  room  possible  to  negotiate  and  arrive 
at  creative,  final,  and  fair  settlements. 

V.     Summary  and  Conclusion 

The  systems  of  both  Kansas  and  Minnesota  have  features  which 
recommend  them  in  the  settlement  context,  Kansas'  being  the  precise 
allocation  of  fault  to  parties,  which  makes  it  fairest  for  those  accused 
of  negligence,  Minnesota's  being  the  joint  and  several  liability  doctrine 


270.  Id. 

271.  The  effect  of  a  Pierringer  release  is  that  plaintiff  receives  the  settlement  amount 
and  any  remaining  judgment  amount  less  the  settling  defendant's  proportion  of  fault.  The 
settling  defendant  is  freed  of  any  threat  of  a  contribution  suit  by  an  agreement  whereby 
plaintiff  will  indemnify  that  defendant  in  case  a  codefendant  presses  a  contribution  suit. 
The  nonsettling  defendant  pays  only  her  own  proportion  of  fault,  or,  if  forced  to  pay 
part  of  a  settling  defendant's  fault  can  go  against  the  settling  defendant  for  contribution. 
This  circuitous  route  leads  to  each  defendant  being  responsible  for  her  own  fault  and  no 
more,  as  under  a  system  such  as  Kansas'.  See  supra  notes  218,  219  and  225-35,  and 
accompanying  text. 


1989]  COMPARATIVE  FAULT  987 

balanced  by  contribution,  which  emphasizes  the  compensation  of  injured 
persons.  For  ease  of  administation,  the  Kansas  Act,  by  not  allowing 
contribution,  makes  for  more  efficiency.^'^^  The  Minnesota  system,  which 
requires  further  action  on  the  part  of  a  defendant  in  order  to  get 
contribution,  is  less  efficient,  but  gives  the  parties  more  flexibility  to 
craft  fair  and  effective  settlements,  and  in  combination  with  Pierringer 
releases  provides  a  strong  incentive  to  settlement. 

Which  state  Indiana  follows  will  depend  in  part  upon  how  her  courts 
answer  the  threshold  questions  of  whether  joint  and  several  liability  has 
been  retained  and  the  position  of  settling  parties  in  the  case  post- 
settlement.  The  fact  that  the  Act  has  foreclosed  contribution  and  the 
federal  court's  decision  in  Gray^^^  indicate  that  Indiana  will  probably 
follow  Kansas  in  abrogating  joint  and  several  liability.  The  position  of 
settled  tortfeasors  will  be  a  harder  question  for  Indiana  courts  and 
lawyers,  dealing  with  nonparty  provisions  which  are  more  detailed  than 
any  other  state's  and  with  no  indication  yet  as  to  whether  settled  parties 
will  be  nonparties  or  sui  generis.  The  courts  must  decide  what  role  a 
settling  defendant  or  tortfeasor  will  play  in  the  consideration  and  al- 
location of  fault. 

The  practical  aspects  of  trying  a  case  in  which  one  of  multiple 
tortfeasors  has  settled  will  center  around  the  position  the  settling  parties 
will  occupy  vis  a  vis  the  plaintiff  and  remaining  defendants.  The  courts 
must  state  whether  or  not  the  settling  tortfeasor  will  become  an  automatic 
nonparty  and  give  guidelines  for  settlement  under  the  Act  and  the 
allocation  of  fault  to  the  settling  tortfeasors,  providing  jury  instructions 
and  procedures  designed  to  protect  both  the  plaintiff  and  defendant. 

By  referring  to  the  caselaw  and  statute  interpretation  of  other  states, 
as  well  as  the  policies  represented  by  the  fault  allocation  systems  involved, 
Indiana  courts  will  be  equipped  to  provide  cogent  answers  to  the  threshold 
questions  and  provide  the  certainty  which  lawyers  and  parties  need  in 
order  to  effect  the  most  advantageous  settlements  possible. 

Elizabeth  Moran  Behnke 


272,  Except  in  a  comparative  implied  indemnity  case  such  as  Kennedy,  which  en- 
compasses a  further  action  by  settling  defendants  in  order  to  get  proportional  contribution. 

273.  684  F.  Supp.  1481  (S.D.  Ind.   1988) 


Retroactive  Application  of  Legislatively  Enlarged  Statutes 
of  Limitations  for  Child  Abuse:  Time's  No  Bar  to 

Revival 

I.     Introduction 

In  the  United  States,  child  sexual  abuse  and  neglect  have  reached 
major,  if  not  epic,  proportions.*  An  estimated  200,000  to  400,000  children 
are  sexually  abused  each  year.^  A  recent  study  suggests  that  perhaps  one 
third  of  the  female  population  experienced  some  form  of  sexual  abuse 
as  a  child. ^  Increased  societal  recognition  of  child  sexual  abuse,  attrib- 
utable in  part  to  increased  reporting  requirements,  has  reignited  an  age- 
old  debate  over  the  relative  scope  of  such  abuse  and  society's  role  in 
curbing  it."* 

The  problem  has  received  legislative  and  executive  attention.  For 
example,  numerous  state  legislatures  enacted  legislation  enlarging  the 
criminal  statute  of  limitations  for  child  sex  abuse  offenses  in  an  effort 
to  facilitate  criminal  prosecution.^  Additionally,  the  United  States  At- 
torney General's  Office  recently  advocated  the  extension  of  such  statutes 
of  limitations.^  These  actions,  although  well-intentioned,  frequently  create 
agonizing  dilemmas  for  the  judiciary  in  applying  the  revised  limitations 
period,  especially  where  the  legislature  fails  to  expressly  dictate  its  in- 
tentions as  to  the  revised  statute's  application.  Moreover,  the  legislation 
may  run  afoul  of  constitutional  ex  post  facto  prohibitions  when  applied 
in  accordance  with  legislative  dictates. 

Preliminarily,  this  Note  will  illuminate  the  magnitude  of  the  child 
sexual  abuse  problem,  and  the  impact  of  the  statute  of  limitations  on 


1.  ten  Bensel,  Child  Abuse  and  Neglect:  The  Scope  of  the  Problem,  35  Juv.  and 
Fam.  Ct.  J.  1  (Winter  1984)  [hereinafter  Child  Abuse  and  Neglect]. 

2.  Middleton,  Plight  of  the  Victim:  A  Plea  for  Action,  66  A.B.A.J.  1190,  1192 
(1980). 

3.  Landis,  Experiences  of  500  Children  with  Adult  Sexual  Deviation,  30  Psy- 
chology Q.  Supp.  91  (1956). 

4.  See  Myers,  Protecting  Children  from  Sexual  Abuse:  What  Does  the  Future 
Hold?,  15  J.  CoNTEMP.  L.  31,  32  (1989)  [hereinafter  Protecting  Children]. 

5.  See,  e.g.,  Alaska  Stat.  12.10.020(c)  (Supp.  1988);  Ariz.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann. 
13-107(B)(1)  (Supp.  1988);  Cal.  Penal  Code  801  (West  1985);  Colo.  Rev.  Stat.  18-3- 
411  (1986);  Tex.  Crim.  Proc.  Code  Ann.  12.01  (Supp.  1988). 

6.  Attorney  General's  Task  Force  on  Family  Violence,  Federal  Executive  and 
Legislative  and  State  Legislative  Action,  Recommendations,  U.S.  Atty.  Gen.,  Final  Report 
103  (Sept.  1984)  [hereinafter  Task  Force  on  Family  Violence].  The  task  force  recommended 
extending  the  statute  of  limitations  to  five  years,  such  period  commencing  at  the  time 
the  victim  attains  majority,  or  the  age  of  sixteen,  whichever  first  occurs. 

989 


990  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

the  states'  ability  to  prosecute  child  sexual  abusers.  The  Note  will  then 
analyze  the  constitutional  ramification  of  retroactive  apphcation  of  the 
revised  statute.  The  Note  will  further  address  the  various  judicial  ap- 
proaches to  the  interpretation  and  apphcation  of  a  revised  statute  of 
limitations  for  child  sexual  abuse,  especially  where  the  legislature  failed 
to  expressly  dictate  the  revised  statute's  application.  Finally,  the  Note 
will  suggest  a  uniform  approach  to  interpretation  and  application  of  the 
revised  statute,  and  propose  that  the  states'  compelling  interest  in  pros- 
ecuting child  sex  abusers  permits  the  revival  of  "time-barred"  prose- 
cutions. 

II.     Child  Sexual  Abuse  -  The  Problem's  Parameters 

A.     The  Scope  of  The  Problem 

The  painful  reality  of  child  sexual  abuse  has  emerged  from  secrecy 
at  least  three  times  previously,  only  to  retreat  under  threat  to  the  dark 
chasms  and  inner  recesses  of  society's  consciousness.^  Each  time,  however, 
society  ignored,  suppressed  and  condemned  the  enlightened  few  who 
dared  suggest  the  existence  of  widespread  child  sexual  abuse. ^  Most 
recently,  beginning  in  1978,^  child  sexual  abuse  recaptured  the  public 
spothght,  inducing  an  avalanche  of  media  and  scholarly  works. '^  Mass 
child  sexual  abuse  cases  blanket  the  evening  news:  McMartin  in  Los 
Angeles,  the  Jordan  case  in  Minnesota,  Country  Walk  in  Florida,  and 
others.^'  Increased  societal  cognizance  of  child  sexual  abuse  is  in  large 
part  attributable  to  the  implementation  of  mandatory  reporting  require- 
ments.^^ Various  statutory  reporting  schemes  require  medical  personnel, 
educators,  relatives,  social  workers  and  even  attorneys  to  report  abuse. '^ 
However,  even  the  increased  reporting  requirements  fail  to  reveal  the 
true  scope  of  the  problem.  Incest,  the  most  intimate  form  of  child  sexual 
abuse,  is  commonly  unreported. '"^  Often,  the  perpetrator,  if  not  a  family 


7.  Protecting  Children,  supra  note  4,  at  32. 

8.  Id.  at  31-36. 

9.  Id.  at  32. 

10.  Id.  Mass  child  sexual  abuse  cases  blanket  the  evening  news:  McMartin  in  Los 
Angeles,  the  Jordan  case  in  Minnesota,  Country  Walk  in  Florida,  and  others. 

11.  Id.  The  McMartin  case  is  reported  as  McMartin  v.  County  of  Los  Angeles, 
202  Cal.  App.  3d  848,  249  Cal.  Rptr.  53  (1988). 

12.  Besharov,  Child  Protection:  Past  Progress,  Present  Problems,  and  Future  Di- 
rections, 17  Fam.  L.Q.   151,  153-55  (Summer  1983). 

13.  Note,  Sexually  4bused  Children:  The  Best  Kept  Legal  Secret,  3  Hum.  Rts. 
Ann.  441,  443-44  (1986)  [hereinafter  Sexually  Abused  Children]. 

14.  Id.  at  445. 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  991 

member,  is  a  relative  or  an  adult  known  to  the  victim.'^  An  estimated 
90%  of  all  cases  involving  female  victims  under  the  age  of  12  are  not 
reported  to  the  police. ^^  Although  estimates  of  the  extent  of  child  sexual 
abuse  vary  widely,  the  problem  is  unquestionably  of  major  magnitude. 

Child  sexual  abuse  inflicts  staggering  economic,  psychological  and 
social  costs  on  society  and  its  victims.  These  costs  are  "taken  out  of 
[the  victims']  current  and  future  health,  happiness,  and  .  .  .  produc- 
tivity. ...  In  effect,  a  large  mortgage  on  their  future  life  is  taken  out 
when  children's  legal  interests  are  not  satisfied.  .  .  ."^^  The  abused  child 
often  becomes  the  abuser.'^  Other  long-term  effects  may  include  a  pro- 
pensity for  promiscuity  and  prostitution  as  well  as  a  predisposition  to 
engage  in  sexually  abusive  relationships.^^  Various  studies  indicate  other 
long-term  effects  including  anxiety,  pseudo-seductive  behavior,  substance 
abuse,  sexual  dysfunction,  homosexuality  and  various  forms  of  psychosis 
such  as  depression  and  suicidal  obsession. ^^ 

In  response  to  public  outcries  over  the  scope  and  treatment  of  the 
child  sexual  abuse  problem,  the  criminal  justice  system  initiated  numerous 


15.  Lloyd,  Corroboration  of  Sexual  Victimization  of  Children,  Child  Sexual 
Abuse  and  the  Law  122,  n.88  (A.BA.  Nat'l  Legal  Resource  Ctr.  For  Child  Advoc.  And 
Prot.  (5th  ed.  1984)). 

16.  Libai,  Protection  of  the  Child  Victim,  15  Wayne  L.  Rev.  977,  1016,  n.l34 
(1969)  [hereinafter  Protection  of  the  Child  Victim]. 

17.  Miller  &  Miller,  Protecting  the  Rights  of  Abused  and  Neglected  Children,  19 
Trlal  68,  72  (June  1983)  [hereinafter  Protecting  the  Rights]  (quoting  Bross  &  Munson, 
Alternative  Models  of  Legal  Representation  for  Children,  5  Okla.  City  U.L.  Rev.  561 
(1980)).  Child  Abuse  &  Neglect;  supra  note  1,  at  2.  The  author  notes  that  the  initial 
costs  for  child  protective  services  is  $10,000  per  case,  exclusive  of  legal  costs.  Psychological 
care  may  run  as  high  as  $24,(XX)  per  year.  Thus,  a  conservative  estimate  of  $50,000  a 
year  per  case  is  given.  Id. 

18.  DeRose,  Adult  Incest  Survivors  and  the  Statute  of  Limitations:  The  Delayed 
Discovery  Rule  and  Long  Term  Damages,  25  Santa  Clara  L.  Rev.  191  (1985)  [hereinafter 
Adult  Incest  Survivors.]  The  well-documented  fact  that  abused  children  frequently  become 
child  abusers  is  noted  as  follows; 

In  nearly  all  of  the  studies  of  male  sexual  offenders  that  have  been  done  to 
date,  well  over  half  or  in  some  cases  nearly  three-quarters  of  the  men  studied 
who  are  serving  time  in  prison  were  found  to  have  been  sexually  abused  as 
young  boys.  .  .  .  Therefore  .  .  .  from  generation  to  generation,  emotional,  phys- 
ical and  sexual  abuse  are  behaviors  exhibited  by  men  who  most  likely  experienced 
such  abuse  in  their  own  childhoods.  Sadly,  what  these  men  learned  from  their 
parents,  they  learned  too  well. 

Id.  at  218,  n.l39  (quoting  S.  Butler,  Conspiracy  of  Silence:  The  Trauma  of  Incest 

67  (1978)). 

19.  Note,  Sexually  Abused  Children,  supra  note  13,  at  452. 

20.  Id.  See  also  J.  Herman,  Father-Daughter  Incest  105  (1981);  B.  Justice  & 
R.  Justice,  The  Broken  Taboo:  Sex  in  the  Family  184-5  (1979);  S.  Butler,  Conspiracy 
of  Silence:  The  Trauma  of  Incest  121  (1978);  Adult  Incest  Survivors,  supra  note  18, 
at  194;  Child  Abuse  and  Neglect,  supra  note  1,  at  4-5. 


992  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

reforms  in  an  effort  to  address  the  needs  of  child  abuse  victims. ^^  For 
example,  commentators  and  critics  propose  that  child  abuse  victims  testify 
on  videotaped  recordings,  thus  reducing  the  trauma  experienced  by  child 
abuse  victims  in  testifying. ^^  Additionally,  numerous  jurisdictions  prom- 
ulgated mandatory  reporting  requirements  to  increase  the  likelihood  that 
child  sexual  abuse  will  be  discovered. ^^  Thus,  increased  societal  cognizance 
has  encouraged  the  judiciary  and  legislature  to  adopt  meaningful  measures 
to  assist  the  child  abuse  victim. 

B.     Barriers  to  Prosecution  of  Abusers 

As  a  preliminary  barrier  to  prosecution,  one  must  recognize  the 
gross  disparity  between  victim  and  offender  in  terms  of  power,  knowledge 
and  resources.^"*  Adults  and  older  children  utilize  this  disparity  to  psy- 
chologically manipulate  the  victim. ^^  In  the  case  of  incest,  the  victim  is 
even  more  vulnerable,  for  the  differences  in  power,  knowledge  and 
resources  are  multiplied  by  the  victim's  dependence  upon  the  offender 
for  Hfe's  basic  necessities.^^ 

Very  limited  force  is  required  to  molest  a  child.  The  child  victim 
is  seldom  able  to  understand  the  significance  or  wrongfulness  of  the 
perpetrator's  conduct. ^^  Over  75^o  of  reported  incest  cases  involve  father- 
daughter  relations. ^^  The  father's  position  as  an  authority  figure  may 
be  utilized  to  persuade  the  child  to  acquiesce.  Although  the  request  may 
seem  unpleasant,  distasteful,  or  even  frightening,  the  child  may  be 
motivated  by  a  strong  desire  not  to  displease  the  offender.^^  In  other 
cases,  the  child  may  be  assured  that  the  activity  is  perfectly  normal. 


21.  See  Comment,  Child  Sexual  Abuse  in  California:  Legislative  and  Judicial 
Responses,  15  Golden  Gate  U.L.  Rev.  437  (1985).  The  article  deals  with  proposed  and 
adopted  alterations  to  California's  system.  Many  of  the  procedures  have  been  adopted  by 
other  states,  for  example,  the  revision  of  reporting  requirements. 

22.  See  Note,  Sexually  Abused  Children,  supra  note  13,  at  478-80. 

23.  See,  e.g.,  Cal.  Penal  Code  §§  11165-11166  (West  Supp.  1985).  California's 
bill  requires  teachers,  social  workers,  probation  officers,  psychologists,  coroners,  police, 
physicians,  surgeons,  dentists  and  numerous  others  to  report  suspected  cases  of  child 
abuse.  Id. 

24.  ten  Bensel,  Child  Abuse  and  Neglect:  Definitions  of  Child  Neglect  and  Abuse, 
35  Juv.  &  Fam.  Ct.  J.  23,  29  (Winter  1984)  [hereinafter  Definitions  of  Child  Neglect]. 

25.  Id. 

26.  Id. 

27.  Note,  Balancing  The  Statute  Of  Limitations  And  The  Discovery  Rule:  Some 
Victims  Of  Incestuous  Abuse  Are  Denied  Access  To  Washington  Courts  -  Tyson  v.  Tyson, 
10  U.  PuGET  Sound  L.  Rev.  721,  727  (1987)  [hereinafter  Balancing  The  Statute  Of 
Limitations]. 

28.  Note,  Sexually  Abused  Children,  supra  note  13,  at  445  n.l8. 

29.  Note,  The  Crime  of  Incest  Against  the  Minor  Child  and  the  State's  Statutory 
Responses,  17  J.  Fam.  L.  93,  96  (1978-79)  [hereinafter  Incest  Against  the  Minor  Child]. 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  993 

given  the  relationship  between  the  adult  and  child. ^°  Whether  the  cause 
of  the  offense  is  a  disparity  in  power,  knowledge  or  resources,  the 
common  result  is  an  unwillingness  or  inability  on  the  part  of  the  child 
to  report  the  offense. 

Most  children  never  tell  anyone  about  the  sexual  encounter.^'  An 
estimated  75%  to  90<^o  of  incest  victims  reach  adulthood  without  revealing 
the  incident(s).^^  The  failure  or  inability  of  the  child  to  report  the  offense 
may  be  motivated  by  one  of  several  factors.  First,  incest  victims  may 
be  ashamed  or  embarrassed,  believing  themselves  to  be  the  cause  of  the 
attack."  Other  incest  victims,  frightened  by  the  offender's  threats,  fear 
that  the  innocent  parent  will  break-up  the  family. ^"^  Other  children  fear 
that  revealing  the  relationship  will  encourage  the  father's  anger,  rejection 
or  physical  harm.^^  The  child  may  fear  her  father  will  be  imprisoned, ^^ 
or  at  a  minimum,  that  her  mother  will  blame  her.^^ 

Another  major  cause  of  unreported  offenses  stems  from  the  child's 
mental  defense  mechanisms.  To  cope  with  undisclosed  victimization, 
children  frequently  mentally  block-out  the  abuse. ^^  As  a  result,  the  child 
may  not  remember  or  divulge  the  abuse  for  years. ^^  Compounding  the 
problem  of  non-reporting  by  child  victims  is  the  fact  that  incest  occurs 


30.  Id. 

31.  Definitions  Of  Child  Neglect,  supra  note  24,  at  31. 

32.  Adult  Incest  Survivors,  supra  note  18,  at  194. 

33.  Definitions  Of  Child  Neglect,  supra  note  24,  at  30. 

34.  Balancing  the  Statute  of  Limitations,  supra  note  27,  at  727. 

35.  Id. 

36.  Id. 

37.  Id.  Dr.  Judith  Herman,  a  noted  expert  in  father-daughter  incest  at  Harvard 
Medical  School  summarizes  such  incest  as  follows: 

Incestuous  abuse  usually  begins  when  the  child  is  between  the  ages  of  six  and 
twelve,  though  cases  involving  younger  children,  including  infants,  have  been 
reported.  The  sexual  contact  typically  begins  with  fondling  and  gradually  proceeds 
to  masturbation  and  oral-genital  contact.   Vaginal  intercourse  is  not  usually 
attempted  until  the  child  reaches  puberty.  Physical  violence  is  not  often  employed, 
since  the  overwhelming  authority  of  the  parent  is  usually  sufficient  to  gain  the 
child's  compliance.  The  sexual  contact  becomes  a  compulsive  behavior  for  the 
father,  whose  need  to  preserve  sexual  access  to  his  daughter  becomes  the  or- 
ganizing principle  of  family  life.  The  sexual  contact  is  usually  repeated  in  secrecy 
for  years,  ending  only  when  the  child  finds  the  resources  to  escape.  The  child 
victim  keeps  the  secret,  fearing  that  if  she  tells  she  will  not  be  believed,  she 
will  be  punished,  or  she  will  destroy  the  family. 
Note,  Civil  Claims  of  Adults  Molested  as  Children:  Maturation  of  Harm  and  the  Statute 
of  Limitations  Hurdle,  15  Fordham  Urb.  L.J.  709,  716  (1987)  (quoting  Herman,  Rec- 
ognition And  Treatment  Of  Incestuous  Families,  5  Int'l  J.  Fam.  Therapy  81,  82  (C. 
Barnard  Ed.  1983)). 

38.  Task  Force  On  Family  Violence,  supra  note  6,  at  103. 

39.  Id. 


994  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

in  secrecy  and  exhibits  few  outwardly  detectable  signs. "^^  Thus,  if  the 
child  does  not  report,  the  abuse  may  continue  unnoticed. 

Once  abuse  is  reported,  the  chance  of  prosecuting  the  abuser  is  low. 
A  mere  24%  of  all  child  sexual  abuse  cases  result  in  criminal  action."*^ 
Once  reported,  familial  indecision"*^  or  prosecutorial  discretion"*^  may 
preclude  criminal  prosecution.  Thus,  the  vast  majority  of  child  sexual 
abuse  incidents  go  unreported  or  unprosecuted. 

A  final  impediment  to  prosecution  is  the  tolling  of  the  statute  of 
limitations.  Most  criminal  statutes  of  limitations  accrue  from  the  date 
of  the  offense."*"*  Thus,  by  the  time  the  child  becomes  emotionally  or 
psychologically  capable  of  confronting  the  experience  and  seeks  legal 
redress,  the  statutory  period  for  prosecution  may  have  expired."*^  Fre- 
quently, disclosure  may  not  occur  for  one  to  three  years  subsequent  to 
the  offense."*^ 

C     Changing  Statutes  of  Limitations  to  Increase  the  Likelihood  of 

Prosecution 

The  emotional  and  psychological  barriers  to  reporting  child  sex  abuse 
frequently  foreclose  the  victim's  opportunity  for  legal  redress  and  preclude 
societal  intervention."*^  Obviously,  the  opportunity  for  legal  redress  varies 


40.  Note,  Incest  Against  The  Minor  Child,  supra  note  29,  at  96. 

41.  Sexually  Abused  Children,  supra  note  13,  at  446.  Even  after  detection,  pros- 
ecution is  impeded  by  (1)  social  skepticism  about  the  reliability  of  the  child's  accusations; 
(2)  classification  of  pedophilia  as  a  mental  disorder  rather  than  a  criminal  offense;  (3) 
procedural  systems  which  traumatize  the  victim;  and  (4)  reluctance  of  prosecutors  to  pursue 
prosecutions  where  the  case  rests  primarily  upon  the  content  and  stability  of  the  child's 
testimony.  Id. 

42.  Id.  at  448-49. 

43.  See  supra  note  41, 

44.  Task  Force  on  Family  Violence,  supra  note  6,  at  103.  Of  the  jurisdictions 
addressing  the  issue  of  retroactive  application  of  the  enlarged  limitations  period  within 
the  context  of  child  sexual  abuse  offenses,  the  following  states  have  statutes  of  limitations 
accruing  from  the  commission  of  the  offense:  CaUfornia,  Cal.  Penal  Code  §§  800,  801 
(West  1985);  Colorado,  Colo.  Rev.  Stat.  §  18-3-411(2)  (1986);  Texas,  Tex.  Crim.  Proc. 
Code  Ann.  §  12.01  (Vernon  1977,  1988  Supp.);  Washington,  Wash.  Rev.  Code  Ann. 

§  9A.04.070  (1988).  In  the  remaining  two  jurisdictions,  the  limitations  period  accrues  from 
the  time  the  minor  reaches  the  age  of  16:  Alaska,  Alaska  Stat.  §  12.10.030(c)  (1984) 
(The  period  runs  from  the  earlier  of  the  victim  attaining  the  age  of  16,  or  the  report  to 
a  peace  officer.  The  section  does  not  extend  the  limitations  period  by  more  than  five 
years.);  Massachusetts,  Mass.  Gen.  Laws  Ann.  ch.  277,  §  63  (West  1972,  Supp.  1988) 
(The  limitations  period  commences  at  the  earlier  of  the  victim  attaining  the  age  of  16, 
or  the  report  to  a  law  enforcement  agency. 

45.  Task  Force  on  Family  Violence,  supra  note  6,  at  103. 

46.  Definitions  of  Child  Neglect,  supra  note  24,  at  30. 

47.  Task  Force  on  Family  Violence,  supra  note  6,  at  103. 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  995 

in  direct  proportion  to  the  length  and  accrual  date  of  the  limitations 
period.  Limitations  periods  commencing  at  the  date  of  the  offense  and 
expiring  within  five  years  are  currently  the  norm/^  However,  lesser 
limitations  periods  still  exist /^  The  statute  of  limitations  in  these  juris- 
dictions remains  a  major  impediment  to  legal  redress. 

In  recognition  of  the  delays  common  in  the  reporting  of  child  sex 
abuse,  the  United  States  Attorney  General  recommended  that  the  states 
enlarge  the  statutes  of  limitations  so  as  to  commence  from  the  date  of 
the  victim's  disclosure. ^° 

Where  legislatures  respond  to  these  concerns  by  extending  the  lim- 
itations period,^'  retroactive  application  may  become  an  issue  in  imple- 
menting the  revised  statute.  Several  policy  considerations  support  a 
presumption  for  retroactive  application.  First,  retroactive  application 
furthers  the  goal  of  reducing  barriers  to  the  prosecution  of  offenders 
and  of  permitting  victims  an  opportunity  for  legal  redress. ^^  Abused 
children  must  recognize  that  society  is  concerned  with  their  plight  and 
that  children's  rights  are  being  actively  protected.  Retroactive  application 
of  enlarged  Hmitations  periods  channels  the  benefits  of  increased  societal 
and  legislative  awareness  to  those  children  who  have  been  abused,  rather 
than  merely  protecting  the  abused  children  of  tomorrow.  Early  societal 
intervention  diminishes  the  psychological  costs  children  pay  by  permitting 
prompt  psychological  care,  and  also  by  preventing  additional  abuse  at 
the  hands  of  the  offender.  Children,  not  adults,  are  the  judges  of  our 
present  civilization." 

A  second  policy  consideration  supporting  retroactive  application  is 
the  need  to  permit  child  abuse  victims  a  day  in  court.  The  American 
legal  system  is  designed  to  channel  conflict  resolution  from  the  streets 
into  the  court  system. ^"^  Fundamental  to  the  operation  of  the  legal  system 
is  the  requirement  that  each  litigant  have  his  or  her  '*day  in  court." 
Although  in  the  criminal  context  it  is  the  prosecution,  not  the  victim. 


48.  See,  e.g.,  Idaho  Code  §  19-40  (1987)  (prosecution  must  be  commenced  within 
5  years  after  offense  committed);  Kan.  Crim.  Code  Ann.  §  21-3106  (1971,  Supp.  1988) 
(prosecution  must  be  commenced  within  5  years  after  offense  committed). 

49.  See,  e.g..  Ark.  Stat.  Ann.  §  5-1-109  (1987)  (prosecution  must  be  commenced 
with  3  years  after  commission;  first  degree  child  sexual  abuse  is  a  class  C  felony  per  5- 
14-108). 

50.  Task  Force  on  Family  Violence,  supra  note  6,  at  103. 

51.  See,  e.g..  Commonwealth  v.  Bargeron,  402  Mass.  589,  593,  524  N.E.2d  829, 
831-32  (1988);  State  v.  Hodgson,  108  Wash.  2d  662,  666,  740  P.2d  848,  850  (1987). 

52.  As  well,  society  obtains  an  opportunity  to  deter,  rehabilitate  or  incarcerate  the 
offender. 

53.  Protecting  the  Rights,  supra  note  17,  at  72. 

54.  See,  e.g.,  H.  Grilliot,  Introduction  to  Law  and  the  Legal  System  3  (2d 
ed.  1979);  1  C.  Torcia,  Wharton's  Criminal  Law  1  (14th  Ed.  1978). 


996  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

who  has  his  *'day  in  court,"  the  victim  may  experience  reUef  and 
satisfaction  from  the  defendant's  prosecution,  and  thus  indirectly,  have 
his  own  day  in  court.  The  statute  of  limitations  limits  this  right  by 
forcing  the  party  to  bring  his  or  her  action  in  a  timely  manner  or  be 
forever  barred.  In  the  civil  context,  the  use  of  exceptions  to  the  limitations 
period's  accrual  such  as  the  ** discovery  rule,"  limits  the  harshness  im- 
posed by  stringent  apphcation  of  the  limitations  period. ^^ 

Retroactive  apphcation  of  revised  statutes  of  limitations  can  serve 
a  similar  function  in  the  context  of  child  sexual  abuse. 

In  the  criminal  context,  the  state  and  not  the  injured  party  prosecutes 
the  action.  In  the  civil  context,  the  prospective  plaintiff  is  generally 
cognizant  of  the  injury  when  it  occurs,  and  as  a  result,  may  bring  an 
action  in  a  timely  manner.  In  the  context  of  child  sexual  abuse  the  state 
is  powerless  to  prosecute  the  child  sex  abuse  offender  until  the  state  is 
informed  of  the  offense.  As  discussed  above,  a  variety  of  physical, 
emotional  and  psychological  factors  prevent  the  victim  from  reporting 
the  offense. ^^  As  a  result  of  this  delay  in  reporting  the  offense,  the 
hmitations  period  and  the  state's  right  to  prosecute  may  expire  prior  to 
the  time  a  child  reports  the  offense. 

A  final  poUcy  consideration  compelling  retroactive  application  of 
the  enlarged  limitations  period  is  the  need  to  punish  the  offender.  One 
of  the  principal  functions  of  criminal  law  is  to  deter  the  offender  and 
all  aspiring  offenders.^^  The  deterrence  theory  is  predicated  upon  the 
belief  that  individuals  are  rational,  hedonistic  beings. ^^  The  unpleasantness 
of  punishment,  coupled  with  its  certainty,  deter  the  offender  from  re- 
peating his  lawless  conduct. ^^  A  secondary  benefit  of  the  deterrence 
theory  is  the  intimidation  of  potential  offenders.^  Thus,  both  the  offender 
and  the  potential  offender,  faced  with  the  certainty  of  severe  punishment, 
will  Hkely  refrain  from  committing  a  contemplated  crime.^' 


55.  See,  e.g.,  N.Y.  Civ.  Prac.  L.  &  R.  214-c  (McKinney  Supp.  1987).  This  statute 
provides  in  pertinent  part: 

*'[W]here  the  discovery  of  the  cause  of  the  injury  is  alleged  to  have  occurred 
less  than  five  years  after  discovery  of  the  injury  or  when  with  reasonable  diligence 
such  injury  should  have  been  discovered,  whichever  is  earlier,  an  action  may 
be  commenced  .  .  .  within  one  year  of  such  discovery  of  the  cause  of  the  injury." 
Id. 

56.  See  supra  notes  24-39  and  accompanying  text. 

57.  1  C.  ToRCiA,  supra  note  54,  §  3.  Criminal  law  may  be  premised  upon  any  of 
three  theories;  deterrence,  retribution  or  reformation.  The  deterrence  theory  is  particularly 
appropriate  for  child  sexual  abuse  offenses  because  of  its  focus  upon  the  individual 
offender.  Id. 

58.  Id. 

59.  Id. 

60.  Id. 

61.  Id. 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  997 

Studies  reveal  that  child  sex  abusers  are  extremely  likely  to  continue 
their  nefarious  conduct,  absent  societal  intervention. ^^  Documentation  of 
unreported  sexual  assaults  against  children  dramatize  the  magnitude  of 
the  problem. ^^  A  study  of  first  offenders^'*  demonstrated  that  many 
offenders  commit  numerous  offenses  prior  to  prosecution  or  conviction. ^^ 
Additionally,  sexual  offenders  avoid  detection  approximately  twice  as 
often  as  they  are  apprehended.^^  These  figures  are  conservative  estimates, 
given  the  fact  that  the  majority  of  offenses  go  unreported,  while  numerous 
others  go  unrecognized  by  the  criminal  justice  system.^''  Therefore,  absent 
societal  intervention,  most  offenders  will  continue  their  activities  un- 
impeded. 

The  typical  pedophile  commits  his  first  offense  as  an  adolescent. ^^ 
Pedophiles  are  likely  to  continue  their  illicit  activities  once  commenced. ^^ 
Thus,  from  a  societal  perspective,  the  opportunity  for  societal  intervention 
at  the  earliest  possible  juncture  is  imperative  so  as  to  maximize  deterrence. 
To  be  an  effective  deterrent,  the  punishment  must  be  certain  and  severe. ^^ 
Retroactive  application  of  the  revised  statute  of  limitations  maximizes 
society's  opportunities  for  intervention,  and  therefore,  increases  the  de- 
terrent effect  of  criminal  punishment.  Furthermore,  early  intervention 
extirpates  the  offender  from  his  criminal  habitat,  protects  the  child  from 
continued  victimization,  and  terminates  the  offender's  reign  of  terror. 

Critics  contend  that  society  has  overreacted  to  the  perceived  demon, 
child  sexual  abuse. ''^  Conceivably,  this  position  has  merit.  However,  at 
either  extreme,  either  over  or  under  reporting,  truth  seldom  resides. ^^ 
Legislatures  mandate  longer  prison  sentences  for  convicted  child  sexual 
offenders,  while  reducing  judicial  sentencing  discretion.^^  Despite  these 


62.  See  Groth,  Longo,  &  McFadin,  Undetected  Recidivism  Among  Rapists  and 
Child  Molesters,  28  Crime  and  Delinq.  450,  451  [hereinafter  Undetected  Recidivism];  but 
see  B.  Karpan,  The  Sexual  Offender  and  His  Offenses  276-78  (New  York  1954). 

63.  Undetected  Recidivism,  supra  note  62,  at  453. 

64.  Here,  meaning  those  who  experienced  a  first  conviction,  and  not  necessarily 
their  first  offense. 

65.  Undetected  Recidivism,  supra  note  62,  at  453-54.  The  study's  authors  interviewed 
offenders  at  correctional  facilities  in  Connecticut  and  Florida.  The  number  of  undetected 
sexual  assaults  reported  by  the  subjects  ranged  from  0  through  250.  Undetected  assaults 
averaged  4.7,  representing  the  number  of  different  victims  molested,  rather  than  the  number 
of  sexual  contacts.  Id.  Additionally,  sexual  offenders  avoid  detection  approximately  twice 
as  often  as  they  are  apprehended. 

66.  Id.  at  456. 

67.  Id.  at  457. 

68.  Id.  at  450. 

69.  Id.  at  451. 

70.  1  C.  ToRciA,  supra  note  54,  §  3. 

71.  Protecting  Children,  supra  note  4  at  39. 

72.  Id. 

73.  Id. 


998  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

perceived  overreactions,  increased  societal  cognizance  has  resulted  in  the 
correction  of  at  least  one  glaring  impediment  to  criminal  prosecution 
of  the  child  sexual  abuser,  that  is,  the  short  statute  of  limitations  period. 

III.     State  Court  Approaches  To  the  Interpretation  and 
Application  of  Legislatively  Enlarged  Statutes  of  Limitations 
FOR  THE  Criminal  Prosecution  of  Child  Sexual  Abuse  Offenses 

Within  the  criminal  context, '''*  the  courts  of  six'^^  jurisdictions  have 
addressed  the  issue  of  the  interpretation  and  application  of  legislatively 
enlarged  statutes  of  limitations  for  child  sexual  abuse  offenses.  In  in- 
terpreting and  applying  these  statutes,  the  courts  have  appUed  a  variety 
of  procedures. ^^  However,  a  two-step  analysis  predominates.  First,  the 
court  must  determine  whether  the  revised  statute  survives  ex  post  facto 
analysis;  then,  the  court  must  determine  how  to  interpret  and  apply  the 
statute. 

A.     Ex  Post  Facto  Analysis 

The  United  States  Constitution  expressly  prohibits  the  states  from 
enacting  ex  post  facto  laws.^^  An  ex  post  facto  law,  to  be  considered 
impermissible  in  the  criminal  context,  "must  be  retrospective;  that  is, 
it  must  apply  to  events  occurring  before  its  enactment  and  must  dis- 
advantage the  offender  affected  by  it."^^  The  classic  exposition  of  ex 


14.  This  note  is  expressly  limited  to  criminal  prosecutions  for  child  sex  abuse.  The 
statute  of  limitations  is  characterized  differently  within  the  civil  context  such  that  factors 
including  minority  or  incapacity  may  apply  so  as  to  prevent  the  running  of  the  statute 
of  limitations  until  the  child  attains  majority. 

75.  Those  jurisdictions  are:  Alaska,  California,  Colorado,  Massachusetts,  Texas 
and  Washington.  A  majority  of  the  states  have  addressed  the  same  issue  within  the  general 
criminal  statute  of  Hmitations  context.  As  explained  within  this  note,  the  state  courts  have 
reached  diverse  results  using  varied  analysis.  See,  e.g.,  State  v.  Paradise,  189  Conn.  356, 
456  A. 2d  305  (1983)  (absent  clear  legislative  intent  requiring  retroactive  application,  criminal 
statute  of  limitations  applied  prospectively;  court  did  not  determine  whether  the  statute 
of  limitations  is  procedural  or  substantive);  Rubin  v.  State,  390  So.  2d  322,  324  (Fla. 
1980)  (statute  of  limitations  is  a  substantive  right,  and  so  statute  of  limitations  in  effect 
at  time  of  offense  is  controlling). 

76.  Cf.  State  v.  Creekpaum,  732  P.2d  557  (Alaska  Ct.  App.  1987),  rev'd,  753 
P. 2d  1139  (Alaska  1988)  (statute  of  hmitations  vests  a  substantive  right;  therefore,  retroactive 
application  of  enlarged  period  prohibited);  Archer  v.  State,  557  S.W.2d  244  (Tex.  Crim. 
App.  1979)  (statute  may  be  applied  to  all  offenses  not  time-barred);  State  v.  Hodgson, 
108  Wash.  2d  662,  740  P. 2d  848  (1987)  (statute  of  limitations  is  procedural;  thus,  judicial 
presumption  of  retroactivity  requires  retrospective  application  of  revised  statute). 

77.  U.S.  Const,  art.  I,  §  10,  cl.   1. 

78.  Weaver  v.  Graham,  450  U.S.  24,  29  (1981). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  999 

post  facto  laws  is  found  in  the  seminal  case  of  Calder  v.  Bull,'^^  which 
states: 

1st.  Every  law  that  makes  an  action  done  before  the  passing  of 
the  law,  and  which  was  innocent  when  done,  criminal;  and 
punishes  such  action.  2d.  Every  law  that  aggravates  a  crime,  or 
makes  it  greater  than  it  was,  when  committed.  3d.  Every  law 
that  changes  the  punishment,  and  inflicts  a  greater  punishment 
than  the  law  annexed  to  the  crime,  when  committed.  4th.  Every 
law  that  alters  the  legal  rules  of  evidence,  and  receives  less,  or 
different  testimony,  than  the  law  required  at  the  time  of  the 
commission  of  the  offence,  in  order  to  convict  the  offender.^° 

The  ex  post  facto  prohibition  was  intended  "to  secure  substantial 
personal  rights  against  arbitrary  and  oppressive  legislation,  but  not  to 
Hmit  legislative  control  of  remedies  and  modes  of  procedure  which  do 
not  affect  matters  of  substance.  "^^  Thus,  although  the  category  of 
retroactive  changes  forbidden  by  the  ex  post  facto  clause  includes  more 
than  just  the  elements  and  punishment  for  a  crime,  the  prohibition,  as 
defined  in  Calder  v.  Bull,^^  arguably  does  not  extend  to  a  retroactive 
appHcation  of  the  statute  of  limitations  because  extension  of  the  statute 
of  limitations  performs  none  of  the  impermissibles  forbidden  by  the 
Calder  decision. 

A  fundamental  issue  in  determining  whether  or  not  retroactive  ap- 
plication of  an  enlarged  statute  of  limitations  is  barred  by  the  ex  post 
facto  prohibition  is  whether  the  statute  of  limitations  vests  substantive 
rights  in  the  accused,  or  is  merely  a  procedural  barrier.  If  the  statute 
vests  substantive  rights,  then  retroactive  application  of  the  statute  of 
Hmitations  should  be  prohibited  by  the  ex  post  facto  clause.  If  the  statute 
is  merely  procedural,  and  vests  no  substantive  rights,  the  enlarged  statute 
of  limitations  survives  ex  post  facto  scrutiny. 

In  the  context  of  child  sexual  abuse,  few  states  have  determined 
that  statute  of  Hmitations  vests  substative  rights  in  the  accused. ^^  However, 
the  "substantive  vested  rights"  analysis  is  important  to  understanding 
the  "time-barred"  approach,  and  the  argument  for  more  expansive 
retroactive  application  of  enlarged  statutes  of  limitations.  One  case  which 
illustrates  the  substantive  versus  procedural  rights  analysis,  and  the  vague- 


79.  3  U.S.  (1  Dall.)  386  (1798). 

80.  Id.  at  390. 

81.  Beazell  v.  Ohio,  269  U.S.   167,  170-71  (1925). 

82.  3  U.S.(1  Dall.)  386  (1798). 

83.  See,  e.g.,  People  v.  Sweet,  207  Cal.  App.  3d  78,  84,  254  Cal.  Rptr.  567,  571 
(1989).  Additionally,  both  Florida  and  Alabama  have  held  that  the  statute  of  limitations 
is  substantive  within  the  general  eriminal  context. 


1000  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

ness  and  uncertainty  involved  in  the  definition  of  an  ex  post  facto  law, 
is  State  v.  Creekpaum.^'^  In  Creekpaum  the  Alaska  Court  of  Appeals 
held  that  a  criminal  statute  of  limitations  vests  a  substantive  right  in 
the  defendant;^^  the  Alaska  Supreme  Court,  in  overturning  the  decision, 
held  that  the  statute  of  limitations  is  procedural,  and  as  such,  extension 
prior  to  the  original  period's  expiration  does  not  violate  either  the  United 
States  or  the  Alaska  Constitution.^^ 

The  Alaska  Court  of  Appeals  determined  that  to  be  classified  as 
substantive  for  purposes  of  ex  post  facto  analysis,  a  change  in  the  law 
must  merely  adversely  affect  the  defendant,  and  operate  so  as  to  place 
the  defendant  "at  a  disadvantage  in  relation  to  the  substance  of  the 
offense  charged  or  the  penalties  prescribed  for  that  offense.''^''  The 
Alaska  Court  of  Appeals  found  Weaver  v.  Graham^^  dispositive.  In 
Weaver,  the  United  States  Supreme  Court  stated  that  although  the 
** substantive  vested  rights"  theory^^  is  useful  for  due  process  analysis, 
the  theory  is  irrelevant  to  the  question  of  whether  a  change  is  substantive 
or  procedural  for  ex  post  facto  purposes. ^°  Critical  to  ex  post  facto 
analysis  is 

the  lack  of  fair  notice  and  governmental  restraint  when  the 
legislature  increases  punishment  beyond  what  is  prescribed  when 
the  crime  was  consummated.  Thus,  even  if  a  statute  merely  alters 
penal  provisions  accorded  by  grace  of  the  legislature,  it  violates 
the  Clause  if  it  is  both  retrospective  and  more  onerous  than  the 
law  in  effect  on  the  date  of  the  offense.^^ 

The  court  of  appeals  found  that  retrospective  application  of  the  enlarged 
limitations  period  disadvantaged  the  offender  affected  by  the  change  and 
was  more  onerous  than  the  law  in  effect  at  the  time  of  the  offense. 
Thus,  the  Alaska  Court  of  Appeals  held  that  the  ex  post  facto  clauses 
of  the  federal  and  Alaska  Constitutions  prohibit  retrospective  change  in 
a  criminal  statute  of  Hmitations.^^ 


84.  732  P.2d  557  (Alaska  Ct.  App.  1987),  rev'd  753  P.2d  1139  (Alaska  1988). 

85.  732  P.2d  at  569. 

86.  753  P.2d  at  1144. 

87.  Id.  at  560.  See  Thompson  v.  Utah,  170  U.S.  343  (1898)  ("[A]  statute  is  ex 
post  facto  which  ...  in  its  relation  to  the  offense  or  its  consequences,  alters  the  situation 
of  the  accused  to  his  disadvantage."). 

88.  450  U.S.  24  (1981). 

89.  See  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420,  425  (2d  Cir.),  cert,  denied,  277  U.S. 
590  (1928). 

90.  Weaver,  450  U.S.  at  29-30. 

91.  Id.  at  30-31. 

92.  State  v.  Creekpaum,  732  P.2d  557,  568  (Alaska  Ct.  App.  1987). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1001 

After  determining  that  the  constitutional  prohibition  was  not  limited 
to  retroactive  changes  in  the  elements  of  or  punishment  for  a  crime, ^^ 
the  court  of  appeals  addressed  the  issue  of  whether  the  criminal  statute 
of  limitations  vests  a  substantive  right  upon  the  accused. ^"^  Preliminarily, 
the  court  opined  that  the  legislature  may  not  revive  an  expired  statute 
of  limitations.^^  The  court  then  reviewed  historical  precedents,  noting 
that  Alaskan  courts  had  previously  held  that  a  civil  statute  of  limitations 
was  substantive,  not  procedural. ^^  Additionally,  criminal  statutes  of  lim- 
itations had  been  held  to  be  substantive,  but  only  within  other  decisional 
contexts  and  not  for  purposes  of  ex  post  facto  analysis.^''  The  Hne 
dividing  ''substance  and  procedure  shifts  as  the  context  changes  .  .  . 
[and]  implies  different  variables  depending  upon  the  particular  problem 
for  which  it  is  used."^^  The  Creekpaum  court  recognized  that  the  dis- 
tinction between  a  procedural  and  substantive  change  "cannot  be  reduced 
to  a  simple  formula,"  but  must  be  determined  on  a  "case-by-case  basis. "^^ 
The  Creekpaum  court  rejected  the  argument  that  the  statute  of  Umitations 
is  a  mere  limitation  upon  the  remedy,  ^^  instead  finding  that  because 
the  statute  of  Umitations  Umits  the  circumstances  under  which  guilt  can 
be  found  and  is  intended  to  preserve  the  accuracy  and  basic  integrity 
of  the  adjudicatory  process  in  criminal  procedure,  the  statute  operates 
as  a  substantive  right  for  purposes  of  ex  post  facto  analysis. ^^*  Thus, 
without  directly  addressing  the  issue  of  legislative  intent,  the  court  forbade 
retroactive  application  of  legislatively  enlarged  criminal  statutes  of  lim- 
itations. ^^^ 


93.  Creekpaum,  732  P. 2d  at  563-64. 

94.  Id.  at  564. 

95.  Id.  at  560-61.  See  also  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420  (2d  Cir.),  cert, 
denied.  111  U.S.  590  (1928). 

Certainly  it  is  one  thing  to  revive  a  prosecution  already  dead,  and  another  to 
give  it  a  longer  lease  of  life.  The  question  turns  upon  how  much  violence  is 
done  to  our  instinctive  feelings  of  justice  and  fair  play.  For  the  state  to  assure 
a  man  that  he  has  become  safe  from  its  pursuit,  and  thereafter  to  withdraw 
assurance,  seems  to  most  of  us  unfair  and  dishonest.  But,  while  the  chase  is 
on,  it  does  not  shock  us  to  have  it  extended  beyond  the  time  first  set,  or  if  it 
does,  the  stake  forgives  it. 
Id.  at  425-26. 

96.  Creekpaum,  732  P. 2d  at  566.  See  Nolan  v.  Sea  Airmotive,  Inc.,  627  P. 2d  1035 
(Alaska  1981). 

97.  See  State  v.  Freeh  Funeral  Home,  185  N.J.  Super  385,  448  A.2d  1037  (1982). 

98.  Hanna  v.  Plumer,  380  U.S.  460,  471  (1965).  A  court  may  seek  to  ascertain 
the  differences  between  substance  and  procedure  in  the  following  contexts:  conflict  of 
laws,  retrospective  application  of  statutes  and  law-making.  Busik  v.  Levine,  63  N.J.  351, 
364-65,  307  A.2d  571,  578-79  (1973). 

99.  Creekpaum,  132  P. 2d  at  562. 

100.  Id.  at  567. 

101.  Id.  at  568. 

102.  Id. 


1002  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

The  appellate  court  premised  its  decision  to  classify  the  statute  of 
Hmitations  as  substantive  largely  upon  the  belief  that,  because  the  en- 
actment of  the  statute  serves  notice  to  the  accused  of  the  period  for 
which  he  must  be  prepared  to  defend  his  act,  "basic  fairness  militates 
against  requiring  the  accused  to  defend  his  acts  once  the  period  .  .  . 
has  expired. "^°^  Although  the  decision  is  laudable  for  its  effort  to  preserve 
the  rights  of  the  criminally  accused,  the  court  failed  to  consider  or 
address  the  legislature's  intent  or  the  child  victim's  right  to  legal  redress. 

On  appeal,  the  Alaska  Supreme  Court  reversed,  holding  that  criminal 
statutes  of  limitations  are  procedural'^"*  and  as  such,  extension  of  the 
statute  prior  to  the  original  period's  expiration  does  not  violate  the 
United  States  or  Alaska  Constitutions. '°^  Like  both  lower  courts,  the 
Alaska  Supreme  Court  found  Weaver  v.  Graham^^^  dispositive. '^^  In 
Weaver,  the  petitioner  challenged,  on  ex  post  facto  grounds,  a  change 
in  Florida's  statutory  formula  for  the  accrual  of  good  time  reductions 
in  prisoners'  sentences.  The  change  made  accrual  of  good  time  reductions 
more  difficult,  thus  increasing  the  quantum  of  punishment  suffered  by 
each  inmate.  The  Supreme  Court  held  that  the  statute  violated  the  ex 
post  facto  prohibition  because  it  ''makes  more  onerous  the  punishment 
for  crimes  committed  before  its  enactment. "'^^ 

Creekpaum  argued  that  the  Weaver  decision  introduced  a  new  analytic 
approach  to  ex  post  facto  analysis. '^^  In  place  of  the  vested  rights 
approach, ''°  the  court  should  focus  upon  only  two  criteria:  (1)  whether 
the  law  was  retrospective,  and  (2)  whether  the  change  disadvantaged  the 
offender  affected  by  the  change. *'•  The  Alaska  Supreme  Court  rejected 
Creekpaum 's  argument,  noting  that  the  Weaver  decision  did  not  nuUify 
existing  ex  post  facto  precedent.''^  Instead,  the  Creekpaum  court  found 
that  the  holding  in  Weaver  fell  within  the  traditional  prohibition  an- 
nounced in  Calder  v.  BuW^^  because  ''it  focused  on  the  change  in  the 


103.  Id.  The  court  further  stated  that  the  statute  of  limitations  defines  "the  outer 
limit  of  delay,  beyond  which  prosecution  will  not  be  tolerated,  even  where  the  government 
has  exercised  good  faith  in  attempting  to  file  .  .  .  and  when  the  accused  is  incapable  of 
identifying  prejudice  .  .  .  from  the  delay."  Id. 

104.  State  v.  Creekpaum,  753  P.2d  1139,  1144  n.l3. 

105.  Id.  at  1144. 

106.  450  U.S.  24  (1981). 

107.  Creekpaum,  753  P.2d  at  1140. 

108.  450  U.S.  at  36. 

109.  753  P.2d  at  1141. 

110.  See  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420,  425  (2d  Cir.),  cert,  denied,  277  U.S. 
590  (1928). 

111.  Creekpaum,  753  P.2d  at  1141. 

112.  Id. 

113.  3  U.S.  (1  Dall.)  386,  390  (1798). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1003 

quantum  of  punishment  Weaver  suffered  as  a  result  of  the  new  law."^'"^ 
The  Creekpaum  court  then  applied  a  two-step  test.  First  the  court 
noted  that  the  revised  statute  of  limitations  was  explicitly  retroactive.'^^ 
Second,  the  court  rejected  Creekpaum's  argument  that  the  new  law  was 
more  onerous  simply  because  Creekpaum  remained  liable  for  prosecution 
when  he  would  have  been  immune  under  the  old  statute.''^  The  court 
determined  that  the  extension  of  the  statute  of  limitations  was  a  mere 
procedural  change' '^  and,  applying  the  Calder  v.  Bull  test,''^  found  that 
retroactive  application  did  not  violate  the  ex  post  facto  clause  because 
the  change  neither  made  conduct  criminal  which  was  innocent  when 
undertaken,  aggravated  a  crime,  permitted  more  severe  punishment  than 
permissible  when  the  crime  was  committed,  nor  altered  the  rules  of 
evidence  to  permit  conviction  on  different  or  lesser  testimony  than 
permissible  when  the  crime  was  committed.''^ 

B.    Analysis  of  Court's  Interpretation  and  Retroactive  Application  of 

Enlarged  Statues  of  Limitation 

If  the  enlarged  statute  of  limitations  survives  a  facial  ex  post  facto 
analysis  (i.e.,  the  statute  does  not  vest  the  defendant  with  a  substantive 
right),  the  issue  becomes  whether  the  enlarged  statute  of  limitations 
should  be  retroactively  applied,  and  if  so,  whether  the  application  is 
limited  solely  to  offenses  not  time-barred  as  of  the  statute's  effective 
date.  The  determinative  question  is  whether  prosecution  is  legally  per- 
missible as  of  the  new  statute's  effective  date. 

Typically,  courts'  analysis  rests  upon  what  has  become  a  fundamental 
precept  of  criminal  law,  that  is,  the  legislature  may  not  extend  the  statute 
of  limitations  so  as  to  revive  an  offense  already  time-barred. '^°  However, 
unless  prospective  appHcation  is  expressly  mandated,  a  statute  which 
extends  the  limitations  period  applies  to  all  offenses  not  time-barred  as 
of  the  statute's  effective  date,  "so  that  a  prosecution  may  be  commenced 
at  any  time  within  the  newly  established  period,  although  the  old  period 
of  Hmitations  has  then  expired.'"^'  Thus,  the  principal  consideration  is 


114.  Creekpaum,   753  P.2d  at  1142. 

115.  Id, 

116.  Id. 

117.  Id.   at  1144,  n.l3. 

118.  3  U.S.  (1  Dall.)  386,  390  (1798). 

119.  Creekpaum,  753  P.2d  at  1143. 

120.  See  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420,  425-26  (2d  Cir.)  cert,  denied  111 
U.S.  590  (1928)  Sobiek  v.  Superior  Ct.,  28  Cal.  App.  3d  846,  850,  106  Cal.  Rptr.  516, 
519  (1972). 

121.  Archer  v.  State,  577  S.W.2d  244.  See  Hill  v.  State,  146  Tex.  Crim.  333,  171 
S.W.2d  880  (1943).  Thus,  the  principal  consideration  is  whether  the  accused  had  acquired 
a  vested  right  to  avoid  prosecution  as  of  the  new  statute's  effective  date. 


1004  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

whether  the  accused  had  acquired  a  vested  right  to  avoid  prosecution 
as  of  the  new  statute's  effective  date.^^^  Traditionally,  the  new  statute 
will  be  applied  only  where  the  accused  does  not  own  a  vested  right  to 
avoid  prosecution.  ^^^  However,  legislative  intent,  the  doctrine  of  strict 
construction,  and  judicial  presumptions  may  limit  the  statute's  appH- 
cation.  Generally,  courts  refuse  to  apply  the  statute  to  those  defendants 
against  whom  the  right  to  prosecute  has  expired  prior  to  legislative 
extension,  regardless  of  legislative  intent. ^^"^ 

In  discerning  legislative  intent  as  to  the  statute's  retroactive  appli- 
cation, courts  use  three  different  approaches.  In  the  first  approach,  the 
revised  statute  applies  prospectively  in  the  absence  of  manifest  legislative 
intent  to  the  contrary. ^^^  In  the  second  approach,  the  revised  statute 
applies  retrospectively  in  the  absence  of  manifest  legislative  intent  to  the 
contrary. '^^  Finally,  where  legislative  intent  is  unclear,  the  courts  apply 
the  statute  either  prospectively  or  retrospectively,  depending  upon  judicial 
presumptions  and  the  judiciary's  perception  of  legislative  intent. '^^ 

In  the  first  approach,  the  revised  statute  applies  prospectively  in  the 
absence  of  manifest  legislative  intent  to  the  contrary.  The  bare  deter- 
mination that  there  is  no  ex  post  facto  barrier  to  retroactive  application 
does  not,  without  clear  legislative  intent,  permit  retroactive  application.'^* 
Clear  legislative  intent  is  necessary  because,  as  a  general  rule,  changes 


122.  See,  e.g..  Archer  v.  State,  577  S.W.2d  244  (Tex.  Crim.  App.  1979);  Hill  v. 
State,  146  Tex.  Crim.  333,  171  S.W.2d  880  (1943). 

123.  Sobiek,  28  Cal.  App.  3d  at  850,  106  Cal.  Rptr.  at  519. 

124.  The  majority  opinion  did  not  address  Legislative  intent  in  either  Texas  case. 
In  People  v.  Smith,  171  Cal.  App.  3d  997,  217  Cal.  Rptr.  634  (1985),  the  court  addressed 
the  issue  of  legislative  intent,  citing  People  v.  Smith,  161  Cal.  App.  3d  1053,  208  Cal. 
Rptr.  318  (1984)  for  the  proposition  that  the  revised  statute  may  be  retroactively  applied 
without  express  legislative  intent.  This  proposition  is  premised  on  the  existence  of  established 
precedents  permitting  application  of  extended  limitations  periods  to  crimes  committed 
before  the  enactments  and  a  legislative  awareness  of  the  court's  existing  judicial  precedents. 
Thus,  the  judiciary  may  infer  that  the  legislature  enacted  the  statute  with  the  knowledge 
and  purpose  that  the  revised  statute  would  apply  to  all  cases  not  time-barred.  A  presumption 
of  prospectivity  "is  to  be  applied  only  after,  considering  all  pertinent  factors,  it  is  determined 
that  it  is  impossible  to  ascertain  the  legislative  intent."  Smith,  171  Cal.  App.  3d  at  1003, 
217  Cal.  Rptr.  at  637. 

125.  See,  e.g..  People  v.  Whitesell,  729  P.2d  985  (Colo.  1986);  People  v.  Midgley, 
714  P.2d  902  (Colo.  1986);  People  v.  Holland,  708  P.2d  119  (Colo.  1985). 

126.  See,  e.g..  State  v.  Hodgson,  44  Wash.  App.  592,  722  P.2d  1336  (1986),  affd 
in  part,  rev'd  in  part,  remanded  in  part,  108  Wash.  2d  662,  740  P.2d  848  (1987). 

127.  See,  e.g..  Commonwealth  v.  Pellegrino,  402  Mass.  1003,  524  N.E.2d  835  (1988); 
Tigges  V.  Commonwealth,  402  Mass.  1003,  524  N.E.2d  834  (1988);  Commonwealth  v. 
Bargeron,  402  Mass.  589,  524  N.E.2d  829  (1988). 

128.  Holland,  708  P.2d  at  120.  See  also  United  States  v.  Richardson,  512  F.2d  105 
(3d  Cir,  1975);  State  v.  Paradise,  189  Conn.  346,  456  A.2d  305  (Conn.  1983). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1005 

in  criminal  statutes  operate  prospectively. ^^^  This  presumption  of  pros- 
pectivity  is  premised  upon  several  maxims  fundamental  to  criminal  law. 
A  cardinal  rule  of  statutory  interpretation  requires  criminal  statutes  to 
be  strictly  construed  in  favor  of  the  accused'^^  and  against  the  gov- 
ernment.'^^ Second,  criminal  Hmitations  statutes  are  interpreted  liberally 
in  favor  of  repose. '^^  However,  despite  the  existence  of  these  two  maxims, 
it  is  commonly  held  that  the  words  of  a  statute  should  be  given  their 
fair  meaning,'"  and  the  statute  interpreted  in  relation  to  the  entire 
enactment  purpose.'^"* 

A  desire  to  protect  the  rights  of  the  accused  against  disadvantageous 
procedural  changes  which  could  result  in  abuse  or  attainder  may  underlie 
the  presumption  for  prospectivity.'^^  Today,  however,  statutes  of  limi- 
tations are  more  likely  to  be  liberally  rather  than  strictly  construed, '^^ 
and  as  a  result,  the  presumption  for  prospectivity  should  carry  less 
weight.  Where  there  is  a  presumption  of  prospective  application,  the 
court  may  apply  the  presumption  in  the  absence  of  clear  legislative  intent 
to  the  contrary. 

By  rotely  applying  a  presumption  for  prospective  application,  this 
approach  fails  to  address  the  victim's  right  of  legal  redress.  Although 
the  presumption  for  prospectivity  may  have  vahd  application  where  both 


129.  See  State  v.  Jones,  132  Conn.  682,  685,  47  A.2d  185,  187  (1946);  Yates  v. 
General  Motors  Acceptance  Corp.,  356  Mass.  529,  531,  254  N.E.2d  785,  786  (1969). 

130.  Holland,  708  P.2d  at  120.  See  also  United  States  v.  Wiltberger,  18  U.S.  (5 
Wheat.)  76,  94-95  (1820) 

The  rule  that  penal  laws  are  to  be  construed  strictly,  is  perhaps  not  much  less 
old  than  construction  itself.  .  .  .  The  case  must  be  a  strong  one,  indeed,  which 
would  justify  a  court  in  departing  from  the  plain  meaning  of  words,  especially, 
in  a  penal  act,  in  search  of  an  intention  which  the  words  themselves  did  not 
suggest.  To  determine  that  a  case  is  within  the  intention  of  a  statute,  its  language 
must  authorize  us  to  say  so.  It  would  be  dangerous,  indeed,  to  carry  the  principle, 
that  a  case  which  is  within  the  reason  or  mischief  of  a  statute,  is  within  its 
provisions,  so  far  as  to  punish  a  crime  not  enumerated  in  the  statute,  because 
it  is  of  equal  atrocity,  or  of  kindred  character,  with  those  which  are  enumerated. 
See  1  C.  ToRciA,  supra  note  54,  §  12. 

131.  United  States  v.  Emmons,  410  U.S.  396,  411  (1973)  ("this  being  a  criminal 
statute,  it  must  be  strictly  construd,  and  any  abiguity  must  be  resolved  in  favor  of  lenity."). 

132.  United  States  v.  Scharton,  285  U.S.  518,  522  (1932);  Waters  v.  United  States, 
328  F.2d  729,  742  (10th  Cir.   1965). 

133.  Singer  v.  United  States,  323  U.S.  338  (1945). 

134.  1  C.  ToRCiA,  supra  note  54,  §  12. 

135.  See  Munzer,  A  Theory  of  Retroactive  Legislation,  61  Tex.  L.  Rev.  425,  464- 
65  (1982).  The  author  suggests  that  retroactive  changes  in  the  statute  of  limitations  are 
impermissible  because  the  changes  carry  a  risk  of  abuse  and  attainder  and  also  because 
the  changes  are  "unlikely  to  meet  the  special  burden  of  justification  applicable  to  all 
retroactive  laws  affecting  personal  liberties."  Id. 

136.  E.  Crawford,  The  Construction  of  Statutes  §  349  (1940). 


1006  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

victim  and  accused  are  of  majority,  and  are  equally  competent  to  protect 
their  own  rights,  this  presumption  overcompensates  for  the  accused's 
perceived  disadvantages  within  the  criminal  justice  system  and  awards 
the  accused  a  decided  advantage  at  the  expense  of  the  minor  victim. 
This  is  because  prospective  application  guards  against  disadvantageous 
procedural  changes  which  operate  to  the  detriment  of  the  accused,  but 
prevents  the  victim,  an  individual  who  is  often  unaware  of  his  rights 
or  powerless  to  protect  them,  from  exercising  his  right  to  redress. '^"^ 

The  second  approach  mandates  retroactive  application  of  the  revised 
statute  in  the  absence  of  manifest  legislative  intent  to  the  contrary.  ^^* 
In  State  v.  Hodgson,^^^  the  Washington  Court  of  Appeals,  although 
recognizing  that  penal  statutes  are  to  be  strictly  construed  in  favor  of 
the  accused,  stated  that  the  strict  construction  doctrine  should  not  be 
rotely  appHed,  but  instead,  the  judiciary  should  examine  the  rationale 
behind  the  doctrine  to  determine  proper  classification  and  application 
of  the  revised  limitations  statute. ''^^  The  strict  construction  doctrine  applies 
to  penal  statutes  because  *'it  is  unjust  to  convict  a  person  without  clear 
notice  to  him  that  (1)  his  contemplated  conduct  is  unlawful,  and  (2) 
certain  penalties  will  attach  to  that  conduct. "''*•  The  effect  of  strict 
construction  is  to  raise  a  judicial  presumption  of  prospectivity.^"^^  How- 
ever, where  a  statute  relates  to  practice,  procedures  or  remedies  and 
does  not  affect  a  substantive  or  vested  right,  Washington  courts  reverse 
the  presumption,  and  apply  a  general  rule  whereby  procedural  statutes 
are  presumed  to  apply  retroactively.^'*^  Therefore,  to  determine  which 
presumption  is  applicable,  a  court  must  determine  whether  the  statute 
of  limitations  operates  as  a  substantive  right  or  merely  performs  a 
procedural  function. ^"^  The  Hodgson  court,  however,  rejected  a  strict 
substantive-procedural  classification,  finding  that  labeling  the  statute  of 
limitations  as  one  or  the  other  tends  to  obscure  rather  than  clarify  the 
law.^'*^  The  court  therefore  undertook  to  classify  the  statute  of  limitations 
based  upon  definition  and  function  rather  than  mere  label. '"^^ 


137.  See  supra  notes  24-56  and  accompanying  text. 

138.  See,  e.g.,  State  v.  Hodgson,  44  Wash.  App.  592,  722  P.2d  1336  (1986),  aff'd 
in  part,  rev'd  in  part,  and  remanded  in  part,  108  Wash.  2d  662,  740  P. 2d  848  (1987). 

139.  Id. 

140.  Hodgson,  44  Wash.  App.  at  602,  722  P.2d  at  1342. 

141.  Id.  See  Commonwealth  v.  Broughton,  257  Pa.  Super.  369,  377,  390  A.2d  1282, 
1286  (1978). 

142.  Hodgson,  44  Wash.  App.  at  602,  722  P.2d  at  1342. 

143.  Id.  See  Johnston  v.  Beneficial  Management  Corp.,  85  Wash.  2d  637,  641,  538 
P.2d  510,  514  (1975). 

144.  Hodgson,  44  Wash.  App.  at  602,  722  P.2d  at  1342. 

145.  Id. 

146.  Id. 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1007 

Emphasizing  the  fact  that  statutes  of  limitations  are  subject  to  the 
will  of  the  legislature,^'*^  the  Hodgson  court  found  that  retroactive  ap- 
plication did  not  impair  vested  or  substantial  rights,  provided  however, 
that  the  offense  was  not  time-barred  as  of  the  statute's  effective  date.*'*^ 
This  is  so  because  "the  statute  is  a  mere  regulation  of  the  remedy, 
subject  to  legislative  control,  and  does  not  become  a  vested  right  until 
the  offense  becomes  time-barred. "^"^^ 

Because  the  statute  of  limitations  approximates  a  procedural  remedy 
rather  than  a  substantive  right,  the  Hodgson  court  determined  that 
retroactive  application  did  not  violate  the  ex  post  facto  clause.  Applying 
the  equivalent  of  the  Calder  v.  Bull  test,^^^  the  court  permitted  retroactive 
application  because  increasing  the  limitation  period  neither  aggravated 
the  crime,  increased  the  punishment  nor  permitted  the  accused  to  be 
convicted  under  rules  permitting  "lesser"  testimony.'^'  In  the  absence 
of  contrary  legislative  intent,  the  presumption  of  retroactivity  applies  to 
the  revised  limitations  statute.^"  Thus,  because  the  statute  of  limitations 
is  not  substantive,  the  ex  post  facto  clause  permits  retroactive  application 
of  the  enlarged  limitations  period  in  accordance  with  the  judicial  pre- 
sumption of  retroactive  application. 

The  Hodgson  court  recognized  the  policy  considerations  underlying 
the  legislature's  extension  of  the  limitations  period. '^^  Although  failing 
to  cite  the  policy  considerations  as  a  factor  in  the  decision  permitting 
retroactive  appHcation,  the  court  at  least  recognized  the  legislature's 
intentions  in  extending  the  statute. '^"^  Thus,  although  not  premising  a 
decision  for  retroactive  application  upon  policy  considerations,  the  court 


147.  Id.  The  court  characterized  statutes  of  limitations  as  ''matters  of  legislative 
grace  .  .  .  [and]  a  surrendering  by  the  sovereign  of  its  right  to  prosecute."  Id. 

148.  Id.  Therefore,  until  the  right  to  a  dismissal  is  absolutely  vested,  the  legislature 
may  change  or  repeal  the  limitations  period.  Id.  See  also  Waters  v.  United  States,  328 
F.2d  739,  743  (10th  Cir.  1964);  Clements  v.  United  States,  266  F.2d  397,  399  (9th  Cir.), 
cert,  denied,  359  U.S.  985  (1959);  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420,  425  (2d  Cir.), 
cert,  denied.  111  U.S.  590  (1928). 

149.  Hodgson,  108  Wash.  2d  at  668,  740  P.2d  at  851. 

150.  See  supra  text  accompanying  note  80;  Calder  v.  Bull,  3  U.S.  (1  Dall.)  386, 
390  (1798). 

151.  Hodgson,  108  Wash.  2d  at  669,  740  P.2d  at  852. 

152.  Id. 

153.  Id.  at  665,  740  P. 2d  at  850.  The  court,  citing  the  legislature's  final  reports, 
noted  that  the  limitations  period  was  extended  based  upon  experience  showing  that  victims 
of  child  abuse,  due  to  fear,  lack  of  understanding  or  manipulation  by  the  offender,  often 
fail  to  report  the  abuse  within  the  shorter  limitations  period.  Although  failing  to  cite  the 
policy  considerations  as  a  factor  in  the  decision  permitting  retroactive  application,  the 
court  at  least  recognized  the  legislature's  intentions  in  extending  the  statute. 

154.  Id.  at  666,  740  P. 2d  at  850. 


1008  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

nonetheless  adopted  a  position  which  maximizes  the  protection  of  the 
child  abuse  victim. 

In  the  final  approach,  the  legislature's  intent  is  not  manifestly  ex- 
pressed, and  as  a  result,  the  court  resorts  to  judicial  presumptions  and 
the  judiciary's  perception  of  legislative  intent  to  determine  the  revised 
statute's  application. 

The  mere  fact  that  the  legislature  extends  the  statute  of  limitations 
may  support  a  presumption  for  retroactive  application.  ^^^  Where  the 
legislature  fails  to  clearly  express  an  intention  as  to  the  application  of 
the  revised  statute,  a  court  may  look  to  the  various  steps  in  the  enactment 
process  to  resolve  any  ambiguity. ^^^  In  Commonwealth  v.  Bargeron,  the 
Massachusetts  Supreme  Court  applied  a  two-step  test  to  determine  whether 
the  revised  Umitations  statute  could  be  retroactively  applied. '^^  Noting 
that  retroactive  statutes  are  not  per  se  unconstitutional,^^^  the  court 
applied  the  Calder  v.  Bull  test,*^^  determining  that  extension  of  the  statute 
merely  extends  the  time  in  which  the  government  may  prosecute,  and 
as  such,  extension  did  not  violate  the  ex  post  facto  prohibition.^^  The 
court  noted  the  absence  of  any  express  language  evidencing  the  legis- 
lature's intent  for  retroactive  application.^^'  The  court  noted  however, 
that  the  omission  did  not  foreclose  retrospective  appUcation.'^^  Retroactive 
statutes  are  unconstitutional  only  when,  on  a  balancing  of  opposing 
considerations,  the  statute  is  unreasonable.'^^  A  court  may  consider  '*the 
precise  evil  which  is  targeted  in  legislation  under  review."'^  The  intent 
of  the  legislature,  ascertained  "from  all  the  words  construed  by  the 
ordinary  and  approved  usage  of  the  language,  considered  in  connection 
with  the  cause  of  its  enactment,  the  mischief  or  imperfection  to  be 
remedied  and  the  main  object  to  be  accompHshed,  to  the  end  that  the 


155.  See,  e.g..  Commonwealth  v.  Bargeron,  402  Mass.  589,  524  N.E.2d  829  (1988). 

156.  Commonwealth  v.  Collett,  387  Mass.  424,  433,  439  N.E.2d  1223,  1229  (1982). 

157.  Bargeron,  402  Mass.  at  590,  524  N.E.2d  at  830.  Although  the  defendant  was 
not  charged  with  sexual  abuse  of  a  minor,  the  court's  reasoning  was  applied  to  two  other 
cases  decided  on  the  same  date,  both  of  which  involved  child  sex  abuse  charges  and 
appUcation  of  the  revised  Umitations  period. 

158.  League  v.  Texas,  184  U.S.  156,  161  (1902). 

159.  See  supra  text  accompanying  note  80;  Calder  v.  Bull,  3  U.S.  (1  Dall.)  386, 
390  (1798). 

160.  Bargeron,  402  Mass.  at  591,  524  N.E.2d  at  830. 

161.  Id.  at  592-93,  524  N.B.2d  at  831. 

162.  Id.  at  592,  524  N.E.2d  at  831.  See  Commonwealth  v.  Greenberg,  339  Mass. 
557,  578-79,  160  N.E.2d  181,  195  (1959). 

163.  See  Usery  v.  Turner  Elkhorn  Mining  Co.,  428  U.S.  1,  14-20  (1976);  American 
Mfrs.  Mut.  Ins.  Co.  v.  Commissioner  of  Ins.,  374  Mass.  181,  189-90,  372  N.E.2d  520, 
525  (1978). 

164.  Bargeron,  402  Mass.  at  593,  524  N.E.2d  at  832.  See  Commonwealth  v.  Collett, 
387  Mass.  424,  432,  439  N.E.2d  1223,  1228-29  (1982). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1009 

purpose  of  its  framers  may  be  effectuated,  "^^^  determines  the  reason- 
ableness of  retroactive  application  and  the  legislature's  intent.  Thus,  the 
court  in  Bargeron  held  there  was  no  constitutional  or  statutory  barrier 
to  retroactive  application  of  the  revised  statute. '^^ 

The  court  in  Bargeron  concluded  that  the  mere  extension  of  the 
limitations  period  for  child  sex  abuse  offenses  furnished  adequate  in- 
dication of  the  legislature's  intention  to  permit  retroactive  application 
of  the  revised  statute. ^^"^  The  court  reasoned  that  the  Massachusetts 
legislature,  recognizing  the  delays  associated  with  a  child's  report  of 
sexual  abuse,  may  have  sought  to  accommodate  such  delays  by  extending 
the  Hmitations  period. ^^^  The  court,  lauding  the  legislature  for  addressing 
the  child  sexual  abuse  issue,  determined  that  ''it  is  not  reasonable  to 
assume  that  the  Legislature  intended  to  delay  the  application  of  the  new 
.  .  .  statute  of  hmitations  which  would  eventuate  if  the  amendment 
appUed  only  to  crimes  occurring  after  its  enactment. "'^^  Thus,  the  court 
reasoned  that  retroactive  apphcation  best  reflected  the  legislature's  in- 
tentions in  passing  the  revised  statute.  Moreover,  the  court  buttressed 
the  decision  in  favor  of  retroactive  application  by  noting  that  the  statute 
of  hmitations  is  procedural,  and  as  such,  the  judicial  presumption  of 
retroactivity  which  apphes  to  non-substantive  rights  permits  retroactive 
application.  *^°  Thus,  although  the  legislature  omitted  language  requiring 
retroactive  application,  the  court  found  sufficient  basis  to  permit  ret- 
rospective application  through  the  use  of  a  judicial  presumption  for 
retroactivity,  and  the  mere  act  of  the  legislature  extending  the  limitations 
period. 

IV.    The  Proposal:  A  Uniform  Approach  to  the  Interpretation 
AND  Application  of  a  Revised  Limitations  Statute 

Where  the  legislature  acts  to  extend  the  criminal  statute  of  limitations 
for  child  sex  abuse  offenses,  strong  pohcy  considerations  compel  a 
presumption  of  retroactivity,  absent  manifest  legislative  intent  to  the 
contrary.  This  Note  proposes  that  courts  adopt  an  approach  which 
realistically  balances  the  needs  of  both  offender  and  victim  in  light  of 
the  victim's  inability  to  effectively  protect  his  or  her  legal  rights.  Further, 
this  Note  suggests  that  retroactive  apphcation  of  an  enlarged  statute  of 
Hmitations  does  not  violate  the  ex  post  facto  prohibition,  even  if  applied 


165.  Hanlon  v.  Rollins,  286  Mass.  444,  447,  190  N.E.  606,  608  (1934). 

166.  Bargeron,  402  Mass.  at  594,  524  N.E.2d  at  832. 

167.  Id.  at  591-94,  524  N.E.2d  at  831-32. 

168.  Id.  at  593,  524  N.E.2d  at  831-32. 

169.  Id.  at  594,  524  N.E.2d  at  832. 

170.  Id. 


1010  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

to  offenses  "time-barred"  at  the  extension  date.  The  difficulty  of  child 
victims  in  obtaining  legal  redress,  the  need  to  afford  the  child  victim 
a  day  in  court,  and  the  need  to  prevent  offenders  from  escaping  pros- 
ecution, collectively  compel  the  application  of  a  judicial  presumption  of 
retroactivity.  Moreover,  the  mere  fact  that  the  legislature  has  addressed 
the  issue  by  extending  the  statute  of  limitations  may  be  construed  as 
intending  retroactive  application.^^' 

A.     Uniform  Approach:  A  Presumption  of  Retroactivity 

Retroactive  application  of  a  legislatively  enlarged  criminal  limitations 
period  does  not  violate  the  constitutional  prohibition  against  ex  post 
facto  laws.  The  majority  of  jurisdictions  addressing  the  issue  held  that, 
for  purposes  of  ex  post  facto  analysis,  the  statute  of  limitations  is 
procedural. '^^  The  statute  of  Umitations,  in  criminal  contexts,  is  an  act 
of  legislative  grace'^^  and  a  surrendering  of  the  sovereign's  right  to 
prosecute. '^^  At  common  law,  criminal  limitations  periods  were  nonex- 
istent.'^^ The  statute  of  limitations  is  clearly  a  reflection  of  pubHc  will 
and  a  matter  of  grace  at  least  until  such  time  as  the  limitations  period 
expires. '^^  In  Chase  Securities  Corp.  v.  Donaldson, ^'^^  the  Supreme  Court 
expounded  upon  the  origin  and  application  of  statutes  of  limitations, 
stating  that: 

[s]tatutes  of  limitation  find  their  justification  in  necessity  and 
convenience  rather  than  in  logic.  They  represent  expedients,  rather 
than  principles.  They  are  practical  and  pragmatic  devices  to  spare 
the  courts  from  litigation  of  stale  claims,  and  the  citizen  from 


171.  See  Bargeron,  402  Mass.  589,  524  N.E.2d  829  (1988).  "[I]t  is  not  reasonable 
to  assume  that  the  Legislature  intended  to  delay  the  application  of  the  new  ten-year  statute 
of  limitations  which  would  eventuate  if  the  amendment  applied  only  to  crimes  occurring 
after  its  enactment."  Id.  at  593,  524  N.E.2d  at  832. 

172.  See,  e.g..  United  States  ex  rel.  Massarella  v.  Elrod,  682  F.2d  688,  689  (7th 
Cir.),  cert,  denied,  460  U.S.  1037  (1982);  Clements  v.  United  States,  266  F.2d  397,  399 
(9th  Cir.),  cert,  denied,  359  U.S.  985  (1959);  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420,  425- 
26  (2d  Cir.),  cert,  denied,  277  U.S.  590  (1928);  State  v.  Ferrie,  243  La.  416,  144  So.  2d 
380  (1962);  State  v.  Merolla,  686  P.2d  244  (Nev.  1984);  Rose  v.  State,  716  S.W.2d  162, 
163  (Tex.App.  1986).  But  see,  e.g.,  Stoner  v.  State,  418  So.  2d  171,  178  (Ala.  Crim. 
App.  1982)  (statute  of  limitations  in  criminal  context  vests  substantive  right);  Rubin  v. 
State,  390  So.  2d  322  (Fla.  1980)  (statute  of  limitations  vests  substantive  right  in  criminal 
context). 

173.  State  v.  Hodgson,  108  Wash.  2d  662,  667,  740  P.2d  848,  851  (1987). 

174.  Id. 

175.  1  C.  ToRCiA,  supra  note  54,  §  90. 

176.  See  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420,  425  (2d  Cir.),  cert,  denied.  111  U.S. 
590  (1928). 

177.  325  U.S.  304  (1945). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1011 

being  put  to  his  defense  after  memories  have  faded,  witnesses 
have  died  or  disappeared,  and  evidence  has  been  lost.  They  are 
by  definition  arbitrary,  and  their  operation  does  not  discriminate 
between  the  just  and  the  unjust  claim,  or  the  [a]voidable  and 
unavoidable  delay.  They  have  come  into  the  law  not  through 
the  judicial  process  but  through  legislation.  They  represent  a 
public  pohcy  about  the  privilege  to  litigate.  Their  shelter  has 
never  been  regarded  as  what  now  is  called  a  "fundamental"  right 
or  what  used  to  be  called  a  "natural"  right  of  the  individual. 
He  may,  of  course,  have  the  protection  of  the  policy  while  it 
exists,  but  the  history  of  pleas  of  limitation  shows  them  to  be 
good  only  by  legislative  grace  and  to  be  subject  to  a  relatively 
large  degree  of  legislative  control. '^^ 

However,  mere  categorization  of  the  statute  of  limitations  as  sub- 
stantive or  procedural  sidesteps  the  central  question  of  the  enlarged 
limitations  period's  effect. '^^  Instead,  courts  should  look  to  the  nature 
and  function  of  criminal  statutes  of  limitations.'^*^  Ex  post  facto  laws, 
as  pronounced  in  Calder  v.  Bull,^^^  are  those  laws  which  (1)  make  an 
act  criminal  which  was  innocent  when  done;  (2)  aggravate  a  crime  or 
make  it  greater  than  when  committed;  (3)  increase  the  punishment;  or 
(4)  alter  the  rules  of  evidence  and  require  lesser  or  different  evidence 
to  convict  than  that  required  at  the  time  of  the  offense. '^^  The  statute 
of  limitations'  extension  performs  none  of  these  impermissibles.  The 
statute's  extension  merely  extends  the  time  in  which  prosecution  is  per- 
missible. As  such,  the  legislature  presumably  could  free  an  offense  of 
any  limitations  period  or  could  provide  for  successive  extensions  of  finite 
periods. '^^  However,  statutes  should  not  be  given  a  construction  which 
destroys  or  impairs  a  vested  right. '^"^  Obviously,  when  the  legislature 
extends  the  statutory  period  prior  to  the  expiration  of  the  original  period, 
the  accused  has  not  obtained  a  vested  right  to  be  free  from  prosecution. 
If  expressly  directed,  the  legislature  may  even  apply  the  extended  Hm- 


178.  M  at  314  (citation  omitted). 

179.  Hodgson,  108  Wash.  2d  662,  667,  740  P.2d  848,  851  (1987).  See  also  State 
V.  Freeh  Funeral  Home,  185  N.J.  Super  385,  389-90,  448  A.2d  1037,  1039  (quoting  Busik 
V.  Levine,  63  N.J.  351,  364,  307  A. 2d  571,  578  (1973)  ("it  is  simplistic  to  assume  that 
all  law  is  divided  neatly  between  'substance'  and  'procedure.'  A  rule  of  procedure  may 
have  an  impact  upon  the  substantive  result  and  be  no  less  a  rule  of  procedure  on  that 
account.  .  .  ."). 

180.  Hodgson,  108  Wash.  2d  at  667,  740  P.2d  at  851. 

181.  3  U.S.  (1  Dall.)  386  (1798). 

182.  Id.  at  390. 

183.  People  v.  Smith,  171  Cal.  App.  3d  997,  1003,  217  Cal.  Rptr.  634,  637  (1985). 

184.  E.  Crawford,  supra  note  136,  §  278. 


1012  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

itations  period  to  revive  "time-barred"  claims. ^^^  The  extension  therefore, 
does  not  divest  the  accused  of  a  vested  right.  Thus,  neither  the  Calder 
ex  post  facto  test,  nor  the  vested  rights  theory  prohibit  retroactive 
application  of  the  enlarged  period. 

The  strict  construction  doctrine  is  frequently  utilized  as  a  judicial 
procedure,  limiting  retroactive  application  unless  clearly  required  by 
express  language  or  necessary  implication. ^^^  Strict  construction  of  penal 
statutes  is  favored  because  the  legislature  owes  the  citizenry  a  duty  to 
clearly  state  those  acts  for  the  commission  of  which  a  citizen  may  lose 
his  life  or  liberty. ^^"^  Although  the  citizenry  may  rely  upon  existing 
elemental  definitions  or  proof  requirements, ^^^  the  accused  cannot  rea- 
sonably develop  a  reliance  or  expectation  as  to  the  time  limit  for  pros- 
ecution. Even  if  developed,  is  there  any  societal  interest  to  be  served 
by  protecting  the  reliance?  When  the  accused  has  committed  all  of  the 
elements  of  an  offense,  the  statute  of  limitations  functions  only  to  restrain 
prosecution  within  legislatively  prescribed  temporal  limits.  Logic  rejects 
the  argument  that  altering  the  statute  of  limitations  affects  the  expec- 
tations of  the  citizenry  as  to  the  lawfulness  of  their  conduct.  At  most, 
only  the  perpetrator  develops  a  reliance  upon  the  statute  of  limitations, 
purposefully  evading  detection  until  the  legislatively  prescribed  period 
expires.  Numerous  jurisdictions  recognize  this  phenomena  and  by  statute, 
prevent  the  tolling  of  the  Hmitations  period  during  the  period  when  the 
accused  is  out  of  state  or  beyond  the  sovereign's  jurisdiction.'^^ 

The  statute  of  limitations  serves  as  a  buffer,  preventing  the  expen- 
diture of  judicial  resources  where  logically,  evidentiary  items  such  as 
testimony  and  documents,  have  disappeared,  grown  stale,  or  been  de- 
stroyed, and  can  no  longer  perform  the  necessary  evidentiary  function.'^ 
Thus,  at  worst,  extension  or  elimination  of  the  limitations  bar  results 
in  reduced  judicial  efficiency  by  forcing  the  court  to  determine  the 
validity  of  a  prosecution,  rather  than  rotely  applying  the  limitations 
period  to  bar  the  same.  Granted,  the  accused  must  be  protected  from 
the  retroactive  application  of  a  definitional  alteration  of  the  criminal 


185.  See  infra  notes  195-246  and  accompanying  text. 

186.  Kopczynski  v.  County  of  Camden,  2  N.J.  419,  424,  66  A.2d  882,  884  (1949) 
"[wjords  in  a  statute  ought  not  to  have  a  retrospective  operation  unless  they  are  so  clear, 
strong  and  imperative  that  no  other  meaning  can  be  annexed  to  them,  or  unless  the  intent 
of  the  Legislature  cannot  otherwise  be  satisfied.");  N.  Singer,  Sutherland  Stat.  Con- 
struction §  41.04  (4th  Ed.  1986). 

187.  N.  Singer,  supra  note  186,  §  59.03. 

188.  For  a  discussion  of  the  citizen's  reliance  interest  and  the  need  to  protect  such 
interests,  see  Note,  Retroactive  Application  Of  Statutes:  Protection  Of  Reliance  Interests, 
40  Me.  L.  Rev.  183  (1988). 

189.  1  C.  ToRCiA,  supra  note  54,  §  94. 

190.  See  United  States  v.  Kubrick,  444  U.S.   Ill,  117  (1979). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1013 

elements. ^^'  However,  retroactive  application  of  the  enlarged  statutory 
period  does  not  prevent  the  citizenry  from  making  everyday  decisions 
with  reasonable  certainty,  and  does  not  alter  the  definition  of  unlawful 
conduct. 

The  strict  construction  doctrine  provides  that  penal  statutes  should 
not  apply  retroactively  without  clear  notice  that  one's  contemplated 
conduct  is  unlawful  and  that  certain  penalties  will  attach. '^^  The  strict 
construction  doctrine  is  not  an  impediment  to  retroactive  application  of 
a  legislatively  enlarged  statute  of  limitations  because  retroactive  appli- 
cation of  the  enlarged  period  neither  affects  the  definition  nor  the  penalty 
for  the  crime. '^^  Moreover,  retroactive  application  does  not  breach  ex 
post  facto  prohibitions  because  extending  the  period  prior  to  prosecution 
neither  aggravates  the  crime,  increases  the  punishment  nor  alters  the 
rules  of  legal  testimony  necessary  for  conviction. ^^"^  Thus,  there  are  no 
constitutional  or  doctrinal  barriers  to  retroactive  application  of  a  leg- 
islatively-enlarged limitations  period. 

B.    Reviving  Time-Barred  Claims 

Courts  which  permit  retroactive  application  of  an  enlarged  criminal 
limitations  period  deny  application  to  offenses  "time-barred"  at  the 
extension. '^^  However,  revival  of  a  time-barred  offense  does  not  offend 
ex  post  facto  prohibitions.  The  ex  post  facto  prohibition  has  long  been 
confined  to  the  criminal  context'^^  but  has  never  been  defined  with  great 
clarity.  Instead,  vague  notions  of  "justice  and  fair  play"^^^  are  used  to 
support  judicial  restraints  on  perceived  ex  post  facto  legislation.  Courts 
suggest  that  a  right,  if  either  "substantial"  or  "vested,"  may  not  be 
altered  after  the  fact.*^^ 

Nineteenth  century  treatise  writers  like  Judge  Cooley  first  coined  the 
notion  of  "substantial  rights. "^^^  Cooley  opined  that  legislatures  may 


191.  Alteration  of  the  definitional  elements  of  the  crime  is  a  classic  example  of  ex 
post  facto  legislation  and  would  be  prohibited. 

192.  Commonwealth  v.  Broughton,  257  Pa.  Super.  369,  377,  390  A.2d  1282,  1286 
(1978). 

193.  State  v.  Hodgson,  44  Wash.  App.  592,  603,  722  P.2d  1336,  1342  (1986)  aff'd 
in  part,  rev'd  in  part,  and  remanded  in  part,  108  Wash.  2d  662,  740  P. 2d  848  (1987). 

194.  See  United  States  ex  rel.  Massarella  v.  Elrod,  682  F.2d  688  (7th  Cir.   1982), 
cert,  denied,  460  U.S.   1037  (1983). 

195.  See,  e.g..  People  v.  Smith,  171  Cal.  App.  3d  997,  217  Cal.  Rptr.  634  (1985); 
State  V.  Hodgson,  108  Wash.  2d  662,  740  P.2d  848  (1987). 

196.  See  Note  Ex  Post  Facto  Limitations  on  Legislative  Power,  73  Mich.  L.  Rev. 
1491,  1492  n.4  (1975)  [hereinafter  Ex  Post  Facto  Limitations]. 

197.  See  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420,  425-26  (2d.  Cir.),  cert,  denied.  111 
U.S.  590  (1928). 

198.  See,  e.g.,  Kring  v.  Missouri,  107  U.S.  221,  232  (1882). 

199.  See  T.  Cooley,  Constitutional  Limitations  272  (1868). 


1014  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

prescribe  different  forms  of  criminal  procedure  but  may  not  dispense 
with  any  substantial  protections  which  existing  criminal  law  affords  the 
accused. ^^  This  vague  notion  of  a  substantial  right  "vested"  in  the 
defendant,  unlawfully  taken  away  by  legislative  change,  formed  the 
foundation  for  the  Supreme  Court's  decision  in  Kring  v.  Missouri .^^^  Ex 
post  facto  analysis  and  the  propriety  of  retroactive  application  require 
consideration  of  three  factors:  reliance,  legislative  function,  and  potential 
for  legislative  abuse. ^°^  Ex  post  facto  legislation  is  objectionable  because 
purportedly,  citizens  rely  upon  the  law  currently  in  effect  to  shape  their 
conduct.  Certainly,  this  premise  is  supportable  with  respect  to  the  elements 
of  a  crime.  However,  few  alleged  criminals  know  the  law,  much  less 
rely  on  it.^^^  Certainly,  ignorance  of  the  law  will  not  excuse  conduct  in 
violation  of  current  statutes. ^^  Reliance  should  be  protected  only  if 
reasonable.  If  an  individual  commits  a  crime,  the  mere  passage  of  time 
should  not  endow  the  individual  with  a  vested  right  to  escape  punishment 
for  the  alleged  wrong.  An  alleged  defendant  can  not  reasonably  rely 
upon  the  statute  of  limitations  to  shelter  his  wrongful  conduct,  and 
society  owes  him  no  such  guarantee. 

Ex  post  facto  laws  are  also  undesirable  because  they  fail  to  serve 
their  primary  purpose,  deterrence. ^^^  This  concept  of  ex  post  facto  laws 
assumes  that  criminal  legislation  is  promulgated  primarily  for  deterrent 
effect.  However,  statutes  of  limitations  are  mere  procedural  limitations 
and  purport  to  serve  no  deterrent  purpose.  The  statute  of  limitations 
has  no  measurable  impact  on  allegedly  criminal  behavior,  neither  en- 
couraging nor  deterring  such  conduct. 

Finally,  ex  post  facto  laws  are  objectionable  because  they  represent 
a  potential  for  legislative  abuse. ^^^  No  legislative  vindictiveness  exists 
where  the  legislature  extends  the  statute  of  limitations,  unless  directed 
principally  to  one  individual.  Unlike  the  enactment  of  legislation  directed 
specifically  toward  a  single  individual  or  group,  extension  of  child  sexual 
abuse  limitation  periods  neither  suggests  nor  represents  an  abuse  of 
legislative  process. 

In  the  civil  context,  courts  have  upheld  the  legislature's  power  to 
revive  time-barred  actions. ^^^  In  Chase  Securities  Corp.  v.  Donaldson, ^^^ 

200.  Id. 

201.  107  U.S.  221,  232  (1882). 

202.  Ex  Post  Facto  Limitations,  supra  note  196,  at  1497-1501. 

203.  Id.  at  1497. 

204.  See,  e.g..  United  States  v.  Casson,  434  F.2d  415,  422  (D.C.  Cir.  1970). 

205.  Ex  Post  Facto  Limitations,  supra  note  196,  at  1498. 

206.  Id.  at  1500-01. 

207.  See.  e.g..  Chase  Sec.  Corp.  v.  Donaldson,  325  U.S.  304  (1945);  Campbell  v. 
Holt,  115  U.S.  620  (1885);  Liebig  v.  Superior  Court,  209  Cal.  App.  3d  828,  257  Cal. 
Rptr.  574  (1989). 

208.  325  U.S.  304  (1945). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1015 

the  Supreme  Court  ruled  that  revival  of  a  personal  cause  of  action, 
where  the  lapse  of  time  did  not  vest  the  party  with  title  to  real  or 
personal  property,  did  not  offend  the  fourteenth  amendment. ^°^  Statutes 
of  limitations  are  arbitrary,  and  their  shelter  has  never  been  recognized 
as  a  fundamental  right. ^'°  Furthermore,  statutes  of  limitations  are  meas- 
ures of  legislative  grace,  subject  to  legislative  control.^'^  "[S]tatutes  of 

Hmitation  go  to  matters  of  remedy,  not  to  destruction  of  fundamental 
rights.  "212 

In  Campbell  v.  Holt,^^^  the  progeny  of  Chase  Securities,  the  Supreme 
Court  found  that  the  right  to  defeat  a  debt  by  the  statute  of  limitations 
was  not  a  vested  right,  and  the  legislature's  determination  that  time 
shall  be  no  bar  did  not  violate  any  right. ^'"^  Man  has  no  ''property  in 
the  bar  of  the  statute  as  a  defense  to  his  promise  to  pay."^^^  '*It  is  no 
natural  right,  .  .  .  but  the  creation  of  conventional  law."^^^  No  right  is 
destroyed  when  the  law  restores  a  remedy  which  has  been  lost.^^^ 

Similarly,  logic  suggests  that  revival  of  the  statute  of  limitations  in 
the  criminal  context  violates  no  constitutional  barriers.  The  majority  of 
jurisdictions  have  found  the  statute  of  limitations  to  be  procedural,  not 
substantive. 2^^  However,  courts  have  suggested  that  the  defendant  acquires 
a  right  not  to  be  prosecuted  when  the  statute  expires. ^^^  Supposedly,  the 
defendant's  full  liberty  has  been  restored  in  a  manner  analogous  to  the 
acquisition  of  property  through  adverse  possession. ^^^  The  distinction 
between  extension  and  revival  in  the  criminal  context  can  only  be  justified 
on  the  premise  that  only  when  a  right  to  prosecute  is  revived  does  an 
act  which  could  not  have  been  punished  without  the  statute  become 
punishable. 22^  Such  reasoning  begs  the  question  and  only  tortures  an 
initially  weak  definition  of  the  ex  post  facto  prohibition. ^^^ 

If  the  statute  of  limitations  were  classified  as  substantive,  a  pro- 
hibition against  revival  would  mold  a  consistent,  though  improper,  train 


209.  Id.  at  311-12. 

210.  Id.  at  314. 
1\\.  Id. 

212.  Id. 

213.  115  U.S.  620  (1885). 

214.  Id.  at  628. 

215.  Id.  at  629. 

216.  Id.  The  court  noted  that  the  phrase  "vested  rights"  is  not  found  in  the 
Constitution.  Id.  at  628.  The  Court's  opinion  suggests  that  the  ex  post  facto  prohibition 
was  designed  principally  to  protect  constitutionally  guaranteed  rights.  Id.  at  629. 

217.  Id. 

218.  See  supra  note  172. 

219.  See  supra  notes  120  through  170  and  accompanying  text. 

220.  See  Ex  Post  Facto  Limitations,  supra  note  196,  at  1512  n.78. 

221.  Id. 
111.  Id. 


1016  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

of  logic.  If  the  statute  of  limitations  is  initially  substantive,  then  the  ex 
post  facto  prohibition  should  prevent  retroactive  appHcation,  and  revival 
is  impossible  from  the  onset.  However,  as  noted,  classification  of  the 
statute  of  limitations  as  substantive  is  arbitrary  and  decidedly  improper. 

The  majority  of  jurisdictions  classify  the  statute  of  limitations  as 
procedural. ^^^  However,  magically,  courts  hold  that,  upon  expiration  of 
the  right  to  prosecute,  the  statute  of  limitations  vests  the  defendant  with 
a  substantive  right.  How  can  a  purely  procedural  device  suddenly  bestow 
upon  the  defendant  a  substantive  right?  An  example  will  expose  the 
inconsistent  and  illogical  nature  of  the  reasoning.  Assume  the  existence 
of  a  two  year  statute  of  limitations.  X  commits  a  crime  on  December 
30,  1984.  Y  commits  a  crime  on  January  1,  1985.  On  December  31, 
1986,  the  legislature  aboUshes  the  statute  of  limitations  and  decrees 
retroactive  application.  The  time-barred  theory  would  hold  that  X  could 
not  be  prosecuted  while  Y  could. ^^"^  Why  should  X  have  a  substantive 
right  to  avoid  prosecution  while  Y  does  not,  when  within  a  two  day 
time  span,  both  committed  the  same  offense?  Either  the  statute  of 
limitations  is  procedural  or  substantive,  but  it  is  no  chameleon!  Weak 
justifications  couched  in  terms  of  offending  '*our  instinctive  feelings  of 
justice  and  fair  play"^^^  explain  little  and  do  not  justify  the  transfor- 
mation. 

If  the  courts  are  attempting  to  protect  the  defendant's  reliance  on 
the  statute  of  limitations  which  existed  at  the  time  the  crime  was  com- 
mitted, then  the  ex  post  facto  prohibition  should  prohibit  not  only 
revival,  but  extension  as  well.  In  Kring  v.  Missouri ^^^^  the  Supreme  Court 
concluded  that  the  ex  post  facto  prohibition  should  apply  to  all  changes 
enhancing  the  position  of  the  state  in  criminal  trials  at  the  expense  of 
the  defendant. ^^^  However,  in  Thompson  v.  Utah,^^^  the  Supreme  Court 
narrowed  the  application  of  the  Kring,  concluding  that  changes  in  criminal 
procedure  could  be,  but  are  not  necessarily,  ex  post  facto. ^^^  The  Court 
held  that  the  defendant  had  a  right  to  a  twelve  person  jury  trial  at  the 
time  of  his  offense  and  that  right  could  not  be  taken  from  him  at  a 
second  trial. ^^°  The  logical  implication  of  the  decision  is  that  rights  vest 


223.  See  supra  note  172. 

224.  The  substantive  rights  theory  would  hold  that  the  revised  statute  could  not 
apply  retroactively. 

225.  See  Falter  v.  United  States,  23  F.2d  420,  426  (2d  Cir.),  cert,  denied,  277  U.S. 
590  (1928). 

226.  107  U.S.  221  (1882). 

227.  Id.  at  232. 

228.  170  U.S.  343  (1898). 

229.  Id.  at  352. 

230.  Id. 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1017 

in  the  defendant  upon  the  commission  of  the  offense.  However,  sub- 
sequent Supreme  Court  decisions  suggest  that  the  decision  in  Thompson 
did  not  limit  the  power  of  the  legislature  to  make  changes  in  "non- 
constitutionaF'  procedural  rights. ^^'  The  determination  whether  a  non- 
constitutional  right  could  be  a  "substantial  right"  was  left  unresolved. ^^^ 

If,  as  suggested  by  the  Thompson  decision,  the  ex  post  facto  pro- 
hibition is  designed  to  protect  constitutional  rights  and  not  non-consti- 
tutional rights,^"  then  clearly  the  defendant's  right  to  avoid  prosecution 
cannot  rise  to  the  level  of  a  constitutionally  guaranteed  right.  Assuming 
the  ex  post  facto  prohibition  is  designed  to  protect  the  defendant's 
reliance  interest,  the  defendant  is  in  effect  alleging  he  acted  on  the 
premise  that  the  prosecution  would  face  certain  obstacles  which  were 
subsequently  removed.  Thus,  the  interest  the  defendant  wants  elevated 
to  the  level  of  a  constitutionally  guaranteed  right  is  a  dubious  interest 
in  avoiding  prosecution  after  committing  a  criminal  offense.^^"* 

Revival  of  a  cause  of  action  is  an  extreme  exercise  of  legislative 
power^^^  and  should  be  done  only  in  rare  circumstances.  Some  procedural 
rules  should  not  be  applied  retroactively. ^^^  Ideally,  a  court  should  balance 
the  state's  public  policy  and  interest  in  prosecution  against  the  defendant's 
right  to  a  technical  defense.  Rather  than  a  prophylactic  rule  against 
retroactive  application,  revival  should  be  permitted  unless  the  rule  was 
widely  relied  upon,  the  revised  rule  cannot  serve  its  purpose  if  retroactively 
appHed,  or  a  vindictive  legislative  motive  pervades. ^^^ 

In  Liebig  v.  Superior  Court  of  Napa  County ^^^^  the  California  Court 
of  Appeals  permitted  the  revival  of  plaintiff's  time-barred  tort  action 
for  sexual  molestation  against  her  grandfather. ^^^  Holding  that  "vested 


231.  See,  e.g.,  Beazell  v.  Ohio,  269  U.S.  167  (1925)  (upholding  change  permitting 
judicial  discretion  in  granting  separate  trials);  Mallett  v.  North  CaroUna,  181  U.S.  589 
(1901)  (upheld  statute  permitting  state  to  appeal  grant  of  new  trial);  Thompson  v.  Missouri, 
171  U.S.  380  (1898)  (defendant  had  no  vested  right  in  rule  of  evidence  prior  to  passage 
of  Missouri  statute). 

232.  Beazell,  269  U.S.  at  171.  The  court  noted  that  "[j]ust  what  alterations  of 
procedure  will  be  held  to  be  of  sufficient  moment  to  transgress  the  constitutional  prohibition 
cannot  be  embraced  within  a  formula  or  stated  in  a  general  proposition.  The  distinction 
is  one  of  degree."  Id. 

233.  For  example,  the  prohibition  may  protect  constitutionally  guaranteed  rights 
such  as  the  right  to  a  jury  trial  in  a  criminal  proceeding. 

234.  Ex  Post  Facto  Limitations,  supra  note  149,  at  1513. 

235.  People  v.  Robinson,  140  111.  App.  3d  29,  ,  487  N.E.2d  1264,  1266 

(1986);  Hopkins  v.  Lincoln  Trust  Co.,  233  N.Y.  213,  213,  135  N.E.  267,  267  (1922). 

236.  For  example,  those  rules  upon  which  the  defendant  may  reasonably  rely,  and 
which  directly  shape  his  conduct.  For  example,  the  interspousal  testimonial  privilege. 

237.  See  Ex  Post  Facto  Limitations,  supra  note  149,  at  1513-16. 

238.  208  Cal.  App.  3d  828,  257  Cal.  Rptr.  574  (1989). 

239.  Id.  at  ,  257  Cal.  Rptr.  at  578. 


1018  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:989 

rights"  are  not  immune  from  retroactive  laws  where  an  important  state 
interest  is  at  stake,  the  court  found  that  maximizing,  for  as  expansive 
a  period  of  time  as  possible,  the  sexual  abuse  claims  of  minor  plaintiffs 
was  an  overriding  state  interest. ^"^^  Similarly,  in  the  criminal  context,  the 
state's  interest  in  prosecuting  and  punishing  child  sexual  abusers  overrides 
defendant's  interest  in  freedom  from  prosecution  and  permits  the  revival 
of  time-barred  actions.  In  Chase  Securities  Corp.  v.  Donaldson, ^^  the 
Supreme  Court  noted  that  a  multitude  of  cases  have  recognized  the 
power  of  the  legislature  to  call  a  liability  into  being  where  there  was 
none  before,  if  the  circumstances  were  such  as  to  appeal  with  some 
strength  to  the  prevailing  views  of  justice  and  if  the  obstacle  in  the  way 
of  the  creation  seemed  small. ^'^^  Thus,  where  the  state  interest  is  great, 
the  legislature  may  revive  a  time-barred  action.  However,  revival  should 
not  be  presumed  and  should  only  be  permitted  where  the  legislature 
expressly  prescribes  such  application. 

Courts  frequently  rely  on  the  Fourteenth  Amendment  of  the  United 
States  Constitution^"^^  to  forbid  revival  of  a  time  barred  claim. ^"^  However, 
the  Supreme  Court  in  both  Campbell  v.  Holt,^'^^  and  Chase  Securities 
Corp.  V.  Donaldson^'^  determined  that  revival  of  an  action  not  vesting 
a  real  or  personal  property  right  does  not  offend  the  fourteenth  amend- 
ment. How  can  an  alleged  defendant  obtain  a  vested  right  to  be  free 
from  prosecution  when  he  commits  an  act  criminal  at  the  time  of 
performance?  To  justify  this  conclusion  for  the  reason  that  the  defen- 
dant's act  could  not  have  been  punished  but  for  the  statute  ignores 
logic,  escapes  reason  and  is  but  an  exercise  in  semantic  circumlocution. 
The  state's  interest  in  prosecuting  child  sex  abusers  overrides  any  "vested 
substantial  right"  the  defendant  may  have  acquired. 


240.  Id. 

241.  325  U.S.  304  (1945). 

242.  Id.  at  315. 

243.  The  amendment  provides  in  pertinent  part  that,  "nor  shall  any  State  deprive 
any  person  of  Hfe,  Uberty,  or  property,  without  due  process  of  law.  .  ."  U.S.  Const. 
amend.  XIV,  §  1. 

244.  See,  e.g..  Board  of  Education  v.  Blodgett,  155  111.  441,  40  N.E.  1025  (1895); 
Sanchez  v.  Access.  Associates,  179  111.  App.  3d  961,  535  N.E.2d  27  (1989);  Markley  v. 
Kavanagh,  140  111.  App.  3d  737,  489  N.E.2d  384  (1986). 

245.  115  U.S.  620  (1885). 

246.  325  U.S.  304  (1945). 


1989]  STATUTE  OF  LIMITATIONS  1019 

V.     Conclusion 

Children  have  been  described  as  the  largest  indigent  class  on  earth. ^"^^ 
Children  are  uniquely  unable  to  protect  their  own  rights. ^"^^  Given  this 
inability  to  protect  their  own  rights,  it  is  imperative  that  we,  as  a  society, 
endeavor  to  protect  those  who  are  unable  to  protect  themselves.  It  is 
the  mark  of  a  civiHzed  society.  Statutes  of  limitations  safeguard  the 
accused  against  stale  claims  by  discouraging  victims  from  sleeping  on 
their  rights.  Although  child  sex  abuse  victims  may  have  a  moral  obligation 
to  report  the  offense  in  a  timely  manner,  the  public  derives  no  benefit 
by  shielding  the  offender  from  prosecution  while  simultaneously  penal- 
izing the  victim  for  his  or  her  inability  to  report  the  offense.  The 
offender  should  not  be  permitted  to  control  his  destiny  by  allowing  him 
to  manipulate  the  victim,  impeding  reporting  and  preventing  prosecution. 
Certainly,  neither  logic  nor  public  policy  require  that  society  maintain 
a  helpless,  silent  vigil,  permitting  the  child  sexual  abuser  to  avoid  pros- 
ecution by  unlawfully  detaining  his  victim,  thus  preventing  the  victim's 
report  and  the  state's  prosecution  of  the  offense.  Yet,  stringent  application 
of  the  statute  of  limitations  inflicts  a  similar  injustice  upon  the  child 
sex  abuse  victim. 

The  child  victim,  subject  to  unique  reporting  impediments,  deserves 
an  opportunity  for  legal  redress.  Child  sexual  abusers  must  be  deterred 
and  punished.  Retroactive  application  of  legislatively  enlarged  statutes 
of  limitations  accomplishes  each  of  these  desirable  objectives.  The  mere 
extension  of  the  limitations  period,  when  mated  with  legislative  purpose, 
supports  a  presumption  for  retroactive  application.  Given  the  minor's 
decided  disadvantage  in  knowledge,  power  and  resources,  fairness  de- 
mands that  the  child  victim  be  given  every  opportunity  for  legal  redress. 
Thus,  absent  manifest  legislative  intent  to  the  contrary,  the  needs  of 
society  and  the  child  sexual  abuse  victim  are  best  served  by  retroactive 
application  of  the  enlarged  limitations  period,  and  where  expressly  de- 
creed, the  revised  limitations  period  may  be  applied  to  revive  a  time- 
barred  claim. 

Thomas  G.  Burroughs 


247.  Bross  &  Munson,  Alternative  Models  of  Legal  Representation  for  Children,  5 
Okla.  City  U.L.  Rev.  561,  565  (1989). 

248.  For  example,  many  states  provide  that  children  under  the  age  of  ten  are 
presumptively  incompetent  to  testify.  States  also  vary  as  to  the  threshold  below  which  a 
child  is  deemed  automatically  incompetent  to  testify.  See  e.g.,  Kellum  v.  State,  396  A. 2d 
166  (Del.  1978)  (3  years  old);  State  v.  Thrasher,  223  Kan.  1016,  666  P.2d  772  (1983)  (4 
years  old). 


ii 


A  Modest  Proposal"— The  Prohibition  of  All-Adult 
Communities  by  the  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of 

1988 

I.    Introduction 

The  traditional  American  dream  of  owning  a  home  is  slowly  fading. 
Zoning  regulations  and  other  local  ordinances  complicate  new  housing 
construction  and  convey  an  '*anti-growth"  attitude  which  discourages 
building.  •  This  trend,  combined  with  an  increase  in  two-career  families 
and  a  decrease  in  the  number  of  famihes  having  children  or  having 
children  later  in  life,^  increases  the  demand  for  the  available  rental 
housing.^  As  the  demand  for  rental  housing  intensifies,  new  legal  issues 
emerge.  One  issue  which  has  received  a  great  amount  of  attention  in 
recent  years  is  familial  discrimination.  This  discrimination  occurs  when 
apartment  complex  owners  entirely  exclude  children  (the  '* all-adult" 
apartment  communities)  or  they  only  accept  children  with  limitations.'^ 

Familial  discrimination  appeals  to  apartment  complex  owners  for 
many  reasons.  Many  adults  who  choose  not  to  have  children,  or  wait 
longer  to  have  children,  wish  to  live  in  a  chiid-free  environment.  There- 
fore, apartment  complex  owners  can  charge  higher  prices  for  all-adult 
communities.  Lower  insurance  and  maintenance  costs  for  all-adult  com- 
munities also  induce  owners  to  exclude  children.^ 

Severe  rental  housing  shortages  faced  by  families  with  children  in 
some  areas  of  the  country^  have  prompted  judicial  decisions^  or  legislation® 


1.  R.  GoETZE,  Rescuing  the  American  Dream  41  (1983).  In  many  of  the  older 
urban  areas,  the  occupants  of  two  out  of  three  households  reside  in  rental  housing. 

2.  Id. 

3.  See  generally  A.  Downs,  Rental  Housing  in  the  1980's  1-4  (1983). 

4.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  Measuring  Restrictive  Rental  Practices  Af- 
fecting Families  with  Children:  A  National  Survey  22  (1980).  Restrictions  on  children 
include  limits  on  the  age  of  children  allowed  in  rental  units  (e.g.,  excluding  children  under 
the  age  of  12),  and  on  the  number  or  location  of  children  (e.g.,  only  one  child  per 
apartment  or  children  restricted  to  specific  buildings).  Id. 

5.  Id.  at  54-67. 

6.  See  D.  Ashford  &  P.  Eston,  The  Extent  and  Effects  of  Discrimination 
Against  Children  in  Rental  Housing:  A  Study  of  Five  Californl\  Cities  6  (1979) 
(This  study  showed  53  percent  of  the  apartment  complexes  in  Fresno,  California,  65 
percent  in  San  Diego,  California,  and  70  percent  in  San  Jose,  California  excluded  children. 
Note  these  statistics  were  compiled  before  California  passed  legislation  prohibiting  familial 
discrimination);  Landlord  Discrimination  Against  Children:  Possible  Solutions  to  a  Housing 
Crisis,  11  LoY.  L.A.L.  Rev.  609,  612  (1978)  (Statistics  indicate  60-80  percent  of  the 
apartment  units  in  Los  Angeles,  California  exclude  children  while  the  vacancy  rate  was 

1021 


1022  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

prohibiting  familial  discrimination  as  the  basis  for  denying  rental  housing 
occupancy.  However,  familial  rights  advocates  criticize  the  various  state 
nondiscrimination  provisions  for  allowing  limited  familial  discrimination, 
for  being  poorly  drafted,  and  for  providing  only  limited  administrative 
remedies.^  Familial  rights  advocates  assert  judicial  decisions  are  inade- 
quate due  to  the  time  and  expense  required  to  maintain  a  private  cause 
of  action. ^^ 

A  few  plaintiffs  have  sought  federal  protection  from  child-exclu- 
sionary poUcies  under  the  Fair  Housing  Act''  or  under  constitutional 
protection  of  the  right  to  privacy  or  equal  protection. '^  However,  it  is 
difficult  for  a  plaintiff  to  maintain  a  cause  of  action  under  the  Fair 
Housing  Act'^  because  the  plaintiff  must  show  the  child-exclusionary 
poHcies  have  a  * 'racially-disparate  impact"''*  or  that  there  has  been  state 
action,  a  prerequisite  for  litigation  alleging  violations  of  the  constitutional 


2.5  to  3.5  percent);  Sixty  Minutes  (CBS  television  broadcast,  January  22,  1978)  (Dan 
Rather  stated  that  famihes  with  children  in  southern  California  experienced  the  greatest 
hardship  locating  rental  housing.  Dora  Ashford  reported  only  20  percent  of  the  apartment 
complexes  in  Santa  Monica,  Cahfornia  did  not  exclude  children). 

7.  See  generally  Marina  Point,  Ltd.  v.  Wolfson,  30  Cal.  3d  721,  640  P.2d  115, 
180  Cal.  Rptr.  496  (1982)  (Richardson,  J.,  dissenting),  cert,  denied,  459  U.S.  858  (1982). 

8.  See  generally  N.J.  Stat.  Ann.  §  2A:  42-101  (West  1952  &  Supp.  1987).  This 
section  provides: 

No  person,  firm  or  corporation  or  any  agent,  officer  or  employee  thereof  shall 
refuse  to  rent  or  lease  any  house  or  apartment  to  another  person  because  his 
family  includes  children  under  14  years  of  age  or  shall  make  an  agreement, 
rental  or  lease  of  any  house  or  apartment  which  provides  that  the  agreement, 
rental  or  lease  shall  be  rendered  null  and  void  upon  the  birth  of  a  child.  This 
section  shall  not  apply  to  any  State  or  Federally  financed  or  assisted  housing 
project  constructed  for  occupancy  by  senior  citizens  or  to  any  property  located 
in  a  retirement  subdivision  as  defined  in  the  "Retirement  Community  Full 
Disclosure  Act"  (P.L.  1969,  c.215;  C.45:22A-1)  or  to  any  owner-occupied  house 
containing  not  more  than  two  dwelling  units. 

9.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act,  1987:  Hearings  on  H.R.  1158  Before  the 
Subcomm.  on  Civil  and  Constitutional  Rights  of  the  House  of  Representatives  Comm. 
on  the  Judiciary,  100th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.  398-99  (1987)  [hereinafter  Hearings]  (statement 
of  James  B,  Morales,  Staff  Atty.,  Nat'l  Center  for  Youth  Law).  Some  statutes  allow 
discrimination  against  children  over  the  age  of  14.  Id.  Others  are  poorly  drafted  because 
they  may  allow  subtle  forms  of  discrimination  by  charging  high  security  deposits  for 
families  with  children  or  by  placing  familial  discrimination  statutes  in  sections  apart  from 
the  civil  rights  areas,  and  not  providing  victims  with  all  the  remedies  available  for  civil 
rights  violations.  Id. 

10.  Walsh,  The  Necessity  for  Shelter:  States  Must  Prohibit  Discrimination  Against 
Children  in  Housing,  15  Fordham  Urb.  L.  J.  481,  518  (1987). 

11.  Betsey  v.  Turtle  Creek  Assoc,  736  F.2d  983  (4th  Cir.  1984). 

12.  Halet  v.  Wend  Inv.  Co.,  672  F.2d  1305  (9th  Cir.  1982). 

13.  42  U.S.C.  §  3608  (1982). 

14.  Betsey,  at  986. 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1023 

rights  to  privacy  or  Equal  Protection.'^  These  contentions  are  difficult 
to  prove  because  they  require  statistics  reflecting  a  greater  impact  on 
minorities  or  that  the  action  was  performed  under  color  of  state  law.'^ 
In  response  to  the  assertion  that  *'[f]amihes  with  children  are  facing 
a  housing  crisis,"'^  President  Reagan  signed  the  Fair  Housing  Amend- 
ments Act  of  1988'^  into  law  on  September  13  of  that  year.  This  Act 
amends  the  Civil  Rights  Act  of  1968'^  by  expanding  the  classes  receiving 
protections^  and  revising  the  procedures  for  enforcement  of  fair  housing 
practices. s'  The  1988  Amendments'^  prohibit  discrimination  in  the  sale 


15.  Hearings,  supra  note  9,  at  402  (testimony  of  James  B.  Morales,  Staff  Atty., 
Nat'l  Center  for  Youth  Law). 

16.  Id. 

17.  Hearings,  supra  note  9,  at  680  (testimony  of  Hon.  Don  Edwards,  Chairman, 
Subcomm.  on  Civil  and  Constitutional  Rights,  Comm.  on  the  Judiciary). 

18.  Pub.  L.  No.   100-430,  102  Stat.   1619-1636  (1988). 

19.  42  U.S.C.  §§  3601-3619  (1982). 

20.  42  U.S.C.  §  3604  (1982)  provides  protection  for  persons  discriminated  against 
on  the  basis  of  race,  color,  rehgion,  sex  or  national  origin.  The  Fair  Housing  Act  as 
amended  by  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1622  (1988)  now  provides  in  pertinent  part: 

It  shall  be  unlawful- 

(a)  To  refuse  to  sell  or  rent,  after  the  making  of  a  bona  fide  offer,  or 
to  refuse  to  negotiate  for  the  sale  or  rental  of,  or  otherwise  make 
unavailable  or  deny,  a  dwelling  to  any  person  because  of  race,  color, 
religion,  sex,  handicap,  familial  status,  or  national  origin. 

(b)  To  discriminate  against  any  person  in  the  terms,  conditions,  or  privileges 
of  sale  or  rental  of  a  dwelling,  or  in  the  provision  of  services  or 
facilities  in  connection  therewith,  because  of  race,  color,  religion,  sex, 
handicap,  famiUal  status,  or  national  origin. 

(c)  To  make,  print,  or  publish  or  cause  to  be  made,  printed,  or  published 
any  notice,  statement,  or  advertisement,  with  respect  to  the  sale  or 
rental  of  a  dwelling  that  indicates  any  preference,  limitation,  or  dis- 
crimination based  on  race,  color,  religion,  sex,  handicap,  familial  status, 
or  national  origin,  or  an  intention  to  make  any  such  preference, 
limitation,  or  discrimination. 

(d)  To  represent  to  any  person  because  of  race,  color,  religion,  sex, 
handicap,  familial  status,  or  national  origin  that  any  dwelling  is  not 
available  for  inspection,  sale,  or  rental  when  such  dwelling  is  in  fact 
so  available. 

(e)  For  profit,  to  induce  or  attempt  to  induce  any  person  to  sell  or  rent 
any  dwelling  by  representations  regarding  the  entry  or  prospective  entry 
into  the  neighborhood  of  a  person  or  persons  of  a  particular  race, 
color,  religion,  sex,  handicap,  familial  status  or  national  origin. 

21.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1625- 
35  (1988).  This  amends  the  enforcement  procedure  by  allowing  hearings  before  admin- 
istrative law  judges,  or  for  a  cause  of  action  to  be  filed  by  the  Attorney  General  or  by 
a  private  person. 

22.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1622 
(1988). 


1024  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

or  rental  of  a  dwelling  based  on  familial  status^^  unless  the  dwelling  is 
located  in  a  retirement  community.^'*  The  retirement  community  exception 
recognizes  the  fact  that  elderly  persons  have  a  greater  need  to  live  in 
a  child-free  environment. ^^ 


23.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1622 
(1988)  provides  in  pertinent  part: 

"Familial  Status"  means  one  or  more  individuals  (who  have  not  attained  the 
age  of  18  years)  being  domiciled  with  - 

(1)  a  parent  or  another  person  having  legal  custody  of  such  individual  or 
individuals;  or 

(2)  the  designee  of  such  parent  or  other  person  having  such  custody,  with  the 
written  permission  of  such  parent  or  other  person. 

The  protections  afforded  against  discrimination  on  the  basis  of  famiUal  status 
shall  apply  to  any  person  who  is  pregnant  or  is  in  the  process  of  securing  legal 
custody  of  any  individual  who  has  not  attained  the  age  of  18  years. 

24.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1623  (1988) 
provides: 

(b)(1)  Nothing  in  this  title  limits  the  applicability  of  any  reasonable  local.  State, 
or  Federal  restrictions  regarding  the  maximum  number  of  occupants  permitted 
to  occupy  a  dwelling.  Nor  does  any  provision  in  this  title  regarding  familial 
status  apply  with  respect  to  housing  for  older  persons. 

(2)  As  used  in  this  section,  "housing  for  older  persons"  means  housing  - 

(A)  provided  under  any  State  or  Federal  program  that  the  Secretary  determines 
is  specifically  designed  and  operated  to  assist  elderly  persons  (as  defined  in  the 
State  or  Federal  program);  or 

(B)  intended  for,  and  solely  occupied  by,  persons  62  years  of  age  or  older;  or 

(C)  intended  and  operated  for  occupancy  by  at  least  one  person  55  years  of 
age  or  older  per  unit.  In  determining  whether  housing  qualifies  as  housing  for 
older  persons  under  this  subsection,  the  Secretary  shall  develop  regulations  which 
require  at  least  the  following  factors: 

(i)  the  existence  of  significant  facilities  and  services  specifically  designed  to  meet 
the  physical  or  social  needs  of  older  persons,  or  if  the  provision  of  such  facilities 
and  services  is  not  practicable,  that  such  housing  is  necessary  to  provide  important 
housing  opportunities  for  older  persons;  and 

(ii)  that  at  least  80  percent  of  the  units  are  occupied  by  at  least  one  person  55 
years  of  age  or  older  per  unit;  and 

(iii)  the  publication  of,  and  adherence  to,  policies  and  procedures  which  dem- 
onstrate an  intent  by  the  owner  or  manager  to  provide  housing  for  persons  55 
years  of  age  or  older. 

(3)  Housing  shall  not  fail  to  meet  the  requirements  for  housing  for  older  persons 
by  reason  of: 

(A)  persons  residing  in  such  housing  as  of  the  date  of  enactment  of  this  Act 
who  do  not  meet  the  age  requirements  of  subsection  2(B)  or  (C):  Provided, 
That  new  occupants  of  such  housing  meet  the  age  requirements  of  subsections 
2(B)  or  (C);  or 

(B)  unoccupied  units:  Provided,  That  such  units  are  reserved  for  occupancy  by 
persons  who  meet  the  age  requirements  of  subsections  (2)(B)  or  (C). 

25.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act:  Hearings  on  H.R.  4119  Before  the  Subcomm. 
on  Civil  and  Constitutional  Rights  of  the  House  of  Representatives  Comm.  on  the  Judiciary, 
99th  Cong.,  2nd  Sess.  62  (1986)  (testimony  of  Hon.  Hamilton  Fish,  Jr.). 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1025 

Familial  discrimination  has  not  been  limited  to  apartment  complexes. 
It  has  also  surfaced  in  mobile  home  parks^^  and  condominiums.^^  How- 
ever, this  Note  will  focus  on  familial  discrimination  in  apartment  com- 
plexes because  this  constitutes  the  majority  of  familial  discrimination 
occurrences.^^  The  Note  will  examine  the  scope  of  the  problems  resulting 
from  familial  discrimination  through  available  statistics,  state  legislation, 
and  judicial  decisions.  Further,  this  Note  will  discuss  the  impact  of  the 
1988  Act  and  address  valid  arguments  against  such  broad  sweeping 
legislation  and  the  rehef,  or  lack  thereof,  the  Act  will  provide  to  families 
with  children. 

Finally,  this  Note  will  suggest  alternatives  to  the  broad  sweeping 
policies  of  the  Act.  These  alternatives  would  provide  relief  from  extensive 
child-exclusionary  policies  which  plague  some  areas  of  the  country  without 
totally  prohibiting  all-adult  apartment  communities. 

II.  Background 

Familial  rights  advocates  have  denounced  child-exclusionary  policies 
as  causing  rental  housing  shortages  for  families  with  children. ^^  These 
policies  generated  such  a  controversy  that  President  Reagan  signed  leg- 
islation prohibiting  all-adult  apartment  communities,  unless  they  are 
designated  as  retirement  communities,  on  September  13,  1988.^^  However, 
no  statistics  demonstrating  the  actual  number  of  families  with  children 
affected  by  exclusionary  poHcies  exist  to  support  this  drastic  measure.^' 

A,     Changes  in  Rental  Housing 

The  1980's  witnessed  an  increased  inability  to  purchase  homes. ^^  This 
is  due  to  higher  real  capital  costs,"  higher  interest  rates, ^"^  and  a  decrease 
in  the  construction  of  new  homes  due  to  high  financing  costs, ^^  labor 


26.  See  Schmidt  v.  Superior  Court,  43  Cal.  3d  1060,  742  P.2d  209,  240  Cal.  Rptr. 
160  (1987). 

27.  See  Ritchey  v.  Villa  Neuva  Condo.  Ass'n,  81   Cal.  App.  3d  688,   146  Cal. 
Rptr.  695  (1978);  White  Egret  Condo,  Inc.  v.  Franklin,  379  So.  2d  346  (Fla.   1980). 

28.  Exclusion  of  Families  With  Children  From  Housing,   18  J.L.  Reform  1121, 
1122  (1985). 

29.  See  Hearings,  supra  note  9. 

30.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1619- 
36  (1988). 

3 1 .  The  study  completed  by  the  University  of  Michigan  Institute  for  Social  Research 
is  the  only  comprehensive  study  available. 

32.  A.  Downs,  supra  note  3,  at  60-61. 

33.  Id. 

34.  Id. 

35.  R.  GoETZE,  supra  note  1,  at  36. 


1026  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

regulations,^^  zoning  constraints,^^  and  complex  permit  requirements.^^ 
Therefore,  a  greater  number  of  people  will  be  residing  in  rental  housing. ^^ 

Yet,  the  supply  of  available  rental  units  will  not  be  able  to  meet 
this  demand.  The  1988  Statistical  Abstract  of  the  United  States  reported 
an  overall  vacancy  rate  of  5.0  percent  for  1981;  this  rate  increased 
gradually  to  6.5  percent  in  1985  and  7.2  percent  in  1986."^  However, 
in  certain  areas  of  the  country,  the  problem  is  more  intense.  For  example, 
there  are  serious  housing  shortages  in  some  urban  areas  (e.g.,  Chicago 
and  Manhattan)"^^  and  in  the  nation's  sunbelt  areas. "^^  Part  of  this  problem 
results  from  the  fact  that  California,  Texas  and  Florida  (the  sunbelt 
areas)  together  accounted  for  53  percent  of  the  population  growth  between 
1980  and  1986.^^ 

The  inability  of  the  supply  of  rental  housing  to  meet  the  demand 
is  attributable  to  many  factors.  Rental  receipts  are  inadequate  to  meet 
construction  and  operating  costs,  making  new  apartment  construction 
economically  impractical. "^  Between  1970  and  1973  construction  began 
on  871,000  multifamily  units;  this  number  decreased  to  458,000  units 
annually  from  1974  to  1980.^^^  Additionally,  many  apartments  are  con- 
verted to  condominiums  each  year  so  the  owner  can  escape  continued 
operating  costs  and  receive  a  more  immediate  return  on  his  investment."*^ 

The  proportion  of  households  consisting  of  a  married  couple  with 
children  under  the  age  of  eighteen  has  decreased  by  thirteen  percent 
since  1970."*^  Many  of  the  adults  who  choose  not  to  have  children  wish 
to  live  in  a  child-free  environment  and  willingly  pay  extra  for  this  luxury."*^ 


36.  Id. 

37.  Id. 

38.  Id. 

39.  Between  1970  and  1979  the  number  of  persons  occupying  rental  housing  in- 
creased by  approximately  3.5  million  persons.  A.  Downs,  supra  note  3,  at  73  n.l.  It  is 
noted  that  the  1980's  will  see  an  increase  of  4.2  million  rental  households.  This  translates 
to  an  increase  of  424,000  rental  households  per  year.  Id.  at  7. 

40.  U.S.  Dept.  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Statistical  Abstract  of 
THE  United  States,  165  (108  ed.  1988). 

41.  A.  Downs,  supra  note  3,  at  42  n.34. 

42.  See  D,  Ashford  &  P.  Eston,  supra  note  6;  R.  Goetze,  supra  note  1,  at  ix. 

43.  U.S.  Dept.  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census,  State  Population  and 
Household  Estimates,  With  Age,  Sex,  and  Components  of  Change  1981-86  1  (Series 
P.  25,  No.   1010,  1987). 

44.  A.  Downs,  supra  note  3,  at  40. 

45.  Id. 

46.  Id.  at  40-41,  n.30.  The  conversion  of  rental  housing  into  condominiums  has 
a  lesser  effect  on  rental  supply  and  demand  because  many  persons  purchasing  condominium 
units  are  former  tenants. 

47.  U.S.  Dept.  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Household  and  Family 
Characteristics:  March  1987  1  (Series  P-20,  No.  424.  1988). 

48.  See  generally  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4. 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1027 

Families  without  children  are  generally  two-career  couples  who,  because 
they  do  not  have  to  bear  the  expense  of  raising  a  family,  can  afford 
to  spend  a  greater  portion  of  their  income  on  rent.  Landlords  who  saw 
a  way  to  exclude  children  (whom  they  perceive  as  costlier  tenants),  and 
possibly  to  charge  a  premium  for  such  rental  housing,  introduced 
the  concept  of  all-adult  or  restricted  apartment  communities/^  All-adult 
apartment  communities  totally  prohibit  anyone  under  the  age  of  eighteen 
from  living  in  the  rental  units. ^°  Restricted  communities  accept  children 
with  Hmitations  on  possibly  one  of  the  following:  age,  the  number  of 
children,  or  the  location  of  children  within  the  complex.^'  Recent  public 
outcry  from  familial  rights  advocates  concerning  child-exclusionary  pol- 
icies resulted  in  the  passage  of  the  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of 
1988,"  which  prohibits  famiUal  discrimination  in  the  rental  housing 
market." 

B.     Problems  Generated  by  Child-Exclusionary  Policies 

No  comprehensive  statistics  exist  which  reflect  the  actual  number  of 
families  affected  nationwide  by  familial  discrimination.  The  University 
of  Michigan  Institute  for  Social  Research  (the  ISR  Study)  completed  the 
most  comprehensive  study  on  the  subject. ^'^  However,  the  authors  of  the 
study  noted  that  it  did  not  constitute  a  complete  measure  of  the  problem: 

These  studies  were  prepared  in  growing  communities  where  the 
rental  housing  market  was  tight  and  the  problems  for  families 
with  children  particularly  noticeable  and  salient.  While  the  data 
strongly  suggest  that  exclusionary  policies  may  be  an  obstacle 
for  many  families  with  children  in  specific  locations,  no  data 
are  available  on  the  extent  to  which  this  is  a  nationwide  phe- 
nomenon.^^ 

Thus,  one  needs  to  examine  available  statistics,  case  law,  and  leg- 
islative actions  to  put  child-exclusionary  policies  into  perspective. 

1.  Statistical  Analysis  of  Familial  Discrimination  Practices. — The  1980 
Census  reported  that  68  miUion  people  reside  in  rental  housing. ^^  Of 


49.  Id. 

50.  Id. 

51.  Id. 

52.  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1619-1636  (1988). 

53.  Id. 

54.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4. 

55.  Id.  at  3. 

56.  U.S.  Dept.  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  THfe  Census,  1980  Census  of  Housing, 
Characteristics  of  Housing  Units,  General  Housing  Characteristics,  Part  A  1-59 
(1983). 


1028  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

the  rental  units,  over  two-thirds,  67.6  percent,  have  no  residents  under 
the  age  of  eighteen;"  over  one-half  of  these  renters  are  under  age  thirty- 
five.^^ 

The  study  conducted  by  the  Institute  for  Social  Research  found  that 
approximately  one  in  four  rental  units  nationwide  are  located  in  all- 
adult  communities.^^  However,  when  the  figures  are  adjusted  to  reflect 
exceptions  made  by  apartment  managers,  the  number  of  apartments 
excluding  children  falls  to  one  in  five.^°  The  study  further  found  that 
50  percent  of  the  units  analyzed  accepted  children  with  Umitations.^' 
These  limitations  included  policies  limiting  the  number  of  children  allowed 
depending  on  the  size  of  the  unit,  policies  limiting  the  children  over  or 
under  a  specific  age,  restrictions  on  children  of  the  opposite  sex  sharing 
bedrooms,  and  policies  separating  families  with  children  from  those 
without  children,  either  by  floor  or  by  building. ^^ 

At  first  glance,  75  percent  of  apartment  units  nationwide  appear  to 
either  totally  exclude  children  or  accept  them  with  limitations."  However, 
the  figures  must  be  put  into  perspective.  First,  some  managers  of  apart- 
ment complexes  reported  exclusionary  policies,  but  stated  they  had  ex- 
ceptions;^'* therefore,  the  proportion  of  exclusionary  or  restrictive  policies 
is  actually  lower.  Additionally,  efficiencies  which  do  not  have  a  separate 
bedroom  and  one-bedroom  apartments  comprise  the  largest  percentage 
of  units  which  have  exclusionary  policies. ^^  Alternatively,  only  2.1  percent 
of  three  or  more  bedroom  units  have  poHcies  excluding  children. ^^ 

2.  Effect  of  Familial  Discrimination  on  Minorities  and  Low  Income 
Families. — If  familial  discriminatory  policies  are  merely  a  smoke  screen 
to  enforce  what  is  truly  a  racial  discrimination  policy,  the  excluded 
tenants  have  a  cause  of  action  under  the  Fair  Housing  Act  of  1968.^^ 
A  1980  study  suggests  child-exclusionary  policies  are  actually  racially 
discriminatory  policies  reporting: 


57.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4,  at  12,  Table  III-l. 

58.  /(i.  at  5.  This  statistic  shows  that  these  renters  do  not  quaUfy  for  residence 
in  retirement  communities.  Id. 

59.  Id.  at  ES-2. 

60.  Id. 

61.  Id.  at  27,  Table  IV-3. 

62.  Id.  at  nn.3-6. 

63.  Id.  at  Table  IV-3. 

64.  Id.  at  70. 

65.  Id.  at  27,  Table  IV-5.  35.5  percent  of  efficiencies  have  exclusionary  pohcies; 
41.5  percent  of  one-bedroom  apartments  exclude  children.  Id. 

66.  Id.  Tv/o  bedroom  apartments  do  comprise  the  largest  percentage  of  the  various 
sized  units  which  place  restrictions  on  the  children  who  are  accepted.  These  restrictions 
usually  limit  the  number  of  children  allowed  (56  percent)  or  do  not  allow  children  of  the 
opposite  sex  to  occupy  the  same  bedroom  (24.9  percent).  Id. 

67.  42  U.S.C.  §  3604(a),  (b)  (1982). 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1029 

Even  when  controlling  for  income,  there  is  a  statistically  sig- 
nificant difference  between  the  percentage  of  minorities,  who 
experienced  serious  housing  problems  due  to  no-children  poHcies, 
and  the  percentage  among  their  white  counterparts.  Undoubtedly 
this  difference  is  due  in  part  to  racial  discrimination,  which 
housing  studies  have  found  to  exist  in  the  rental  market.  What 
is  not  known  is  the  extent  to  which  no-children  poHcies  are  used 
as  a  smoke  screen  for  racial  discrimination.^^ 

Alternatively,  the  ISR  study  states:  "Among  those  who  rent,  female- 
headed  households  and  minority  groups  are  no  more  likely  to  suffer 
from  no-children  poHcies  in  the  rental  market  than  other  groups. "^^  The 
discrepancies  between  the  two  surveys  can  be  explained  in  part  by  differing 
methodology. ^°  Additionally,  the  ISR  study  reflected  that  the  higher 
percentage  of  minorities  reporting  problems  relating  to  child-exclusionary 
policies  can  be  explained  in  part  by  the  fact  that  minority  group  tenants 
are  more  Hkely  to  have  children  in  the  household  than  their  white 
counterparts.^'  This  study  further  suggested  that  the  problems  experienced 
by  minority  tenants  correlate  to  the  price  of  housing  which  is  available 
in  the  various  units  to  which  they  normally  have  access. ^^ 

Further,  both  studies  discovered  lower  income  families  feel  the  effect 
of  child-exclusionary  policies  to  a  much  greater  extent  than  do  middle 
to  higher  income  families. ^^  The  ISR  study  reports  low  income  families 
with  children  experience  more   frustration  when  attempting  to   locate 


68.  J.  Greene  &  G.  Blake,  How  Restrictive  Rental  Practices  Affect  Families 
With  Children  30-31  (1980). 

69.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4,  at  ES-2. 

70.  The  Greene  study  and  the  ISR  study  utilized  very  different  methods  of  obtaining 
their  respective  sampling  groups.  The  Greene  Study  aired  public  service  announcements 
on  television  and  radio  stations  in  six  metropohtan  areas.  These  announcements  invited 
persons  who  had  experienced  or  were  experiencing  difficulties  in  finding  rental  housing 
to  call  and  tell  of  their  experiences.  The  study  reached  only  those  persons  who  had 
experienced  difficulties  and  was  concentrated  in  urban  areas  where  the  problems  are  more 
intense.  Nor  did  the  Greene  Study  survey  people  who  had  not  experienced  difficulties  to 
have  an  unbiased  comparison  group.  J.  Greene  &  G.  Blake,  supra  note  68,  at  1.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  ISR  study  was  conducted  by  the  use  of  randomly  generated  telephone 
numbers  to  gather  a  sample  of  tenants,  the  sample  of  managers  was  obtained  by  questioning 
the  tenants  who  were  part  of  the  survey.  R.  Marans  <&  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4,  at  5. 

71.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4,  at  12,  Table  II-l. 

72.  Id.  at  5. 

73.  J.  Greene  &  G.  Blake,  supra  note  68,  at  10,  Table  II.  The  study  found  65.4 
percent  of  the  respondents  reporting  income  fell  below  the  $15,000  annual  income  level. 
The  number  of  respondents  above  the  $30,000  annual  income  level  was  4  percent.  The 
highest  percentage  group  (26.2  percent)  fell  between  an  annual  income  level  of  $5,000 
and  $9,999.  Id. 


1030  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

rental  housing  and  were  more  likely  to  settle  for  housing  below  their 
expected  standard.'''*  This  study  further  stated: 

While  there  is  no  discernible  relationship  between  monthly  rents 
and  the  presence  or  absence  of  no-children  policies,  the  higher 
rent  units  are  more  Hkely  to  be  found  in  buildings  or  complexes 
which  limit  children  by  age  and  location.  .  .  .  The  likelihood  of 
age  and  location  limitations  occurring  increases  as  the  monthly 
rent  increases.  Moreover,  the  likelihood  that  two  bedroom  rentals 
in  apartment  buildings  or  complexes  renting  for  more  than  $200 
prohibit  families  with  children  is  roughly  twice  as  great  as  com- 
parably-sized units  renting  for  $200  or  less.''^ 

Part  of  the  reason  low  income  families  cannot  find  rental  housing 
can  be  attributed  to  rent  escalation  rather  than  child-exclusionary  policies. 
Although  rental  prices  did  not  rise  as  quickly  as  the  consumer  price 
index  from  1960  to  1981,^^  this  trend  has  reversed  and  from  July  1981  to 
December  1982,  the  consumer  price  index  showed  that  the  component 
for  residential  rent  rose  faster  than  the  overall  index. ^^  Rental  prices 
reportedly  are  now  increasing  at  a  faster  rate  than  tenant  income.^* 
Therefore,  the  majority  of  nonsubsidized  housing  is  merely  beyond  the 
reach  of  low  income  families  with  children. 

In  summary,  no  one  has  undertaken  a  comprehensive  study  which 
presents  an  accurate  portrayal  of  the  problems  caused  by  familial  dis- 


74.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4,  at  72.  The  group  experiencing  the 
most  difficult  problems  were  those  famiUes  who  have  at  least  three  children  and  fall  into 
the  lower  income  range.  Id. 

75.  Id.  at  40. 

76.  A.  Downs,  supra  note  3,  at  3-4  (1983). 

[Rlesidential  rents  did  not  increase  as  fast  as  consumer  income,  operating  costs, 
or  construction  costs.  This  was  true  even  after  correction  for  substantial  un- 
derestimation of  rental  costs  by  the  consumer  price  index.  The  best  available 
estimate  is  that  real  rent  levels  fell  about  8,4  percent  from  1960  to  1981,  or 
roughly  4.2  percent  each  decade. 
Id. 

11 .  Id.  at  133  n.3.  In  addition,  beginning  in  about  1961  the  Federal  Government 
instituted  programs  designed  to  attract  private  developers  into  the  low  income  housing 
market.  The  private  developers  were  required  to  make  a  twenty  or  forty  year  commitment 
to  the  project.  The  developers  are  able  to  take  low  income  housing  off  the  market  or 
convert  it  into  high  rental  housing  if  they  defaulted  or  prepaid  their  mortgage  after  their 
commitment  period  expired.  Many  developers  have  either  defaulted  or  have  prepaid  their 
mortgage  and,  therefore,  have  removed  their  property  from  the  low  income  market.  The 
number  of  low  income  units  removed  from  the  low  income  housing  market  is  projected 
to  peak  in  the  1990's.  National  Low^  Income  Housing  Preservation  Commission,  Pre- 
venting THE  Disappearance  of  Low  Income  Housing,  1-6  (1988). 

78.  Why  Johnny  Can't  Rent- An  Examination  of  Laws  Prohibiting  Discrimination 
Against  Families  in  Rental  Housing,  94  Harv,  L.  Rev,   1829,  1832  n,7  (1981), 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1031 

crimination.  The  statistics  which  are  available  show  that  serious  problems 
exist  in  the  urban  and  sunbelt  areas  of  the  nation  where  there  is  a  need 
for  antidiscrimination  measures. ^^  There  is  no  comprehensive  data  avail- 
able for  the  less  densely  populated  areas  of  the  nation.  Data  shows  that 
lower  income  families  with  children  are  more  adversely  affected  by 
exclusionary  poHcies.  However,  this  can  only  be  due  to  the  unavailability 
of  low  income  housing,  and  raising  of  rental  rates  which  put  many 
rental  units  beyond  the  reach  of  low  income  families  with  children  regardless 
of  child-exclusionary  poUcies.  However,  when  the  national  picture  of 
problems  arising  from  famihal  discriminatory  policies  is  put  into  per- 
spective, the  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988^^  is  much  too  broad 
and  will  not  provide  relief  for  those  who  need  it  most:  lower  income 
families  with  children. 

3.  Judicial  Decisions. — Tenants  denied  rental  housing  or  evicted  from 
rental  housing  because  of  their  race,  color,  religion,  sex,  or  national 
origin  have  been  provided  protection  under  the  Fair  Housing  Act^^  since 
1968.  Prior  to  the  1988  Amendments,  tenants  showing  denial  or  eviction 
premised  on  familial  discrimination,  but  related  to  a  protected  class, 
had  a  cause  of  action  under  the  Fair  Housing  Act. 

This  was  accomplished  in  Betsey  v.  Turtle  Creek  Assoc. ^^  In  Betsey, 
the  apartment  owner  instituted  an  all-adult  policy  in  a  complex  which 
housed  mainly  black  families  with  children. ^^  The  tenants  filed  suit 
alleging  violation  of  the  Fair  Housing  Act^'*  and  presented  statistics 
showing  the  conversion  would  have  an  immediate  "disproportionate 
impact  on  the  black  tenants. '*^^  The  Fourth  Circuit  held  that  a  plaintiff 
presents  a.  prima  facie  case  of  racial  discrimination  under  the  Fair  Housing 
Amendments  Act  of  1968  if  he  can  show  that  the  denial  of  or  eviction 
from  rental  housing  '*was  motivated  by  a  racially  discriminating  purpose 
or  because  it  is  shown  to  have  a  disproportionate  adverse  impact  on 
minorities. "^^  The  court  found  both  elements  present  and  stated  a  ''con- 
tinuing disproportionate  impact"  on  blacks  was  not  required. ^^ 

Betsey  represents  the  first  case  striking  down  racial  discrimination 
disguised  as  familial  discrimination  and  was  the  first  case  of  its  type 
decided  under  the  Fair  Housing  Act.  Although  this  case  sets  favorable 


79.  See  supra  note  6  and  accompanying  text. 

80.  Pub.  L.  No.   100-430,  102  Stat.  1619-36  (1988). 

81.  42  U.S.C.  §  3604  (1982). 

82.  736  F.2d  983  (4th  Cir.  1984). 

83.  Id. 

84.  42  U.S.C.  §  3604  (1982). 

85.  Betsey,  736  F.2d  at  986. 

86.  Id.  at  987. 

87.  Id.  at  986. 


1032  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

precedent  for  minority  families  with  children  who  can  show  a  disparate 
impact  against  them  as  minorities,  it  offers  little  or  no  reUef  for  Caucasian 
families  with  children  who  experience  discrimination  in  the  rental  housing 
market. 

Another  case  in  which  the  plaintiff  sought  relief  from  child-exclu- 
sionary poHcies  under  the  Fair  Housing  Act  is  the  1982  case  of  Halet 
V.  Wend  Investment  Co.^^  The  Caucasian  plaintiff  in  Halet  was  denied 
rental  housing  because  he  had  a  child  who  would  be  living  in  the  unit. 
Although  the  district  court  dismissed  the  case  on  other  grounds,  the 
Ninth  Circuit  held  the  plaintiff  had  standing  to  challenge  racial  dis- 
crimination under  the  Fair  Housing  Act.  The  court  stated: 

The  Supreme  Court  .  .  .  held  that  a  plaintiff  who  has  suffered 
an  actual  injury  is  permitted  to  prove  that  the  rights  of  another 
are  infringed.  Here,  Halet  claims  that  he  was  denied  an  apartment 
because  of  a  policy  that  allegedly  infringes  on  the  rights  of 
Blacks  and  Hispanics.  Under  Gladstone  this  is  sufficient  to 
support  Halet 's  standing  under  the  Act.^^ 

Although  the  Fair  Housing  Act  may  provide  relief  to  victims  of 
familial  discrimination,  plaintiffs  often  have  difficulty  proving  the  req- 
uisite discriminatory  intent.  In  Metropolitan  Housing  Development  Corp, 
V.   Village  of  Arlington  Heights,^  the  Seventh  Circuit  stated: 

[A]  requirement  that  the  plaintiff  prove  discriminatory  intent 
before  relief  can  be  granted  under  the  statute  is  often  a  burden 
that  is  impossible  to  satisfy.  ...  [A]  strict  focus  on  intent  permits 
racial  discrimination  to  go  unpunished  in  the  absence  of  evidence 
of  overt  bigotry.^* 

In  addition  to  invoking  the  Fair  Housing  Act,  plaintiffs  have  sought 
protection  under  the  fourteenth  amendment  which  provides  that  every 
United  States  citizen  is  entitled  to  equal  protection  and  due  process  of 
the  laws^^  or  under  Section  1983  of  the  Civil  Rights  Act.^^  Only  recently 


88.  672  F.2d  1305  (9th  Cir.  1982). 

89.  Id.  at  1309  (citation  omitted). 

90.  558  F.2d  1283  (7th  Cir.  1977),  cert,  denied,  434  U.S.  1025  (1978). 

91.  Id.  at  1285. 

92.  U.S.  Const,  amend.  XIV,  §  1,  The  Due  Process  Clause  states: 

All  persons  born  or  naturalized  in  the  United  States,  and  subject  to  the  jurisdiction 
thereof,  are  citizens  of  the  United  States  and  of  the  State  wherein  they  reside. 
No  State  shall  make  or  enforce  any  law  which  shall  abridge  the  privileges  or 
immunities  of  citizens  of  the  United  States;  nor  shall  any  State  deprive  any 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1033 

have  cases  alleging  familial  discrimination  met  with  any  success  under 
the  latter  of  these  two  federal  provisions.^"* 

The  fourteenth  amendment  of  the  Constitution  sets  forth  that  no 
person  shall  be  denied  equal  protection  of  the  law  by  any  state. ^^  The 
Equal  Protection  Clause  '^governs  all  governmental  actions  which  classify 
individuals  for  different  benefits  or  burdens  under  the  law,"^^  and  requires 
that  'individuals  be  treated  in  a  manner  similar  to  others  as  an  inde- 
pendent constitutional  guarantee."^''  The  Equal  Protection  Clause  does 
not  invalidate  the  government's  ability  to  classify  people,  **but  it  does 
guarantee  that  those  classifications  will  not  be  based  upon  impermissible 
criteria  or  arbitrarily  used  to  burden  a  group  of  individuals."^^ 

There  are  three  standards  of  review  which  the  Court  may  utilize 
when  analyzing  equal  protection  issues. ^^  If  the  class  involved  is  one 
that  the  Supreme  Court  has  termed  an  ''insular  minority"  or  a  "suspect 
class,"  the  case  is  subject  to  strict  scrutiny. '°^  If  a  case  involves  a  suspect 
class,  the  practice  involved  will  be  invalidated  unless  it  can  be  shown 
"that  it  is  pursuing  a  'compelling'  or  'overriding'  end — one  whose  value 
is  so  great  that  it  justifies  the  limitations  of  fundamental  constitutional 


person  of  life,  liberty,  or  property,  without  due  process  of  law;  nor  deny  to 
any  person  within  its  jurisdiction  the  equal  protection  of  the  laws. 

93.  42  U.S.C.  §  1983  (1982).  Section  1983  provides: 

Every  person  who,  under  color  of  any  statute,  ordinance,  regulation,  custom, 
or  usage,  of  any  State  or  Territory,  subjects,  or  causes  to  be  subjected,  any 
citizen  of  the  United  States  or  other  person  within  the  jurisdiction  thereof  to 
the  deprivation  of  any  rights,  privileges,  or  immunities  secured  by  the  Constitution 
and  laws,  shall  be  liable  to  the  party  injured  in  an  action  at  law,  suit  in  equity, 
or  other  proper  proceeding  for  redress. 

94.  See  Halet  v.  Wend  Inv.  Co.,  672  F.2d  1305  (9th  Cir.  1982). 

95.  U.S.  Const,  amend.  XIV,  §  1. 

96.  J.  NowAK,  R.  Rotunda  &  J.  Young,  Constitutional  Law  §  14.1  (3d  ed. 
1986).  See  also  Lehr  v.  Robertson,  463  U.S.  250  (1983);  Harris  v.  McRae,  448  U.S.  297, 
reh'g  denied,  448  U.S.  917  (1980). 

97.  J.  NowAK,  R.  Rotunda  &  J.  Young,  supra  note  96,  at  §  14.1. 

98.  Id. 

99.  Id.  at  §  14.3. 

100.  Id.  See  also  United  States  v.  Carolene  Products  Co.,  304  U.S.  144  (1938); 
Yick  Wo  V.  Hopkins,  118  U.S.  356  (1886).  The  other  types  of  review  are  the  rational 
relationship  test  and  the  intermediate  test.  Under  the  rational  relationship  test,  the  court 
only  looks  to  determine  if  the  classification  involved  "bears  a  rational  relationship  to  an 
end  of  government  which  is  not  prohibited  by  the  Constitution."  J.  Nowak,  R.  Rotunda 
&  J.  Young,  supra  note  96,  at  §  14.3.  The  intermediate  test  falls  between  the  strict 
scrutiny  and  the  rational  relationship  test.  The  intermediate  test  does  not  invoke  the  strong 
presumption  of  constitutionality  present  under  the  rational  relationship  test  but  allows  the 
government  to  utilize  the  classification  if  it  is  a  reasonable  way  to  achieve  a  substantial 
government  end  and  not  an  arbitrary  classification.  The  intermediate  test  has  been  used 
with  gender-based  classes  and  illegitimacy  cases.  Id. 


1034  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

values. "'°'  To  date,  the  suspect  classes  do  not  include  one  based  on 
familial  status.'"^  Since  families  with  children  are  not  a  suspect  class,  a 
familial  discrimination  cause  of  action  will  not  be  successful  under  the 
Equal  Protection  Clause  of  the  fourteenth  amendment^"^  unless  it  can 
be  shown  the  discriminatory  practice  involved  is  racial  discrimination 
disguised  as  familial  discrimination.  A  plaintiff  may  be  better  able 
to  assert  a  cause  of  action  under  the  Due  Process  Clause  of  the  fourteenth 
amendment.  In  Moore  v.  City  of  East  Cleveland, ^^"^  the  Supreme  Court 
struck  down  an  ordinance  prohibiting  extended  family  members  from 
living  together. '°^  The  Court,  quoting  Cleveland  Board  of  Education  v, 
Lafleur,^^^  stated  "freedom  of  personal  choice  in  matters  of  marriage 
and  family  life  is  one  of  the  liberties  protected  by  the  Due  Process 
Clause  of  the  Fourteenth  Amendment.  "^^^  The  Moore  case  can  be  dis- 
tinguished from  familial  discrimination  cases  because  the  ordinance  in- 
volved did  not  merely  ban  the  family  in  question  from  the  rental  unit, 
it  completely  prohibited  the  family  from  Hving  together  and  subjected 
them  to  criminal  penalties  if  they  did.'^^  However,  the  Halet  court  adopted 
this  view  and  held: 

Family  life,  in  particular  the  right  of  family  members  to  live 
together,  is  part  of  the  fundamental  right  of  privacy.  .  .  .  The 
ordinance  in  Moore  prohibited  a  household  from  including  certain 
extended  family  members.  The  policy  in  this  case  prohibits  a 
household  from  including  immediate  family  members — that  is 
children.  A  fundamental  right  is  even  more  clearly  involved  here 
because  the  rental  policy  infringes  the  choice  of  parents  to  live 
with  their  children  rather  than  the  choice  of  more  distant  re- 
lations. ...  A  fundamental  right  to  be  free  from  state  intrusion 
in  decisions  concerning  family  relationships  in  the  nuclear  family 
has  been  clearly  recognized. '^^ 

Under  this  theory,  the  court  reversed  the  dismissal  of  Halet's  claim 
and  remanded  it  to  the  district  court  to  determine  whether  a  "genuinely 


101.  J.  NowAK,  R.  Rotunda  &  J.  Young,  supra  note  96,  §  14.3. 

102.  See,  e.g.,  Graham  v.  Richardson,  403  U.S.  365  (1971)  (alienage  is  a  suspect 
class);  Loving  v.  Virginia,  388  U.S.  1  (1967)  (race  is  a  protected  class);  Hernandez  v. 
State,  347  U.S.  475  (1954)  (national  origin  is  a  suspect  class). 

103.  Halet  v.  Wend  Inv.  Co.,  672  F.2d  1305,  1309  (1982). 

104.  431  U.S.  494  (1987). 

105.  Id. 

106.  414  U.S.  632  (1974). 

107.  Moore  v.  City  of  E.  Cleveland,  431  U.S.  at  499  (quoting  Cleveland  Bd.  of 
Educ.  V.  Lafleur,  414  U.S.  632,  639-40  (1974)). 

108.  Id. 

109.  Halet  v.  Wend  Inv.  Co.,  672  F.2d  1305,  1311  (1982). 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1035 

significant  deprivation" ''°  of  a  fundamental  right  had  taken  place,  and 
if  so  whether  the  child-exclusionary  policy  could  stand  up  to  the  strict 
scrutiny  test.'^^  These  same  arguments  sustained  Halet's  claim  of  dep- 
rivation of  rights  under  Section  1983  of  the  Civil  Rights  Act.'^^ 

Although  a  plaintiff  alleging  familial  discrimination  may  show  a 
Section  1983  or  fourteenth  amendment  deprivation  of  rights,  there  is 
yet  another  obstacle  to  overcome.  To  maintain  a  Section  1983  action, 
the  plaintiff  must  show  the  injury  was  rendered  under  color  of  state 
lawJ'^  A  plaintiff  must  show  state  involvement  to  have  a  successful 
fourteenth  amendment  due  process  cause  of  action. '^^  Essentially,  an 
action  under  color  of  state  law  and  state  action  are  the  same.^^^  Halet 
alleged  he  could  present  evidence  of  sufficient  state  action  in  his  particular 
case  and,  therefore,  the  court  directed  the  district  court  to  grant  Halet 
leave  to  amend  his  complaint  to  include  such  allegations.'*^  On  remand 
the  district  court  found  for  Halet,  awarding  him  attorney  fees  and  costs. "^ 

However,  many  plaintiffs  will  not  be  able  to  show  such  state  in- 
volvement because  most  apartment  complex  owners  have  little  contact 
with  the  state.  This  was  the  result  in  Langley  v.  Monumental  Corp.,^^^ 
where  the  district  court  held  that  there  was  not  sufficient  state  action 
when  a  county  ordinance  permits  familial  discrimination. ''^  The  court 


110.  Id.  (quoting  Hawaii  Boating  Ass'n  v.  Water  Transp.  Facilities  Div.,  651  F.2d 
661,  664-65  (9th  Cir.   1981)). 

111.  Halet,  672  F.2d  at  1311. 

112.  Id.  at  1309. 

113.  Id. 

114.  Id. 

115.  Id. 

116.  Id.  at  1310.  Specifically,  Mr.  Halet  alleged  the  following  state  involvement: 

(1)  the  County  owns  the  land  leased  to  Wend   [landlord]   for  the  apartment 
complex; 

(2)  the  County  acquired  and  prepared  the  land  using  federal  and  state  funds 
and  used  federal  services  in  dredging  the  harbor  in  the  redevelopment  area; 

(3)  the  purchase  of  land  was  part  of  a  large  redevelopment  program; 

(4)  the  County  leased  the  land  to  Wend  for  the  benefit  of  the  public  in  providing 
housing; 

(5)  the  lease  prohibits  race  or  religious  discrimination; 

(6)  the  County  oversees  the  development  of  the  area  and  the  design  of  the 
buildings  and  had  final  approval  of  all  plans; 

(7)  the  County  controls  the  use  and  purpose  of  the  apartment  and  the  rent 
charged; 

(8)  Wend  pays  a  percentage  of  the  rentals  to  the  County;  and 

(9)  Wend  must  abide  by  all  the  conditions  of  the  lease. 
Id. 

117.  Familial  Discrimination  in  Rental  Housing:  The  Halet  Decision,  28  St.  Louis 
U.L.J.   1085,  1090  n,36  (1984). 

118.  496  F.  Supp.   1144  (D.  Md.  1980). 

119.  Id.  at  1150. 


1036  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

further  stated  that  invocation  of  judicial  eviction  proceedings  by  the 
apartment  owner  would  be  sufficient  to  sustain  the  state  action  require- 
ment. ^^°  Thus,  the  Halet  decision  offers  only  a  small  portion  of  familial 
discrimination  victims  relief  under  the  fourteenth  amendment  Due  Process 
Clause'21  or  under  Section  1983  of  the  Civil  Rights  Act.'^z 

Many  plaintiffs  seeking  relief  from  child-exclusionary  polices  have 
pursued  a  cause  of  action  at  the  state  level. ^^^  One  of  the  earliest  state 
cases  involving  familial  discrimination  is  the  1946  case  of  Lamont  Building 
Co.  V.  Court .^^"^  In  Lamont,  the  tenants  rented  an  apartment  with  full 
knowledge  of  the  adults-only  poHcy  and  with  full  knowledge  that  the 
wife  was  pregnant.  When  the  child  was  born  and  began  residing  in  the 
apartment,  the  apartment  owner  advised  the  tenants  the  child  must  be 
removed  from  the  apartment  or  the  family  would  have  to  vacate  the 
premises.  Upon  the  tenants*  refusal  to  leave,  the  owner  filed  an  action 
in  forcible  entry  and  detainer. ^^^  The  Ohio  Supreme  Court  enforced  the 
adults-only  provision  stating  the  owner  of  the  realty  may  impose  con- 
ditions on  its  occupancy  so  long  as  the  conditions  do  not  contravene 
public  policy. '^^  The  court  further  held  the  child-exclusionary  policy  was 
not  injurious  to  the  public. '^^ 

A  California  Court  of  Appeals  reached  a  similar  result  in  Flowers 
V.  John  Burnham  &  Co.^^^  In  Flowers,  the  court  upheld  the  validity  of 
a  landlord's  policy  Umiting  child  tenants  to  girls  of  all  ages  and  boys 
under  five,  finding  the  policy  was  not  unconstitutionally  discriminatory 
and,  therefore,  it  did  not  violate  California's  Unruh  Act  which  guarantees 
equal  protection. '^^  The  Court  found  the  Unruh  Act  prevents  arbitrary 
discrimination;  however,  the  court  held  the  poUcy  in  question  was  not 


120.  Id.  at  1150-51. 

121.  U.S.  Const,  amend.  XIV,  §  1. 

122.  42  U.S.C.  §  3604  (1982). 

123.  See  generally  Marina  Point,  Ltd.  v.  Wolfson,  30  Cal.  3d  721,  640  P.2d  115, 
180  Cal.  Rptr.  496  (Richardson,  J.,  dissenting),  cert,  denied,  459  U.S.  858  (1982);  Flowers 
V.  John  Burnham  &  Co.,  21  Cal.  App.  3d  700,  98  Cal.  Rptr.  644  (1972). 

124.  147  Ohio  St.  183,  70  N.E.2d  447  (1946)  (Bell,  J.,  dissenting). 

125.  Id. 

126.  Id.  at  183,  70  N.E.2d  at  448. 

127.  Id. 

128.  21  Cal.  App.  3d  700,  98  Cal.  Rptr.  644  (1972). 

129.  Cal.  Civ.  Code  §§  51,  52  (West  1970).  Section  51  provided  in  part: 
All  persons  within  the  jurisdiction  of  this  State  are  free  and  equal,  and  no 
matter  what  their  race,  color,  religion,  ancestry,  or  national  origin  are  entitled 
to  the  full  and  equal  accommodations,  advantages,  facilities,  privileges,  or  services 
in  business  establishments  of  every  kind  whatsoever. 

Section  52  specified  the  damages  for  violation  of  §  51.  Flowers,  21  Cal.  App.  3d  at  702, 
98  Cal.  Rptr.  at  644-45. 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1037 

arbitrary  "[bjecause  the  independence,  mischievousness,  boisterousness, 
and  rowdyism  of  children  vary  by  age  and  sex."^^° 

Approximately  ten  years  after  the  Flowers  decision,  the  California 
Supreme  Court  decided  the  landmark  case  of  Marina  Point,  Ltd.  v. 
Wolfson,^^^  which  effectively  overruled  Flowers.  In  Marina  Point,  an 
apartment  complex  owner  altered  his  policy  to  ultimately  exclude  children 
after  plaintiffs  had  assumed  residency.  The  owner  allowed  the  children 
who  were  present  when  the  policy  took  effect  to  remain  there.  Plaintiffs 
had  their  first  child  after  the  policy  was  instituted.  The  owner  sought 
to  evict  plaintiffs  who  asserted  the  no-children  policy  violated  the  Cal- 
ifornia Unruh  Act.'^^  The  court  invalidated  the  policy  stating  'Hhe  Unruh 
Act  does  not  permit  a  business  enterprise  to  exclude  an  entire  class  of 
individuals  on  the  basis  of  a  generalized  prediction  that  the  class  *as  a 
whole'  is  more  likely  to  commit  misconduct  than  some  other  class  of 
the  public.  "•" 

In  its  discussion,  the  court  stated  that  if  owners  could  exclude  children 
from  rental  housing  under  the  Unruh  Act,  then  all  business  owners 
could  technically  exclude  children  from  their  enterprises. ^^"^  The  court 
distinguished  familial  discrimination  from  the  validity  of  age  discrimi- 
nation retirement  communities  noting  housing  for  the  elderly  meets  a 
specialized  social  need.  In  its  conclusion,  the  court  made  a  very  strong 
statement  against  familial  discrimination: 

A  society  that  sanctions  wholesale  discrimination  against  its  chil- 
dren in  obtaining  housing  engages  in  suspect  activity.  Even  the 
most  primitive  society  fosters  the  protection  of  its  young;  such 
a  society  would  hardly  discriminate  against  children  in  their  need 
for  shelter.  ...  To  permit  such  discrimination  is  to  approve  of 
widespread,  and  potentially  universal,  exclusion  of  children  from 
housing.  Neither  statute  nor  interpretation  of  statute,  however, 
sanctions  the  sacrifice  of  the  well-being  of  children  on  the  alter 
[sic]  of  a  landlord's  profit,  or  possibly  some  tenant's  conven- 
ience. ^^^ 

The  dissent,  however,  noted  the  poUcy  was  not  designed  to  provide 
** wholesale  discrimination  against  children"  but  to  recognize  there  are 
two  conflicting  interests  involved. '^^  Children  should  be  protected  from 


130.  Flowers  at  703,  98  Cal.  Rptr.  at  645. 

131.  30  Cal.  3d  721,  640  P.2d  115,  180  Cal.  Rptr.  496  (Richardson,  J.,  dissenting), 
cert,  denied,  459  U.S.  858  (1982). 

132.  Id.  at  724,  640  P.2d  at  118.  180  Cal.  Rptr.  at  499-500. 

133.  Id.  at  744,  640  P.2d  at  125,  180  Cal.  Rptr.  at  507. 

134.  Id.  at  739,  640  P.2d  at  126,  180  Cal.  Rptr.  at  508. 

135.  Id.  at  744,  640  P. 2d  at  129,  180  Cal.  Rptr.  at  510. 

136.  Id.  at  745,  640  P.2d  at  130,  180  Cal.  Rptr.  at  511. 


1038  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

widespread  housing  discrimination,  yet  adults  may  have  a  legitimate 
desire  to  live  in  a  child-free  environment. ^^^  The  dissent  stated  that  a 
"just  society  and  its  law  courts"  should  attempt  to  accommodate  both 
groups. ^^^  However,  the  Marina  Point  decision  effectively  prohibited 
famiUal  discrimination  poHcies  in  all  apartment  complexes  in  California. '^^ 

Although  some  plaintiffs  alleging  familial  discrimination  have  re- 
ceived reUef  through  judicial  decisions,  there  are  many  who  will  be 
unable  to  obtain  such  relief.  It  is  very  expensive  and  time  consuming 
to  initiate  legal  action.  Many  victims  of  famihal  discrimination  will  not 
be  able  to  finance  a  lawsuit  and,  therefore,  cannot  receive  judicial  relief. 
The  Fair  Housing  Act'"^^  provides  that  the  Secretary  of  Housing  and 
Urban  Development  (HUD)  will  investigate  allegations  of  housing  dis- 
crimination, and  also  provides  proper  enforcement  mechanisms. ^"^^  How- 
ever, HUD  receives  complaints  concerning  less  than  one  percent  of  the 
instances  of  discrimination  and  of  those  presented,  HUD  attempts  to 
resolve  only  one-third. ^'*^ 

4.  State  Legislative  Action. — At  the  present  time,  seventeen  states 
and  the  District  of  Columbia  have  legislation  prohibiting  or  limiting 
familial  discriminatory  practices.'"*^  These  statutes  vary  in  the  classes  they 
protect  and  the  exceptions  they  allow.  They  do  not  provide  adequate 
relief  in  the  areas  of  the  country  where  famiUes  with  children  face  a 
serious  plight. 

Many  of  the  statutes  prohibit  familial  discrimination,  but  provide 
many  exceptions.*"^  For  example,  the  Virginia  statute  provides  in  part: 
"It  shall  be  an  unlawful  discriminatory  housing  practice  because  of  .  .  . 


137.  Id. 

138.  Id. 

139.  See  San  Jose  Country  Club  Apartments  v.  County,  137  Cal.  App.  3d  951, 
187  Cal.  Rptr.  493  (1982). 

140.  42  U.S.C.  §§  3610-3611  (1982). 

141.  Id.  at  §§  3608,  3610. 

142.  The  Necessity  for  Shelter,  supra  note  10,  at  510  n.l79.  The  remaining  two- 
thirds  of  the  complaints  received  are  diverted  to  local  agencies. 

143.  Alaska  Stat.  §  18.80.240  (1986);  Ariz.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  §  33-1315  (1974); 
Cal.  Crv.  Code  §  51.2  (West  1982  &  Supp.  1988);  Conn.  Gen.  Stat.  Ann.  §  46a-64 
(West  1958  &  Supp.  1988);  Del.  Code  Ann.  tit.  25,  §  6503  (1974  &  Supp.  1986);  D.C. 
Code  Ann.  §  1-2511  (1987);  III.  Ann.  Stat.  ch.  68,  para.  3-104  (Smith-Hurd  1959  & 
Supp.  1988);  Me.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  tit.  14,  §  6027  (1964  &  Supp.  1987);  Mass.  Gen. 
Laws  Ann.  ch.  151B,  §  4  (West  1982  &  Supp.  1988);  Mich.  Comp.  Laws  Ann.  §  37.2502 
(West  1985);  Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  363.03  (West  1982  &  Supp.  1988);  Mont.  Code  Ann. 
§  49-2-305  (1987);  N.H.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  §  354-A:8  (1984);  N.J.  Stat.  Ann.  §  2A:42- 
101  (West  1952  &  Supp.  '1987-88);  N.Y.  Exec.  Law  §  296  (McKinney  1982  &  Supp. 
1988);  R.I.  Gen.  Laws  §  34-27.4  (1984  &  Supp.  1988);  Vt.  Stat.  Ann.  tit.  9  §  4505 
(1984  &  Supp.  1987);  Va.  Code  Ann.  §  36-88  (1984  &  Supp.  1988). 

144.  Alaska  Stat.  §  18.80.240  (1986);  Va.  Code  §  36-88  (1984  &  Supp.  1988). 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1039 

parenthood  ...  [t]o  refuse  to  sell  or  rent  after  the  making  of  a  bona 
fide  offer,  or  to  refuse  to  negotiate  for  the  sale  or  rental  of,  or  otherwise 
make  unavailable  or  deny,  a  dwelling. "^"^^  At  first  glance,  it  appears  the 
statute  totally  prohibits  familial  discrimination.  However,  the  statute 
continues  and  states:  ''Notwithstanding  the  foregoing  provisions,  it  shall 
not  be  an  unlawful  discriminatory  housing  practice  to  operate  an  all- 
adult  or  all-elderly  community.  .  .  ."^"^^  In  effect,  a  landlord  may  establish 
an  all-adult  community  if  it  is  specified  as  such.  If,  however,  the 
community  is  not  classified  as  an  all-adult  or  all-elderly  community,  it 
is  unlawful  to  practice  familial  discrimination.''*^ 

Some  of  the  state  statutes  do  not  place  the  prohibition  of  familial 
discrimination  within  their  fair  housing  law  section. '"^^  This  limits  the 
remedies  which  are  available  to  victims  of  child-exclusionary  policies. '^^ 
Other  statutes  place  familial  discrimination  within  the  civil  rights  section, 
but  in  sections  separate  from  the  main  text  where  other  protected  classes 
{e.g.,  race,  religion,  sex)  are  located. '^°  The  Illinois  statute  dealing  with 
familial  discrimination  provides  protection  only  for  children  under  the 
age  of  fourteen; '^'  New  Hampshire  exempts  communities  where  all  re- 
sidents are  at  least  forty-five  while  Michigan  sets  the  age  at  fifty.'" 

A  few  of  these  statutes  allow  familial  discriminatory  policies  in  a 
portion  of  the  buildings  of  a  large  community.'"  For  example,  in  Mas- 
sachusetts,  if  the  complex  contains   one  hundred  or  more  buildings, 


145.  Va.  Code  Ann.  §  36-88  (1984  &  Supp.  1988). 

146.  Id. 

147.  Alaska  Stat.  §  18.80.240  (1986);  Va.  Code  Ann.  §  36-88  (1984  &  Supp. 
1988). 

148.  Alaska  Stat.  §  18.80.240  (1986);  Ariz.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  §  33-1315  (1974); 
Cal.  Civ.  Code  §  51.2  (West  1982  &  Supp.  1988);  Del.  Code  Ann.  tit.  25  §  6503  (1974 
&  Supp.  1986);  Me.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  tit.  14  §  6027  (1964  &  Supp.  1987);  N.J.  Stat. 
Ann.  §  2A:42-101  (West  1952  &  Supp.  1987-88);  N.Y.  Exec.  Law  §  296  (McKinney  1982 
&  Supp.   1987). 

149.  Hearings,  supra  note  9,  at  398  stimony  of  James  B.  Morales,  Staff  Atty., 
Nat'l  Center  for  Youth  Law]. 

150.  Ariz.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  §  33-1315  (1974);  Cal.  Civ.  Code  §  51.2  (West  1982 
&  Supp.  1988);  Del.  Code  Ann.  tit.  25  §  6503  (1974  &  Supp.  1986);  III.  Ann.  Stat. 
ch.  68,  para.  3-104  (Smith-Hurd  1959  &  Supp.  1988);  Me.  Rev,  Stat.  Ann.  tit.  14,  § 
6027  (1964  &  Supp.  1987);  Mass.  Gen.  Laws  Ann.  ch.  15 IB  §  4  (West  1982  &  Supp. 
1987). 

151.  III.  Ann.  Stat.  ch.  68,  para.  3-104  (Smith-Hurd  1959  &  Supp.  1988). 

152.  Mich.  Comp.  Laws  Ann.  §  37-2502  (West  1985);  N.H.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  § 
354-A:8  (1984). 

153.  Mass.  Gen.  Laws  Ann.  ch.  15 IB,  §  4  (West  1982  &  Supp.  1988).  See  also 
Minn.  Stat.  Ann.  §  363.03  (West  1966  &  Supp.  1988)  (which  permits  familial  discrimination 
pohcies  in  one-third  of  a  complex's  buildings);  Me.  Rev.  Stat.  Ann.  tit.  14  §  6027  (1964 
&  Supp.  1987)  (which  permits  discriminatory  practices  in  25  percent  of  the  units  within 
a  complex). 


1040  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

children  may  be  excluded  from  one-half.  ^^"^  While  allowing  a  portion  of 
the  complex  to  restrict  children  attempts  to  recognize  the  needs  and 
desires  of  families  with  children  and  those  adults  who  wish  to  live  in 
a  child-free  environment,  these  methods  are  criticized  as  providing  a 
**major  loophole"  which  promotes  familial  discrimination.^" 

Some  familial  rights  advocates  criticize  the  state  statutes  alleging  the 
statutes  provide  weak  enforcement  procedures. *^^  The  majority  of  these 
laws  provide  a  private  cause  of  action  which  may  be  too  expensive  and 
time-consuming  for  the  injured  party  to  pursue. '^^  The  rehef  available 
to  the  plaintiff  is  inadequate  and  often  allows  the  discriminatory  policies 
to  continue,  and  worse,  the  plaintiff  and  family  may  still  be  without 
housing.  Many  states  have  established  administrative  agencies  to  handle 
the  complaints  and  enforcement  of  their  fair  housing  statutes. '^^  This 
alleviates  the  necessity  of  the  plaintiff  financing  a  lawsuit,  but  it  may 
not  be  effective.  For  example,  California  passed  its  statute  prohibiting 
familial  discrimination  in  1982,  but  the  administrative  agency  directed 
to  handle  these  matters  refused  to  take  action  for  over  two  years. ^^^ 

In  addition  to  the  civil  penalties,  some  state  statutes  impose  criminal 
penalties  for  violations. ^^°  These  may  be  the  least  effective  way  of 
achieving  enforcement  as  the  prosecuting  attorneys  may  be  reluctant  to 
prosecute  a  landlord,  and  this  type  of  case  will  not  demand  their  time 
when  compared  to  more  serious  crimes.'^' 

To  summarize,  state  legislative  schemes  provide  haphazard  protection 
for  families  with  children  who  face  discrimination  in  rental  housing. 
Some  allow  apartment  complexes  to  be  registered  as  all-adult  commu- 
nities, and  state  it  is  only  discrimination  if  communities  not  registered 
as  such  exclude  children.  ^^^  Others  only  prohibit  discrimination  against 
children  under  a  certain  age,  provide  exemptions  down  to  the  age  of 
forty-five,  or  allow  a  certain  percentage  of  buildings  within  a  complex 


154.  Mass.  Gen.  Laws  Ann.  ch.  151B  §  4  (West  1982  &  Supp.  1988). 

155.  Hearings,  supra  note  9,  at  396-97. 

156.  Id. 

157.  See,  e.g.,  Cal.  Civ.  Code  §  51.2  (West  1982  &  Supp.  1988);  Mich.  Comp. 
Laws  Ann.  §  37:2502  (West  1985);  N.Y.  Exec.  Law  §  296  (McKinney  1982  &  Supp. 
1987);  Va.  Code  Ann.  §  36-88  (1984  &  Supp.  1988). 

158.  See  generally  Cal.  Civ.  Code  §  51.2  (West  1982  &  Supp.  1988);  Conn.  Gen. 
Stat.  Ann.  §  46a-64  (West  1958  &  Supp.  1988);  Mont.  Code  Ann.  §  49-2-305  (1987). 

159.  Hearings,  supra  note  9,  at  400-01  n.57.  The  administrative  agency  claimed  they 
did  not  have  adequate  resources  or  lacked  legal  authority  to  handle  familial  discrimination 
complaints.  They  began  handling  such  complaints  after  receiving  political  pressure  and 
familial  discrimination  complaints  constituted  30  percent  of  the  housing  complaints  received. 

160.  Id.  at  396-97. 

161.  Id. 

162.  See  supra  note  147  and  accompanying  text. 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1041 

to  be  designated  as  adults-only.  Often,  the  enforcement  procedures  do 
not  provide  adequate  relief. 

III.    The  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988 

The  Amendments  to  the  Fair  Housing  Act  which  was  passed  on 
September  13,  1988,  added  families  with  children  to  the  hst  of  protected 
groups.^"  The  Amendments  also  modified  enforcement  procedures  to 
make  them  more  effective.  The  purpose  of  the  Amendments  was  to 
alleviate  the  problems  families  with  children  face  in  finding  adequate 
rental  housing.'^  However,  the  problems  faced  by  low  income  families 
with  children  will  not  be  alleviated  by  the  Amendments. 

A.    Modified  Procedures 

Prior  to  the  1988  Amendments,  all  discriminatory  housing  complaints 
referred  to  HUD  or  private  civil  actions  had  to  commence  within  180 
days.'^^  Under  the  terms  of  the  Amendments,  a  complaint  about  an 
apartment  owner  may  be  filed  with  HUD  within  one  year  of  the  alleged 
discriminatory  act.'^^  This  allows  the  aggrieved  person  to  take  care  of 
the  immediate  problem  of  locating  housing  before  proceeding  with  the 
complaint,  and  alleviates  the  problems  associated  with  a  short  statute 
of  limitations.  The  new  Act  shortens  the  amount  of  time  HUD  has  to 
investigate  a  complaint  after  its  receipt  from  thirty  to  ten  days.  The 
Act  still  provides  the  accused  apartment  owner  an  opportunity  to  file 
an  answer,  but  the  owner  must  now  file  an  answer  within  ten  days  of 
receiving  notification  of  the  complaint. '^^  The  Amendments  further  pro- 
vide HUD  must  complete  all  investigations  within  100  days.^^^ 

Under  both  the  prior  law  and  the  Amendments,  HUD  officials  may 
engage  in  conciliatory  actions  to  the  extent  feasible.  ^^^  The  conciliation 
agreement  may  provide  for  binding  arbitration  of  the  dispute. '^°  If  HUD 
or  the  aggrieved  person  can  show  that  the  owner  has  breached  the 
conciliation  agreement,  the  Attorney  General  may  commence  a  civil  action 


163.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  101-430,  102  Stat.  1622 
(1988). 

164.  See  Hearings,  supra  note  9. 

165.  42  U.S.C.  §§  3610,  3612  (1982). 

166.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  101-430,  102  Stat.  1624- 
25  (1988). 

167.  Id. 

168.  Id.  If  HUD  cannot  complete  the  investigation  within  the  requisite  100  days, 
the  appropriate  HUD  official  must  notify  both  parties  in  writing.  Id. 

169.  Id.  at  1626. 

170.  Id. 


1042  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

within  90  days  of  the  alleged  breach. '^^  The  Amendments  further  provide 
in  emergency  situations  HUD  may  initiate  a  civil  action  seeking  temporary 
relief  for  the  aggrieved  person  immediately  after  the  filing  of  the  com- 
plaint.'*^^ If  HUD  believes  no  conciUatory  agreement  will  be  reached, 
and  HUD  finds  reasonable  cause  to  believe  the  owner  has  discriminated, 
HUD  officials  are  to  turn  their  investigate  results  over  to  the  Attorney 
General  who  will  commence  civil  action  against  the  owner. '^^  These 
modifications  take  the  burden  of  financing  a  lawsuit  off  of  the  tenant 
and  provide  immediate  remedial  measures  if  the  aggrieved  person  is 
unable  to  locate  rental  housing. 

In  addition,  unless  an  election  otherwise  is  made,  an  administrative 
law  judge  appointed  pursuant  to  federal  regulations  presides  over  the 
hearing. '"^"^  This  hearing  must  be  held  within  120  days  of  the  filing  of 
the  charge. '^^  The  judge  must  report  a  decision  within  60  days  of 
completion  of  the  hearing. '^^  If  the  administrative  law  judge  finds  an 
apartment  owner  has  or  is  about  to  engage  in  discriminatory  activity, 
the  judge  * 'shall  promptly  issue  an  order  for  such  relief  as  may  be 
appropriate,  which  may  include  actual  damages  suffered  by  the  aggrieved 
person  and  injunctive  or  equitable  relief.  Such  order  may,  to  vindicate 
the  public  interest,  assess  a  civil  penalty  against  the  respondent.  .  .  ."'"'^ 
If  no  discriminatory  action  took  place  or  was  about  to  take  place,  the 
action  will  be  dismissed.  However,  the  lawsuit  will  injure  the  owner  to 
the  extent  he  had  to  finance  his  defense.  This  will  provide  a  deterrent 
against  the  temptation  of  engaging  in  discriminatory  practices. 

Any  party  to  the  final  order  of  the  administrative  law  judge  may 
obtain  judicial  review  of  the  order  pursuant  to  the  federal  regulations 
governing  the  appellate  process. '^^  Jurisdiction  for  judicial  review  is  in 
the  judicial  circuit  where  the  alleged  discriminatory  activity  occurred. '^^ 
If  HUD  officials  do  not  enforce  the  administrative  law  judge's  findings, 
nor  seek  judicial  review  of  the  findings,  the  party  entitled  to  rehef  may 
seek  a  decree  enforcing  the  order  from  the  Court  of  Appeals  in  the 


171.     Id. 
111.     Id. 

173.  Id. 

174.  5  U.S.C.  §  3105  (1982). 

175.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  101-430,  102  Stat.  1625, 

1630  (1988). 

176.  Id. 

111.  Id.  The  civil  penalties  begin  at  $10,000  and  range  to  $50,000,  the  amount 
assessed  increasing  if  the  owner  has  been  adjudicated  as  having  practiced  discriminatory 
housing  policies  within  the  recent  past.  Id. 

178.  28  U.S.C.  §  158  (1982). 

179.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1625, 

1631  (1988). 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1043 

circuit  where  the  violation  occurred. '^°  Again,  the  court  from  which 
judicial  review  is  sought  may  issue  temporary  orders  to  alleviate  any 
pressing  problems  faced  by  the  aggrieved  party. ^^^  The  Amendments 
further  provide  that  an  aggrieved  person  may  commence  a  civil  action 
in  a  district  court  without  utilizing  HUD  services  or  they  may  initiate 
such  an  action  on  their  own  for  the  breach  of  a  conciliation  agreement. '^^ 
The  tenant  must  finance  the  lawsuit  when  he  initiates  it.  The  aggrieved 
party  must  initiate  the  action  within  two  years  of  the  occurrence  of 
either  the  discriminatory  practice  or  the  breach  of  the  conciliation  agree- 
ment.'^^ However,  if  HUD  obtained  a  conciUation  agreement  or  an 
administrative  law  hearing  has  begun,  the  tenant  cannot  commence  a 
civil  action  in  a  court  of  law.'^'*  Under  both  the  Fair  Housing  Act  and 
the  Amendments,  there  is  a  provision  that  a  private  person  may  have 
the  court  appoint  an  attorney  for  him  if  the  requisite  need  can  be 
shown. '^^  The  same  relief  is  available  to  a  private  person  who  commences 
a  civil  action  as  there  is  for  a  person  who  proceeds  through  HUD.'^^ 

There  are  advantages  and  disadvantages  with  a  tenant  utilizing  HUD's 
services  and  with  a  tenant  filing  a  private  action.  Allowing  HUD  to 
investigate,  attempt  conciUation,  or  the  Attorney  General  to  file  an  action 
against  the  apartment  owner  removes  the  expense  of  financing  a  lawsuit 
from  a  tenant's  shoulders.  This  provides  a  way  for  many  low  income 
persons  to  be  heard.  The  advantage  of  filing  a  private  action  is  that 
the  plaintiff  is  able  to  maintain  more  control  over  the  suit.  For  most 
tenants,  the  decision  will  rest  on  the  amount  of  money  necessary  to 
maintain  a  cause  of  action. 

The  Amendments  provide  that  the  Attorney  General  may  commence 
a  civil  action  in  district  court  when  he  believes  discriminatory  practices 
prohibited  by  the  Fair  Housing  Act  are  taking  place  or  have  taken 
place. '^^  The  Attorney  General  may  also  intervene  in  an  action  initiated 
by  a  private  person  if  "the  case  is  of  general  pubhc  importance. "'^^  In 
a  civil  action  maintained  privately  or  by  the  Attorney  General,  the  court 
may  order  injunctive  or  other  preventive  reHef,  award  monetary  damages 
and  access  civil  penalties. '^^ 


180.  Id.  at  1632. 

181.  Id. 

182.  Id.  at  1633.  In  all  matters  commenced  under  the  Fair  Housing  Act,  the  amount 
in  controversy  requirement  is  waived.  Id. 

183.  Id. 

184.  Id. 

185.  Id. 

186.  Id. 

187.  Id.  at  1626. 

188.  Id.  at  1633. 

189.  Id.  at  1636.  The  Amendments  provide  that  the  Court: 


1044  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

The  overall  purpose  behind  the  1988  Amendments  is  to  include 
families  with  children  in  the  list  of  classes  protected  from  housing 
discrimination  and  to  increase  the  ease  and  effectiveness  of  the  enforce- 
ment measures. '^^  This  has  been  accomplished  by  lengthening  the  time 
in  which  to  file  the  action  and  decreasing  the  time  in  which  HUD  has 
to  respond.  Under  the  terms  of  the  Amendments,  the  parties  may  agree 
to  submit  to  binding  arbitration  or  the  matters  may  be  heard  by  ad- 
ministrative law  judges  with  a  provision  for  judicial  review.  Civil  action 
may  be  commenced  upon  the  breach  of  a  concihation  agreement,  by  a 
private  person  who  chooses  to  proceed  without  HUD's  services,  or  by  the 
Attorney  General  if  there  is  reasonable  cause  to  beheve  discriminatory 
practices  are  taking  place.  The  Amendments  provide  for  immediate  relief, 
when  necessary,  injunctive  relief,  equitable  relief,  monetary  damages  and 
civil  penalties,  the  amount  of  which  may  increase  if  the  owner  has 
violated  the  Fair  Housing  Act  in  recent  years. 

B.     Shortcomings  of  the  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988 

As  has  been  estabhshed  previously,  there  are  areas  of  the  country 
where  families  with  children  face  serious  problems  in  locating  adequate 
rental  housing. '^^  The  1988  Amendments'^^  to  the  Fair  Housing  Act'^^ 
totally  prohibit  child-exclusionary  policies  nationwide.'^"*  However,  such 
broad-sweeping  legislation  is  not  necessary  nor  is  it  appropriate.  Initially, 
one  must  realize  that  child-exclusionary  policies  have  not  arisen  out  of 
hatred.  FamiUal  rights  advocates  have  placed  famihal  discrimination  on 
the  same  level  as  racial  discrimination.  For  example,  the  majority  in 
Marina  Point  stated,  ''[t]o  permit  such  discrimination  is  to  approve  of 
widespread,  and  potentially  universal,  exclusion  of  children  from  housing. 
Neither  statute  nor  interpretation  of  statute,   however,   sanctions  the 


(A)  may  award  such  preventive  relief,  including  a  permanent  or  temporary 
injunction,  restraining  order,  or  other  order  against  the  person  responsible  for 
a  violation  of  this  title  as  is  necessary  to  assure  the  full  enjoyment  of  the  rights 
granted  by  this  title, 

(B)  may  award  such  other  relief  as  the  court  deems  appropriate,  including 
monetary  damages  to  persons  aggrieved,  and 

(C)  may  to  vindicate  the  public  interest,  assess  a  civil  penalty  against  the 
respondent  - 

(i)  in  an  amount  not  exceeding  $50,000  for  a  first  violation;  and 

(ii)  in  an  amount  not  exceeding  $100,000  for  any  subsequent  violation. 

190.  Id.  at  1624-36. 

191.  See  supra  note  6  and  accompanying  text. 

192.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1619- 
1636  (1988). 

193.  42  U.S.C.  §  3601-3631  (1982). 

194.  Pub.  L.  No.  100-340,  102  Stat.   1625  (1988). 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1045 

sacrifice  of  the  well-being  of  children  on  the  alter  [sic]  of  a  landlord's 
profit,  or  possibly  some  tenants'  convenience."'^^ 

Alternatively,  the  Marina  Point  dissenting  opinion  recognizes  there 
are  two  sides  to  every  issue,  and  that  if  the  question  were  phrased 
differently,  the  response  would  not  be  the  same.'^^  Additionally,  the 
dissent  states  there  should  be  an  attempt  to  accommodate  both  families 
with  children  and  those  wanting  to  live  in  an  all-adult  community.  The 
dissent  in  Marina  Point  notes  that  rather  than  asking  if  we  should 
approve  ''whole  sale  discrimination  against  children,"'^  the  question 
could  be  phrased  "do  our  middle  aged  or  older  citizens,  having  worked 
long  and  hard,  having  raised  their  own  children,  having  paid  both  their 
taxes  and  their  dues  to  society  retain  a  right  to  spend  their  remaining 
years  in  a  relatively  quiet,  peaceful  and  tranquil  environment  of  their 
own  choice? '"^^  The  dissent  indicates  a  compromise  between  the  two 
extremes  would  be  more  appropriate. 

Under  the  Amendments,  retirement  communities  may  continue  to 
exclude  children. '^^  However,  the  Amendments  ignore  the  rights  and 
needs  of  young  and  middle-aged  adults  without  children.  Statistics  show 
that  adults  without  children  occupy  over  two-thirds  of  the  rental  units^°^ 
and  that  persons  under  age  thirty-five  occupy  over  one-half  of  these 
households. ^°'  This  Note  does  not  dispute  the  necessity  for  legislation 
limiting  the  number  of  apartment  units  which  exclude  children;  what 
the  Note  disputes  is  its  total  prohibition  of  all-adult  apartment  com- 
munities. This  total  prohibition  is  too  broad  when  adults  without  children 
occupy  67.6  percent  of  the  rental  units  and  there  is  no  substantial  data 
measuring  the  extent  of  familial  discrimination  nationwide. ^'^^ 

Studies  have  documented  that  the  families  with  children  facing  the 
greatest  problem  in  locating  rental  housing  are  low  income  families. ^°^ 
The  California  Supreme  Court  stated  that  landlords  have  instituted  fa- 
milial discriminatory  policies  so  that  they  may  charge  a  premium  for 
their  rental  units. ^^  However,  the  latter  proposition  is  not  an  accurate 
assessment.  The  ISR  study  completed  in  1980  stated: 

195.  Marina  Point,  Ltd.  v.  Wolfson,  30  Cal.  3d  745,  745,  640  P.2d  115,  129,  180 
Cal.  Rptr.  496,  511  (Richardson,  J.,  dissenting),  cert,  denied,  459  U.S.  858  (1982). 

196.  Id.  at  745,  640  P.2d  at  130,  180  Cal.  Rptr.  at  511  (Richardson,  J.,  dissenting). 

197.  Id. 

198.  Id. 

199.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.  100-430,  102  Stat.  1619- 
1636  (1988). 

2(K).  See  supra  note  57  and  accompanying  text. 

201.  See  supra  note  58  and  accompanying  text. 

202.  See  supra  note  55  and  accompanying  text. 

203.  See  supra  notes  73-75  and  accompanying  text.  See  also  Hearings,  supra  note 
9,  at  373  stimony  of  James  B.  Morales,  Staff  Atty,  Nat'l  Center  for  Youth  Law]. 

204.  Marina  Point,  Ltd.  v.  Wolfson,  30  Cal.  3d  271,  744,  640  P.2d  115,  129,  180 
Cal.  Rptr.  496,  511  (Richardson,  J.,  dissenting),  cert,  denied,  459  U.S.  858  (1982). 


1046  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

Families  with  children  pay  a  significantly  higher  monthly  rent 
than  families  without  children,  primarily  because  they  tend  to 
occupy  larger  units.  When  the  number  of  bedrooms  and  the 
occupancy  per  unit  are  held  constant  no  significant  differences 
are  found  between  the  monthly  rents  of  the  two  groups.  The 
higher  cost  of  rental  housing  for  families  with  children  is  at- 
tributable to  the  greater  number  of  persons  in  the  household 
and  the  size  of  the  unit  rented. ^^^ 

The  all-adult  units  which  command  such  high  prices  often  offer 
extra  facilities.  Adult  communities  are  often  equipped  with  attractive 
nuisances  such  as  saunas,  whirlpools,  exercise  facilities  and  swimming 
pools,  which  account  for  the  increased  rental  price. ^°^  Even  when  these 
apartments  can  no  longer  exclude  children,  the  rental  price  will  not 
decrease  enough  to  be  within  the  affordable  price  range  for  low  income 
families.  Until  owners  build  more  low  and  moderately  priced  rental 
housing,  low  income  families  will  be  unable  to  locate  adequate  housing. 

Additionally,  at  least  one  study  stated  that  minority  groups  and 
households  headed  by  women  feel  the  greatest  impact  of  exclusionary 
policies. ^^^  However,  the  ISR  study  concluded  this  is  not  the  case.^^^ 
Logic  explains  the  differing  results.  Minorities  and  female  head  of  house- 
hold families  tend  to  fall  within  the  lower  income  brackets,  and  when 
the  study  accounts  for  those  variables,  the  disparities  between  minorities, 
women  and  the  general  rental  population  come  close  to  disappearing. ^°^ 

The  drafters  of  the  Amendments  failed  to  reaUze  that  many  apartment 
complexes  have  been  designed  and  built  for  adults-only  and,  therefore, 
are  inherently  dangerous  to  children.  The  dissent  in  Marina  recognized 
this  danger  stating: 

The  evidence  before  the  trial  court  established,  in  substance,  that 
Marina  Point  was  designed  and  constructed  for  the  purpose  of 
providing  all-adult  rental  housing,  and  that  as  such  its  facilities 
were  ill-adapted  for  use  by  children.  .  .  .  [T]he  use  of  existing 
facilities  at  Marina  Point  by  children  when  playing  results  in 
substantial  danger  both  to  themselves  and  to  adult  tenants  alike. ^'° 


205.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4,  at  72. 

206.  Marina  Point,  Ltd.,  at  744,  640  P. 2d  at  130,  180  Cal.  Rptr.  at  511  (Richardson, 
J.,  dissenting). 

207.  J.  Greene  &  G.  Blake,  supra  note  68,  at  72. 

208.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4,  at  72. 

209.  See  id. 

210.  Marina  Point,  Ltd.,  at  746,  640  P. 2d  at  130-31,   180  Cal.  Rptr.  at  512  (Ri- 
chardson, J.,  dissenting). 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1047 

Although  all  the  dangers  faced  by  children  can  never  be  eliminated, 
those  apartment  complexes  designed  exclusively  for  adults  should  remain 
just  that,  all-adult  communities. 

The  1988  Amendments  could  be  the  impetus  for  apartment  owners 
to  withdraw  or  remain  out  of  the  rental  market.  From  1970  to  1976, 
owners  removed  approximately  250,000  rental  units  which  were  con- 
structed before  1965  from  the  market  each  year.^'*  This  phenomenon, 
combined  with  the  decreased  number  of  multifamily  units  on  which 
construction  has  begun, ^'^  causes  increased  problems  for  potential  tenants. 
If  developers  and  landlords  perceive  children  as  a  problem  to  avoid, 
and  they  realize  they  cannot  avoid  children,  they  will  remove  their  units 
from  the  rental  market  or  forego  construction. 

In  parts  of  the  country,  there  is  a  severe  problem  confronting  families 
with  children  who  are  attempting  to  locate  rental  housing. ^'^  However, 
no  statistics  measure  the  extent  of  the  problem  nationwide.  Lower  income 
families  face  the  gravest  difficulty  in  locating  adequate  rental  housing. 
The  1988  Amendments  to  the  Fair  Housing  Act  in  part  eliminate  familial 
discrimination.^''*  They  will  not,  however,  eliminate  the  problems  faced  by 
low  income  families  since  it  will  not  significantly  lower  rental  costs.  In 
addition,  the  drafters  of  the  Amendments  failed  to  recognize  the  needs 
and  desires  of  the  greatest  portion  of  the  rental  population — adults 
without  children.  Finally,  the  drafters  of  the  Amendments  did  not  con- 
sider the  inherent  dangers  children  may  face  when  they  occupy  apartments 
which  have  been  designed  and  built  for  an  all-adult  clientele. 

IV.     Shortcomings  of  Total  Prohibition  of  All  Adult  Apartment 

Communities 

Familial  discrimination,  unlike  racial  discrimination,  is  not  based  on 
hatred.  There  are  legitimate  reasons  why  adults  desire  to  live  in  a  child- 
free  environment  and  why  apartment  owners  want  to  restrict  their  rental 
units  to  adults-only.  Rather  than  assuming  such  desires  are  based  on 
hatred  or  greed.  Congress  and  the  courts  should  look  at  both  sides  of 
the  issue. 

A.     The  Rights  of  Adults  to  Live  in  a  Child-Free  Environment 

The  New  Jersey  Supreme  Court  stated  that  '*[t]here  cannot  be  the 
slightest  doubt  that  shelter,  along  with  food,  are  the  most  basic  human 


211.  A.  Downs,  supra  note  3,  at  40. 

212.  See  supra  notes  44-45  and  accompanying  text. 

213.  See  supra  note  6  and  accompanying  text. 

214.  Fair  Housing  Amendments  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.   100-430,  102  Stat.   1619-36 
(1988). 


1048  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

needs.  ...  It  is  plain  beyond  dispute  the  proper  provision  for  adequate 
housing  of  all  categories  of  people  is  certainly  an  absolute  essential  in 
promotion  of  the  general  welfare.  .  .  .*'^^^  The  supporters  of  all-adult 
communities  are  not  attempting  to  deny  families  with  children  a  place 
to  live,  but  are  asserting  that  they  also  have  rights,  one  of  which  is  to 
live  in  a  child-free  environment  if  they  so  desire. 

Over  two-thirds  of  the  occupied  rental  units  have  no  residents  under 
the  age  of  eighteen,^^^  yet  the  majority  of  the  rental  population  are  not 
allowed  to  choose  their  living  environment  under  terms  of  the  1988 
Amendments.  In  1972,  the  California  Supreme  Court  stated  that  children 
are  more  independent,  boisterous,  and  rowdy.^'^  This  is  only  one  reason 
adults  without  children  choose  to  live  in  an  all-adult  community. 

In  addition,  it  may  be  much  easier  to  find  amenities  such  as  saunas, 
whirlpools,  swimming  pools,  and  exercise  facilities  in  all-adult  com- 
munities. These  amenities  become  attractive  nuisances  when  children  are 
present.  If  children  are  allowed  to  become  residents  of  apartment  com- 
plexes with  such  facilities,  owners  may  limit  the  hours  of  availability 
or  eliminate  such  facihties. 

Furthermore,  the  Department  of  Commerce  has  documented  that 
certain  crimes  associated  with  residences  are  highly  likely  to  be  committed 
by  minors.^'^  Specifically,  1988  statistics  show  that  32  percent  of  all 
thefts,  35.9  percent  of  all  burglaries,  40.4  percent  of  all  arsons,  and 
42.8  percent  of  all  vandalism  is  committed  by  persons  under  the  age 
of  eighteen. ^'^ 

In  Halet  v.  Wend  Investment  Co.,^^^  the  Ninth  Circuit  held  that 
"the  right  of  family  members  to  live  together  is  part  of  the  fundamental 
right  to  privacy.  "^^'  However,  adults  without  children  have  a  similar 
right  to  privacy  when  deciding  where  to  live  their  lives  and  a  similar 
right  to  equal  protection  under  the  fourteenth  amendment  of  the  Con- 
stitution. The  Supreme  Court  in  Eisenstadt  v.  Baird^^^  held  that  single 
people  cannot  be  treated  differently  than  married  people  as  far  as  the 
distribution  of  contraceptives  is  concerned. ^^^  The  Court  held: 


215.  Southern  Burlington  County  NAACP  v.  Mount  Laurel,  336  A.2d  713,   727 
(N.J.),  cert,  denied,  423  U.S.  808  (1975). 

216.  See  supra  note  57  and  accompanying  text. 

217.  Flowers  v.  John  Burnham  &  Co.,  21  Cal.  App.  3d  700,  98  Cal.  Rptr.  644 
(1972). 

218.  U.S.  Dept.  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census.  Statistical  Abstract  of 
THE  United  States,  165,  278  (108  ed.  1988). 

219.  Id. 

220.  672  F.2d  1305  (9th  Cir.  1982). 

221.  Id.   at  1311. 

222.  405  U.S.  438  (1972). 

223.  Id. 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1049 

If  under  Griswold  the  distribution  of  contraceptives  to  married 
persons  cannot  be  prohibited,  a  ban  on  distribution  to  unmarried 
persons  would  be  equally  impermissible.  ...  [I]f  the  right  of 
privacy  means  anything,  it  is  the  right  of  the  individual,  married 
or  single,  to  be  free  from  unwanted  governmental  intrusion  into 
matters  so  fundamentally  affecting  a  person  as  the  decision 
whether  to  bear  or  beget  a  child. ^^"^ 

Similarly,  single  people  should  not  be  treated  differently  than  families 
with  children  and  should  be  granted  the  fundamental  right  to  privacy 
and,  therefore,  the  ability  to  decide  where  and  in  what  manner  they 
will  live. 

Tenants  raised  the  right  to  privacy  and  equal  protection  arguments 
in  San  Jose  Country  Club  Apartments  v.  County  of  Santa  ClaraP^  The 
court  rejected  both  arguments  stating  the  cause  of  action  involved  no 
fundamental  right.^^^  However,  in  Halet,^^^  the  Ninth  Circuit  held  that 
*'[f]amily  life,  in  particular  the  right  of  family  members  to  live  together, 
is  part  of  the  fundamental  right  of  privacy.  "^^^  Therefore,  the  right  to 
privacy  and  the  equal  protection  argument  of  adults  without  children 
merit  discussion. 

The  Court  of  Appeals  for  the  District  of  Columbia  stated  '*[l]iberty 
under  law  extends  to  the  full  range  of  conduct  which  the  individual  is 
free  to  pursue. "^^^  Thus,  liberty  extends  to  one's  right  to  decide  how 
and  where  he  will  live.  In  Shelton  v.  Tucker,^^^  the  Supreme  Court  held: 

[E]ven  though  the  governmental  purpose  be  legitimate  and  sub- 
stantial, that  purpose  cannot  be  pursued  by  means  that  broadly 
stifle  fundamental  personal  liberties  when  the  end  can  be  more 
narrowly  achieved.  The  breadth  of  legislative  abridgement  must 
be  viewed  in  the  light  of  less  drastic  means  for  achieving  the 
same  basic  purpose. ^^* 

The  1988  Amendments  constitute  a  total  ban  on  all-adult  apartment 
communities  with  an  exception  for  retirement  communities. ^^^  Studies 


224.  Id.  at  453. 

225.  137  Cal.  App.  3d  948,  198  Cal.  Rptr.  493  (1982).  This  case  was  decided  shortly 
after  Marina  Point,  Ltd. 

226.  Id.  at  954,  198  Cal.  Rptr.  at  496. 

227.  672  F.2d  1305  (1982). 

228.  Id.  at  1311. 

229.  Ricks  v.  District  of  Columbia,  414  F.2d  1097,  1101  (D.C.  Cir.  1968)  (quoting 
Boiling  V.  Sharpe,  347  U.S.  497  (1954)). 

230.  Shelton  v.  Tucker,  364  U.S.  479  (1960). 

231.  Id.  at  488  (footnotes  omitted). 

232.  Fair  Housing  Amendment  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.   100-340,  102  Stat.   1619-36 
(1988). 


1050  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

have  not  documented  that  families  with  children  face  serious  problems 
finding  adequate  rental  housing  nationwide.^"  However,  studies  have 
documented  that  67.6  percent  of  all  rental  households  have  no  residents 
under  the  age  of  eighteen^^"^  and  low  income  families  with  children  face 
a  serious  problem  locating  adequate  rental  housing. ^^^  Therefore,  the 
Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988  stifles  liberty,  a  fundamental 
right. 

The  one  exception  to  the  ban  on  child-exclusionary  policies  is  re- 
tirement communities. ^^^  In  Taxpayers  Association  of  Weymouth  Town- 
ship, Inc.  V.  Weymouth  Township, ^^'^  the  New  Jersey  Supreme  Court 
recognized  that  the  elderly  were  a  class  deserving  special  treatment. ^^^ 
The  court  noted  that  the  elderly  have  specialized  housing  needs  because 
they  have  fixed  and  limited  incomes. ^^^  Although  familial  rights  advocates 
state  that  child-exclusionary  policies  are  the  reason  so  many  families 
cannot  locate  adequate  housing,  the  real  cause  of  the  problem  is  limited 
income. ^"^^  Rather  than  prohibiting  all-adult  apartment  communities  and 
adversely  affecting  the  rights  of  over  two-thirds  of  the  rental  households, 
the  legislation  should  turn  its  efforts  toward  providing  adequate  rental 
housing  within  the  economic  means  of  low  income  families. 

B.    Apartment  Owners  and  the  Free  Enterprise  System 

In  America's  capitalistic  society,  supply  increases  to  meet  demand. ^^' 
Therefore,  if  all-adult  communities  eventually  become  too  widespread, 
and  families  with  children  cannot  locate  housing  due  to  exclusionary 
policies,  apartment  owners  will  invest  in  apartment  complexes  which 
welcome  children.  The  supply  will  fit  itself  to  the  needs  of  the  demand. 
However,  it  will  take  time  to  achieve  the  balance.  In  some  areas  of  the 
country,  families  with  children  face  severe  problems  and  the  requisite 
time  is  not  available.  Thus,  some  form  of  legislation  is  necessary,  but 
it  need  not  be  as  prohibitive  as  the  1988  Amendments. 

The  court  in  Marina  Point  characterized  landlords  who  exclude 
children  as  being  greedy, ^'^^  and  the  connotation  was  that  these  landlords 


233.  See  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra' noiQ  4. 

234.  See  supra  note  57  and  accompanying  text. 

235.  See  supra  note  203  and  accompanying  text. 

236.  Fair  Housing  Amendment  of  1988,  Pub.  L.  No.   100-430,   102  Stat.   1619-36 
(1988). 

237.  71  N.J.  249,  364  A.2d  1016  (1976),  cert,  denied,  430  U.S.  977  (1977). 

238.  Id. 

239.  Id.  at  267-68,  364  A.2d  at  1026. 

240.  See  supra  notes  56-61  and  accompanying  text. 

241.  R.  McKenzie,  Economics  44-66  (1986). 

242.  Marina  Point,  Ltd.  v.  Wolfson,  30  Cal.  3d  721,  745,  640  P.2d  115,  129,  180 
Cal.  Rptr.  496,  511  (Richardson,  J.,  dissenting),  cert,  denied,  459  U.S.  858  (1982). 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1051 

are  evil.^'*^  However,  there  are  legitimate  reasons  why  landlords  want  to 
restrict  their  apartments  to  all  adults.  Initially,  familial  rights  advocates 
must  recognize  that  landlords  are  first  and  foremost  business  persons 
who  provide  rental  housing  to  make  a  profit,  a  reasonable  endeavor. 

With  the  decline  in  the  number  of  women  who  have  children,  and 
the  increase  in  the  number  of  two-career  families, ^'*^  landlords  saw  an 
increased  demand  for  all-adult  communities.  Landlords  and  land  de- 
velopers responded  by  providing  apartment  communities  which  restricted 
or  excluded  children. ^''^  The  owners  designed  and  developed  many  of 
these  complexes  for  adults-only.^"^^  Apartment  owners  realize  that  they 
are  held  to  a  higher  standard  of  care  in  negligence  actions  when  children 
are  present  because  accidents  concerning  children  are  foreseeable  and, 
therefore,  have  a  legitimate  interest  in  excluding  or  restricting  children. ^'^^ 
Thus,  a  landlord's  interest  in  excluding  children  from  rental  units  is  a 
legitimate  economic  one  not  solely  motivated  by  greed. 

There  are  no  statistics  reflecting  whether  or  not  the  presence  of 
children  leads  to  increased  maintenance  costs  and  increased  insurance 
costs.  However,  the  ISR  study  reflects  that  81  percent  of  the  landlords 
surveyed  felt  that  higher  maintenance  costs  were  a  problem  associated 
with  child  tenants  and  38  percent  felt  higher  insurance  costs  were  a 
similar  problem, ^"^^  When  one  combines  these  factors  with  rents  which 
are  inadequate  to  meet  construction  and  operating  costs, ^"^^  landlords 
face  an  economically  infeasible  situation.  If  their  operating  costs  increase. 


243.  Id. 

244.  See  supra  note  49  and  accompanying  text. 

245.  See  id. 

246.  See  supra  note  206  and  accompanying  text. 

247.  See  generally  D.  Dobbs,  R.  Keeton  &  D.  Owen,  Prosser  and  Keeton  on 
Torts  200-01  (5th  ed.  1984)  ("The  question  comes  down  essentially  to  one  of  whether 
the  foreseeable  risk  outweighs  the  utihty  of  the  actor's  conduct.")  Id.  Kopera  v.  Moschella, 
400  F.  Supp.  131  (S.D.  Miss.  1975)  (complex  owners  were  negligent  in  faiUng  to  have  a 
lifeguard  on  duty  at  the  pool,  to  fence  the  area  and  secure  it  with  a  gate,  to  cover  the 
pool  during  time  when  the  weather  was  not  conducive  to  its  use  and  to  maintain  rescue 
equipment  in  the  area  of  the  pool;  their  negligence  was  the  proximate  cause  of  death); 
Lidster  v.  Jones,  176  Ga.  App.  392,  336  S.E.2d  287  (1985)  (landlord  held  liable  for  dog 
biting  tenant  when  he  knew  of  dog's  vicious  propensities  but  did  nothing  to  keep  dog 
out  of  complex's  common  areas);  Acosta  v.  Irdank  Realty  Corp.,  38  Misc.  2d  859,  238 
N.Y.S.2d  713  (1963)  (landlord  held  liable  for  child  eating  lead  paint  chips). 

248.  R.  Marans  &  M.  Colten,  supra  note  4  at  64-65,  Table  VI-I.  Additionally, 
this  author  conducted  a  telephone  survey  of  insurance  agencies  in  Indianapolis,  Indiana, 
who  provide  liability  insurance  for  apartment  complex  owners.  Of  the  18  who  stated  they 
take  the  presence  of  children  into  account,  the  policy  price  was  an  average  of  14  percent 
less  expensive  when  children  were  excluded.  Six  other  companies  reported  they  turned  the 
information  over  to  their  underwriters  who  determine  the  policy  price.  The  underwriters 
take  into  consideration  the  presence  of  children  and  attractive  nuisances. 

249.  See  supra  note  44  and  accompanying  text. 


1052  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

and  they  are  held  to  a  higher  standard  of  care  due  to  the  presence  of 
children,  they  will  convert  the  units  into  condominiums  or  remove  them 
from  the  rental  market.  The  trend  has  been  toward  an  increase  in  the 
number  of  units  being  removed  from  the  rental  market  in  recent  years. ^^° 

Further,  it  is  unrealistic  to  believe  that  the  prohibition  of  child- 
exclusionary  policies  will  increase  the  number  of  rental  units  which  are 
within  the  economic  means  of  low  income  families.  Landlords  and 
developers  must  be  able  to  charge  prices  which  will  meet  their  operating 
costs  and  generate  a  profit.  Studies  have  shown  that  when  occupancy 
per  unit  and  the  number  of  bedrooms  per  unit  are  held  constant,  there 
is  no  significant  difference  in  the  monthly  rent  charged  for  families  with 
children  and  those  without  children.^^'  Thus,  prohibiting  familial  dis- 
crimination will  not  change  the  composition  of  the  rental  market,  rental 
prices  will  not  decrease  significantly,  and  low  income  families  will  still 
experience  problems  locating  adequate  rental  housing. 

To  summarize,  the  free  enterprise  system  would  eventually  solve  the 
problem  as  apartment  owners  would  change  the  nature  of  their  supply 
to  meet  the  current  demand.  However,  in  some  areas  of  the  country, 
this  process  would  be  too  time  consuming.  Genuine  economic  interest, 
not  greed,  generates  the  increased  instances  of  familial  discrimination. 
Increased  restrictions  on  landlords  and  higher  prices  associated  with  child 
tenants  will  prompt  some  landlords  to  take  their  rental  units  off  the 
market  and  may  discourage  developers  from  entering  the  market.  In 
addition,  the  Amendments  will  not  result  in  lowering  rental  prices  to  a 
level  within  the  economic  means  of  low  income  families. 

V.    Alternatives  to  the  1988  Amendments 

Rather  than  a  total  prohibition  of  familial  discrimination,  the  gov- 
ernment should  institute  a  less  restrictive  provision  which  would  recognize 
both  factors.  An  alternative  is  to  allow  a  percentage  of  all-adult  com- 
munities based  on  the  population  of  a  given  area.  Alcoholic  beverage 
commissions  work  on  this  type  of  quota  system.  This  Note  will  utilize 
the  Indiana  Alcoholic  Beverage  Laws.^"  The  Indiana  Code  provides  for 
issuance  of  five  types  of  alcoholic  beverage  permits. ^^^  The  number  of 
each  type  of  permit  issued  is  based  on  the  population  figures  of  the 
county,  city,  or  town  in  question. ^^^^  For  example,  '*the  commission  may 
issue  only  one  [1]  package  Hquor  store  dealer's  permit  in  an  incorporated 


250.  See  supra  note  211  and  accompanying  text. 

251.  See  supra  note  205  and  accompanying  text. 

252.  IND.  Code  §  7.1-3-22  (1988). 

253.  iND.  Code  §§  7.1-3-22-1  to  -5  (1988). 

254.  Id. 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1053 

city  or  town  for  each  five  thousand  [5,000]  persons,  or  fraction  thereof, 
within  the  incorporated  city  or  town."^^^  The  commission  bases  the 
population  figures  on  reports  issued  by  the  federal  government. ^^^ 

There  have  been  few  suits  filed  in  this  area,^^"^  suggesting  the  quota 
method  is  an  effective  means  of  limiting  permits.  In  Smock  v.  Coots, ^^^ 
the  Indiana  Court  of  Appeals  upheld  the  commission's  denial  of  a  package 
store  permit  recognizing  that  the  quota  statute  set  the  upper,  not  the 
lower  limits,  on  the  number  of  permits  which  could  be  issued. ^^^  This 
allows  for  flexibility  in  the  system  so  that  area-specific  problems  can 
be  addressed. 

The  legislature  could  establish  a  system  similar  to  Indiana's  alcoholic 
beverage  permit  quota  system  to  regulate  the  number  of  all-adult  apart- 
ment complexes  allowed.  The  statute  would  require  an  applicant  receiving 
a  permit  to  pay  fees  established  by  the  statute. ^^°  Those  obtaining  such 
a  permit  could  redeem  the  cost  through  lower  maintenance  costs,  lower 
insurance  costs,  or  they  could  pass  the  cost  on  to  tenants  willing  to  pay 
more  to  live  in  a  child-free  environment.  In  those  areas  where  the  number 
of  apartment  owners  desiring  such  a  permit  would  exceed  the  number 
of  authorized  permits,  HUD  could  hold  an  auction,^^'  or  the  apartment 


255.  IND.  Code  §  7.1-3-22-5  (1988). 

256.  iND.  Code  §  7.1-3-22-1.5  (1988)  (approved  March  5,  1988).  The  decennial 
census  is  reported  by  the  federal  government  and  is  adjusted  by  corrected  population 
counts  which  may  be  issued  periodically  after  the  decennial  census. 

257.  Research  uncovered  two  cases  challenging  the  denial  of  an  alcoholic  beverage 
permit  since  the  quota  system  took  effect  in  1973.  See  Indiana  Alcoholic  Beverage  Comm'n 
V.  State  ex  rel.  Harmon,  269  Ind.  48,  379  N.E.2d  140  (1978);  Smock  v.  Coots,  165  Ind. 
App.  474,  333  N.E.2d  119,  reh'g  denied  (1975). 

Research  uncovered  four  cases  dealing  with  the  renewal  of  a  liquor  permit.  See  Pettit 
V.  Indiana  Alcoholic  Beverage  Comm'n,  511  N.E.2d  312  (Ind.  App.  1989);  Indiana  Alcoholic 
Beverage  Comm'n  v.  Johnson,  158  Ind.  App.  467,  303  N.E.2d  64  (1973);  Indiana  Alcoholic 
Beverage  Comm'n  v.  Lake  Superior  Court,  259  Ind.  123,  284  N.E.2d  746  (1972);  Indiana 
Alcoholic  Beverage  Comm'n  v.  Lamb,  256  Ind.  65,  267  N.E.2d  161  (1971).  In  O'Banion 
V.  State  ex  rel.  Shively,  146  Ind.  App.  223,  253  N.E.2d  739  (1969),  plaintiff  sought  to 
enjoin  defendant  from  selling  alcoholic  beverages  until  the  defendant  received  authority 
from  the  Zoning  Board  to  carry  on  the  business  at  its  particular  location. 

258.  165  Ind.  App.  474,  333  N.E.2d  119,  reh'g  denied  (1975). 

259.  Id. 

260.  See  generally  Ind.  Code  §  7.1-3-24-10  (1988). 

261.  See  generally  Ind.  Code  §  7.1-3-22-9  (1988).  This  section  provides  in  pertinent 
part: 

(a)  This  section  applies  to  any  permit  that  is  subject  to  the  quota  provisions 
of  this  chapter  unless  that  permit  is  obtained  by  sale,  assignment  or  transfer 
under  I.C.  7.1-3.2-4. 

(b)  Whenever  a  permit  to  which  this  chapter  applies  becomes  available,  the 
commission  shall  offer  an  opportunity  to  bid  for  that  permit  to  all  persons  who 
are  qualified  to  receive  that  permit  and  who  have  indicated  a  desire  to  obtain 


1054  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

complexes  having  the  policy  in  existence  longer  could  be  given  the  first 
option  of  a  permit. 

Opponents  may  argue  that  such  a  permit  system  would  be  difficult 
and  expensive  to  administer.  However,  the  alcoholic  beverage  permit 
quota  systems  have  been  operational  for  some  time.^^^  In  addition,  part 
of  HUD's  duties  is  to  investigate  the  effectiveness  of  the  blanket  ban 
on  exclusionary  policies.^"  These  investigations  are  time  consuming  and 
expensive.  If  these  resources  are  applied  to  the  administration  of  a  quota 
system  which  accounts  for  the  needs  of  both  groups,  the  cost  may  well 
even  out.  In  addition,  the  all-adult  permits  would  generate  fees  which 
could  be  applied  toward  the  cost  of  providing  subsidized  housing,  or 
to  provide  incentives  for  developers  to  build  famihal  units  or  low  income 
housing. 

Providing  incentives  for  the  construction  of  low  income  housing  may 
be  more  effective  than  a  ban  on  all-adult  communities  because  it  will 
lure  future  building  into  the  precise  area  where  it  is  needed. ^^  Direct 
subsidies  may  not  be  seen  as  desirable,  because  there  are  other  more 
pressing  needs  for  those  federal  funds. ^^^  Other  options  are  available 
and  are  discussed  below. 

One  incentive  to  promote  the  development  of  low  income  housing 
is  tax  exempt  bonds.  If  developers  perceive  the  rental  market  as  a  losing 
proposition,  they  will  not  invest  their  capital.  However,  tax  exempt  bonds 
may  provide  the  necessary  incentive  to  promote  building.  Further,  tax 
exempt  bonds  could  be  offered  only  to  those  whose  rental  units  will  be 
offered  at  a  price  within  the  range  of  low  income  families. 

In  addition,  incentives  could  be  offered  to  the  owners  of  existing 
units  so  they  will  not  be  removed  from  the  market.  Grants,  low  interest 
loans, ^^^  or  tax  exempt  bonds  could  be  offered  for  the  rehabilitation  of 
rental   units   targeted   to   be   removed   from  the   market.    A   condition 


that  permit.  The  commission  shall  receive  bids  at  an  auction  that  it  conducts. 
The  highest  bidder  at  the  commission's  auction  who  is  qualified  to  receive  the 
permit  in  all  respects  (including  a  determination  by  the  local  board  that  the 
person  is  of  good  moral  character  and  good  repute  in  the  community  in  which 
that  person  resides)  is  entitled  to  receive  the  permit.  This  bidder  shall  pay  the 
amount  of  the  bid  at  the  time  the  permit  is  issued  as  a  special  fee  for  initial 
issuance  of  the  permit. 

262.  The  Indiana  Alcoholic  Beverage  System  has  been  operational  since  1973.  1973 
Ind.  Acts  55. 

263.  42  U.S. C.  §  3604  (1982).  Some  of  this  investigation  is  accompUshed  through 
the  use  of  testers.  A  person  or  couple  with  and  without  a  child  would  be  sent  to  inquire 
about  the  availability  of  rental  housing  to  see  if  patterns  of  discrimination  can  be  detected. 

264.  See  supra  note  78,  at  1846-47. 

265.  A.  Downs,  supra  note  3,  at  9. 

266.  Id. 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1055 

precedent  for  the  receipt  of  such  funds  could  be  the  provision  of  low 
income  rental  housing  for  families. 

There  are  also  tax  advantages  which  may  be  offered  to  developers 
willing  to  invest  in  low  income  housing. ^^"^  First,  the  federal  government 
could  allow  those  people  willing  to  invest  in  such  rental  housing  the 
opportunity  to  write  off  the  interest  and  property  taxes  during  construc- 
tion rather  than  capitalizing  them.^^®  This  program  would  need  established 
guidelines  and  limitations  to  avoid  allowing  only  wealthy  investors  to 
take  advantage  of  the  incentives. ^^^ 

There  is  one  disadvantage  with  the  tax  incentives  discussed  above. 
The  Tax  Reform  Act  of  1986^^°  repealed  these  incentives,  and  it  is 
unlikely  they  will  be  reinstated.  However,  the  reform  enacted  section  42 
which  provides  a  tax  credit  for  qualified  low  income  housing. ^^^  Section 
42(h)  Hmits  the  amount  of  new  low  income  housing  credits  issued  annually 
per  state. ^''^  Owners  of  qualified  low  income  housing  are  entitled  to  a 
credit  in  each  of  ten  years. ^"^^  The  income  tax  credit  equals  the  applicable 
percentage  for  the  building  multiplied  by  the  qualified  basis  allocable 
to  low  income  rental  units  in  each  qualified  building. ^^'^  The  existence 


267.  Id.  at  10. 

268.  Id.  at  165. 

269.  Id. 

270.  Pub.  L.  No.  99-514,  100  Stat.  2189  (1986). 

271.  I.R.C.  §  42  (1986).  This  section  provides  in  pertinent  part: 

I.R.C.  §  42(g)(1)  defines  a  qualified  low-income  housing  project  as  any  residential 
rental  project  where  either  20%  or  more  of  the  residential  units  in  such  property 
are  both  rent  restricted  and  occupied  by  individuals  whose  income  is  50*^o  or 
less  of  the  area's  median  gross  income,  or  40%  or  more  of  the  residential  units 
in  such  projects  are  both  rent  restricted  and  occupied  by  individuals  whose 
income  is  60%  or  less  of  the  area's  median  gross  income.  The  owner  must 
irrevocably  elect  to  comply  with  either  of  the  minimum  set-aside  requirements 
at  the  time  the  project  is  placed  in  service. 

R.  Madden,  Taxation  of  Real  Estate  Transactions- An  Overview,  480-2nd  Tax  Mgmt. 

(BNA)  A-66-68  (1987)  (footnotes  omitted). 

272.  I.R.C.  §  42  (1986).  This  section  provides  in  pertinent  part: 

A  taxpayer  who  is  otherwise  ehgible  to  take  the  low-income  housing  credit  must 
still  obtain  an  allocation  of  credit  authority  from  the  state  or  local  credit  agency 
in  whose  jurisdiction  the  qualifying  low-income  housing  project  is  located,  unless 
the  taxpayer  finances  it  with  the  proceeds  of  a  tax-exempt  bond  which  received 
an  allocation  pursuant  to  the  private  activity  bond  limitation  added  by  the  1986 
TRA.  There  is  no  state  volume  limitation  for  projects  financed  by  such  tax 
exempt  bonds  and  the  taxpayer  does  not  need  to  obtain  any  credit  authority.  .  .  . 
Each  state  is  allocated  an  annual  credit  authority  equal  to  $1.25  for  every  resident 
of  the  state. 
R.  Madden,  supra  note  271  (footnotes  omitted). 

273.  I.R.C.  §  42(0(1)  (1986). 

274.  I.R.C.  §  42(a)(b)  (1986).  This  section  provides  in  pertinent  part: 


1056  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

of  the  low  income  housing  tax  credit  indicates  the  legislature's  awareness 
of  the  need  for  low  income  housing  and  wiUingness  to  provide  a  tax 
incentive  for  apartment  owners  and  developers.  Because  the  current  credits 
allowed  are  not  sufficient  to  provide  an  adequate  supply  of  low  income 
housing,  the  logical  way  to  promote  further  development  of  low  income 
housing  is  to  increase  the  present  4  and  9  percent  credit  amounts  and 
increase  the  number  of  credits  allowed  by  the  Code. 

In  response  to  the  problem  Congress  has  estabUshed  Housing  Voucher 
and  Certificate  Programs  which  provide  tenant-based  assistance  (assis- 
tance that  follows  the  family  if  it  moves)  so  that  the  eligible  family  can 
afford  standard  housing. ^''^  Under  the  terms  of  both  programs,  the 
families  receiving  certificates  or  vouchers  are  responsible  for  finding 
suitable  housing  which  meets  eligibility  requirements  established  by  HUD.^^^ 
The  two  programs  share  a  common  waiting  Ust,^^"^  and  both  programs 
require  that  a  family  contribute  the  greater  of  30  percent  of  their  adjusted 
monthly  income  or  10  percent  of  their  monthly  income  toward  the  rental 
payment,  with  HUD  paying  the  balance  directly  to  the  apartment  owner. ^^^ 


The  credit  is  equal  to  the  applicable  credit  percentage  for  the  project,  multiplied 
by  the  qualified  basis  allocable  to  low-income  units  in  each  qualified  low-income 
building.  §  42(a). 

For  projects  placed  in  service  in  1987,  the  apphcable  credit  percentage  is  9% 
for  non-federally  subsidized  newly  constructed  or  rehabilitated  low-income  units 
(provided  that  rehabilitation  expenditures  average  $2, (XX)  or  more  per  low-income 
unit),  4%  for  newly  constructed  or  rehabiUtated  low-income  units  where  the 
construction  or  rehabilitation  is  financed  with  tax-exempt  bonds  or  similar  sub- 
sidies (provided  that  rehabilitation  expenditures  average  $2,(X)0  or  more  per  low- 
income  unit),  and  4%  for  the  acquisition  of  existing  low-income  units  provided 
that  the  property  is  acquired  at  least  10  years  after  the  latter  of  the  date  the 
property  was  last  placed  in  service  or  the  date  of  the  most  recent  unqualified 
substantial  improvement.  .  .  .  For  projects  placed  in  service  after  1987,  credit 
rates  are  to  be  issued  by  the  IRS  on  a  monthly  basis.  .  .  .  For  newly  constructed 
or  rehabilitated  units  without  federal  subsidies,  the  credit  rates  are  to  be  computed 
so  that  the  present  value  of  the  10  annual  credit  amounts  at  the  beginning  of 
the  10-year  period  equals  70%  of  the  qualified  basis  on  the  low-income  units. 
R.  Madden,  supra  note  271  (footnotes  omitted). 

275.  Section  8  Housing  Vouchers,  53  Fed.  Reg.  34,371,  34,374-75  (1988)  (to  be 
codified  at  24  C.F.R.  §  511). 

276.  Id.  at  34,398;  24  C.F.R.  §  882.103  (1988).  In  general,  the  housing  must  be 
sanitary,  it  must  contain  adequate  toilet  facilities,  kitchen  facilities,  hot  and  cold  running 
water,  a  living  room,  bedroom,  safe  heating  and/or  cooling  system,  and  adequate  lighting. 
Although  this  Hst  is  not  exhaustive,  it  does  cover  the  basic  requirements.  Id. 

277.  Id.  at  34,393.  The  family  may  refuse  the  offer  of  a  housing  voucher  if  they 
prefer  to  wait  for  the  availability  of  a  certificate  and  vice  versa.  If,  however,  a  family 
refuses  the  offer  of  both,  they  may  be  removed  from  the  waiting  list.  Id. 

278.  Id.  at  34,403,  24  C.F.R.  §§  813.107,  882.102.  HUD  provides  the  following 
simple  example  for  the  computation  of  the  requisite  tenant  payment: 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1057 

The  main  difference  between  the  programs  is  that  with  a  certificate,  the 
rent  charged  by  the  owner  cannot  exceed  ceilings  set  by  HUD,^^^  while 
the  voucher  program  allows  the  rent  to  exceed  HUD's  ceilings,  but  the 
family  is  required  to  make  up  the  difference.^^^  The  primary  shortcomings 
of  the  housing  voucher  and  the  certificate  programs  are  the  long  waiting 
Hsts,  and  the  fact  elderly  and  handicapped  persons  are  granted  preference 
for  the  receipt  of  a  voucher  or  certificate  over  low  income  families. ^^' 
Hence,  there  are  many  less  restrictive  programs  the  legislature  could 
implement.  The  best  approach  is  a  quota  system  combined  with  an 
increase  in  the  low  income  housing  credit. ^^^  This  would  account  for 
the  needs  and  desires  of  both  famihes  with  children  and  those  who  wish 
to  live  in  a  child-free  environment.  It  would  generate  revenues  which 
could  be  used  to  finance  programs  designed  to  provide  incentives  to 
developers  to  enter  the  low  income  rental  market  and  for  existing  owners 
to  remain  in  the  market. 

VI.     Conclusion 

There  are  areas  of  the  country  facing  a  severe  rental  housing  shortage 
with  an  inordinate  number  of  all-adult  apartment  communities.  However, 
the  areas  of  the  country  reflecting  the  most  serious  problems  account 
for  53  percent  of  the  population  increase  nation  wide.  ^^^  The  supply  of 


[I]f  a  family  qualifies  for  a  four-bedroom  housing  voucher  under  the  PHA 

occupancy  standards  and  has  monthly  adjusted  income  of  $500,  and  the  payment 

standard  amount   for  a   four-bedroom   housing  voucher   is   $600,   the  housing 

assistance  payment  for  the  family  is  the  payment  standard  amount  ($600)  minus 

30  percent  of  the  family's  monthly  adjusted  income  ($150)  which  is  $450. 

Id.  at  34,403.  Monthly  adjusted  income  is  1/2  of  a  family's  annual  income  less  allowances 

for  each  dependent,  elderly  family  members,  handicapped  assistance  expenses,  and  child 

care  expenses.  24  C.F.R.  §  813.102  (1988). 

279.  24  C.F.R.  §  882.104  (1988).  Under  the  certificate  program  a  certificate  will 
not  be  issued  if  the  fair  market  rent  for  the  apartment  exceeds  HUD's  set  ceilings.  Id. 

280.  53  Fed.  Reg.  §  887.209  (1988).  The  voucher  program  allows  the  rent  charged 
to  exceed  the  fair  market  rent  by  approximately  $20  to  $50,  but  the  participating  family 
must  account  for  the  difference.  Telephone  interview  with  Pat  Beeler,  Clerk  for  Program 
Manager  of  the  Indiana  Department  of  Human  Services  (March  1,  1989). 

281.  As  of  March  1989,  the  pubUc  housing  authority  for  Marion  County,  Indiana 
ceased  accepting  apphcations.  There  are  approximately  5, (XX)  famihes  currently  on  the 
waiting  list,  and  a  family  has  to  wait  approximately  three  years  before  receiving  a  voucher 
or  certificate.  Elderly  and  handicapped  persons  are  granted  preference  and  may  receive 
a  voucher  or  certificate  in  about  six  months.  Additionally,  the  landlord  may  not  decide 
to  rent  the  apartment  in  compliance  with  the  program  requirements.  Therefore,  the  unit 
is  not  devoted  to  low-income  housing  for  a  long  period  of  time.  Telephone  interview  with 
Pat  Beeler,  Clerk  for  Program  Manager  of  the  Indiana  Department  of  Human  Services 
(March  1,  1989). 

282.  l.R.C.  §  42  (1986). 

283.  See  supra  note  43  and  accompanying  text. 


1058  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1021 

rental  housing  is  not  meeting  the  demand  as  there  is  an  increase  in  the 
number  of  rental  units  removed  from  the  market  annually,  and  a  decrease 
in  the  construction  of  new  units. ^^^ 

HUD's  previous  enforcement  policies  under  the  Fair  Housing  Act 
were  not  effective.^^^  The  1988  Amendments  provide  much  more  effective 
enforcement  procedures.  The  Amendments  put  the  burden  of  preparing 
and  financing  a  legal  action  on  the  government,  allowing  more  victims 
to  take  advantage  of  the  protection  provided.  It  further  provides  for 
conciliation  agreements  and  binding  arbitration  which  may  alleviate  the 
necessity  of  going  to  court. 

Remedial  legislation  is  definitely  needed,  but  it  should  not  consist 
of  a  complete  prohibition  of  child-exclusionary  policies.  The  statistics 
do  not  call  for  such  broad-sweeping  legislation.  Adults  without  children 
occupy  the  great  majority  of  rental  units. ^^^  The  segment  of  the  population 
facing  the  greatest  housing  problems  is  low  income  families  with  children, 
but  statistics  suggest  inadequate  income,  not  familial  discrimination 
prompts  this  problem. ^^"^  Obviously,  the  legislature  must  place  a  limit 
on  the  amount  of  famiUal  discriminatory  poUcies  allowed  in  a  given 
case,  but  statistics  do  not  call  for  a  total  prohibition  of  such  policies. 

Families  with  children  have  a  fundamental  right  to  privacy  to  live 
as  a  nuclear  family. ^^^  However,  the  other  67.6  percent^*^  of  the  rental 
market  has  a  corresponding  right  to  privacy  which  should  be  recognized 
and  respected.  This  right  to  privacy  includes  the  right  to  live  in  an 
environment  of  their  choice. ^^° 

Apartment  owners  also  have  legitimate  reasons  to  exclude  or  restrict 
children.  The  legislature  must  remember  that  apartment  complex  owners 
entered  the  rental  market  to  generate  a  profit.  Apartment  owners  face 
increasing  difficulties  in  receiving  rental  receipts  which  exceed  operating 
costs. ^^*  Furthermore,  many  developers  designed  and  built  complexes  with 
added  features  specifically  for  adults.  These  amenities  become  attractive 
nuisances  to  children  and,  therefore,  apartment  owners  may  be  held  to 
a  higher  standard  of  care  in  negligence  actions  when  children  are  present. ^^^ 
These  costs  may  appear  insurmountable  and  may  prompt  landlords  to 
get  out  of  the  rental  market.  Furthermore,  these  costs  are  a  barrier  to 


284.  See  supra  note  45  and  accompanying  text. 

285.  See  supra  note  142  and  accompanying  text. 

286.  See  supra  note  57  and  accompanying  text. 

287.  See  supra  note  73  and  accompanying  text. 

288.  See  supra  notes  221-31  and  accompanying  text. 

289.  See  supra  note  57  and  accompanying  text. 

290.  See  supra  notes  221-31  and  accompanying  text. 

291.  See  supra  note  44  and  accompanying  text. 

292.  See  supra  notes  246-48  and  accompanying  text. 


1989]  FAIR  HOUSING  AMENDMENTS  1059 

developers  who  are  considering  investments  in  the  rental  market. 

There  are  less  restrictive  measures  to  control  familial  discrimination 
than  total  prohibition.  These  consist  of  a  quota  system  which  would 
allow  a  certain  number  of  all-adult  apartment  communities  in  each  town 
or  city.  This  system  has  the  advantage  of  flexibility  lacking  in  the  Fair 
Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988.^^^  The  quota  system  would  generate 
revenue  which  the  government  could  use  to  offset  revenue  lost  through 
an  increased  percentage  for  the  low  income  housing  tax  credit.  This 
program  has  the  advantage  of  directly  targeting  the  problem  areas  and 
increasing  the  availability  of  adequate  rental  housing  for  low  income 
famihes  with  children.  The  same  cannot  be  said  of  the  1988  Amendments 
to  the  Fair  Housing  Act,^^"^  which  are  far  too  sweeping  and  which  will 
hinder  provision  of  adequate  rental  housing  to  the  low  income  rental 
market. 

Mary  Kay  Fleming 


293.  Pub.  L.  No.   100-430,  102  Stat.   1619-36  (1988). 

294.  Id. 


The  Fraud-on-the-Market  Theory:  A  **Basic"ally  Good 
Idea  Whose  Time  Has  Arrived,  Basic,  Inc.  v.  Levinson 

I.     Introduction 

The  stock  market  has  been  shaken  once  again.  Black  Monday, 
October  19,  1987  has  replaced  Black  Tuesday  of  October  1929.^  Wall 
Street  stories  of  mergers  and  acquisitions,^  high  yield  junk  bonds,  insider 
trading,^  market  manipulations,"*  the  Drexel  Burnham  Lambert  settle- 
ment,^ and  leveraged  buyouts  of  a  proportion,  magnitude,  and  number 
never  dreamed  of  just  five  years  ago^  have  filled  the  newspapers  and 
news  magazines. 

For  many  years  the  stock  market  was  stable  in  the  sense  that  prices 
rose  and  fell  with  the  conditions  of  the  day.  The  underlying  assumptions 
of  investment  risk  were  not  seriously  questioned  even  though  efforts 
were  made  to  maintain  quality  control.^  The  nation  was  confident  that 
nothing  like  the  Great  Depression  and  the  market  crash  of  1929  would 
ever  be  repeated.^  Congress  enacted  the  Securities  Act  of  1933^  and  the 
Securities  Exchange  Act  of  1934'^  in  an  effort  to  ensure  the  safety  of 


1.  The  Crash  of  '87,  Wall  Street  Journal,  December  11,  1987,  at  1,  col.  6. 

2.  N.Y.  Times,  October  21,  1988,  at  1,  col.  3  (A  partnership  led  by  the  Wall 
Street  firm  of  Shearson  Lehman  Hutton  Inc.  is  reportedly  planning  to  offer  about  $17 
billion  for  RJR  Nabisco,  Inc). 

3.  N.Y.  Times,  December  19,  1987,  at  1,  col.  1  (Ivan  F.  Boesky  is  sentenced  to 
three  years  in  prison  in  insider  trading  scandal). 

4.  Wall  Street  Journal,  October  14,  1987,  §  A,  at  6,  col.  1  (At  least  two 
investigations  are  under  way  into  possible  illegal  self-dealing  involving  private  charitable 
foundations  funded  and  controlled  by  Drexel  Burnham's  junk  bond  chief,  Michael  Milken, 
his  brother  Lowell  and  others). 

5.  The  National  Law  Journal,  Oct.  31,  1988,  at  9,  col.  1  (Drexel  waits  for  next 
shoe  to  drop:  criminal  charges  anticipated). 

6.  N.Y.  Times,  October  21,  1988,  at  1,  col.  3. 

7.  See  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  Authorization  Act  of  1987 ,  Securities 
Laws  and  Corporate  Disclosure  Regulations:  Hearing  Before  the  Subcommittee  on  Oversight 
and  Investigations  of  the  Committee  on  Energy  and  Commerce,  House  of  Representatives, 
97th  Cong.,  2nd  Sess.  (1982)  The  Securities  Acts  Amendments  of  1975.  (Congress  enacted 
the  1975  Amendments  after  the  crisis  of  1969  and  1970  which  caused  the  failure  of  many 
broker-dealers,  including  several  of  the  oldest  and  largest  Wall  Street  firms). 

8.  N.Y.  Times,  October  21,  1987,  §IV  at  15,  col.  3  (Old  jokes,  that  were  formed 
during  Great  Depression,  are  being  revived  and  updated  during  current  stock  market  crisis). 
It  is  not  suggested  that  the  causal  factors  of  the  market  decUne  in  1987  are  the  same  as 
those  present  in  1929.  See,  The  October  1987  Market  Break,  Fed.  Sec.  L.  Rep.  (CCH) 
No.  1271  (Feb.  9,   1988). 

9.  15  U.S.C.  §§  77a  -  77aa  (1982). 
10.     15  U.S.C.  §§  78a  -  78kk  (1982). 

1061 


1062  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

the  American  economy.''  Individuals  bought  and  sold  securities  and 
made  or  lost  money  feeling  secure  that  illegality  or  fraud  had  not  affected 
the  risk.  Attorneys  advised  their  clients  candidly  and  responsibly  of  the 
cHent's  obHgations  to  disclose  information  as  required  by  the  SEC  laws. 
If  fraud  was  involved  in  the  market  prices  or  conditions,  laws  were 
available  with  which  to  prosecute  the  perpetrators.'^  In  particular,  Rule 
lOb-5'^  provided  broad  language  with  which  to  carry  out  the  purpose 
of  protecting  market  investors  from  the  types  of  activities,  namely  fraud 
and  manipulation,  that  nearly  brought  the  country  to  the  brink  of 
economic  disaster  during  the  last  years  of  the  1920's. 

Until  1975,  the  Supreme  Court  applied  broadly  the  SEC  regulations 
in  finding  a  lOb-5  fraud  action.'"*  With  the  Blue  Chip  Stamps  v.  Manor 
Drug  Stores  case,'^  however,  the  Court  began  to  interpret  more  narrowly 
aspects  of  the  fraud  action.'^  Justice  Rehnquist,  writing  the  majority 

11.  See  infra  notes  12-13,  24-27  and  accompanying  text. 

12.  Sections  11  and  12(2)  of  the  Securities  Act  of  1933,  15  U.S.C.  77k,  771(2) 
(1982),  provide  express  causes  of  action  by  defrauded  or  misled  buyers  of  securities,  but 
the  remedies  are  limited.  Section  11  of  the  Securities  Act  prohibits  material  misstatements 
and  omissions  in  registration  statements.  Section  12(2)  imposes  liability  on  a  seller  of 
registered  or  unregistered  securities  for  material  misstatements  or  omissions  in  any  com- 
munication through  which  the  securities  are  offered  or  sold.  The  Securities  Exchange  Act 
of  1934  provides  antifraud  provisions  in  sections  10(b)  and  16(b),  15  U.S.C.  78j(b),  78p(b) 
(1982).  An  imphed  cause  of  action  for  violation  of  section  10(b)  was  accepted  in  Kardon 
V.  National  Gypsum  Co.,  69  F.  Supp.  512  (E.D.  Pa.  1946).  Section  10(b)  appHes  to  all 
securities  but  section  16(b)  applies  to  equity  securities  of  registered  companies  and  only 
to  directors,  officers,  and  ten  percent  or  more  shareholders. 

13.  15  U.S.C.  §  78J05),  and  the  Rule  promulgated  thereunder,  17  C.F.R.  240.10b- 
5  states: 

It  shall  be  unlawful  for  any  person,  directly  or  indirectly,  by  use  of  any 
means  or  instrumentality  or  interstate  commerce,  or  of  the  mails  or  of  any 
facility  of  any  nation  securities  exchange, 

(a)  To  employ  any  device,  scheme,  or  artifice  to  defraud, 

(b)  To  make  any  untrue  statement  of  a  material  fact  or  to  omit  to  state 
a  material  fact  necessary  in  order  to  make  the  statements  made,  in  the  Ught  of 
the  circumstances  under  which  they  were  made,  not  misleading,  or 

(c)  To  engage  in  any  act,  practice,  or  course  of  business  which  operates 
or  would  operate  as  a  fraud  or  deceit  upon  any  person,  in  connection  with  the 
purchase  or  sale  of  any  security. 

14.  Phillips,  An  Essay:  The  Competing  Currents  of  Rule  lOb-5  Jurisprudence y  21 
iND.  L.  Rev.  625  (1988). 

15.  421  U.S,  723  (1975).  The  Court  limited  lOb-5  actions  to  actual  purchasers  or 
sellers  of  securities.  Id.  at  725. 

16.  See  Santa  Fe  Indus.,  Inc.  v.  Green,  430  U.S.  462  (1977)  (manipulative  or 
deceptive  conduct  is  required  for  lOb-5  actions);  Dirks  v,  SEC,  463  U.S.  646  (1983)  (a 
tippee  is  not  under  a  duty  to  disclose  or  refrain  from  trading  unless  the  tip  is  a  breach 
of  her  fiduciary  duty);  Chiarella  v.  United  States,  445  U.S.  222  (1980)  (no  duty  to  disclose 
mere  possession  of  nonpublic  insider  information);  Ernst  &  Ernst  v.  Hochfelder,  425  U.S. 
185  (1976)  (scienter,  i.e.,  intent  to  deceive,  manipulate,  or  defraud,  on  the  part  of  the 
defendant  is  necessary). 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1063 

Opinion  in  Blue  Chip,  argued  that  there  was  "widespread  recognition" 
that  the  problem  of  vexatious  litigation  under  Rule  lOb-5  cases  needed 
to  be  circumscribed  J  "^ 

If,  indeed,  the  Court  has  sought  to  refine  the  scope  of  securities 
fraud  actions  during  the  past  14  years,  it  has  made  a  major  shift  toward 
a  broader  interpretation  with  Basic  Inc.  v.  Levinson^^.  In  the  Basic 
case,  the  Court  supported  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory.'^  Fraud- 
on-the-market  is  a  theory  which  recognizes  that  a  materially  false  state- 
ment or  omission,  made  available  to  the  general  public,  may  be  relied 
upon  by  stock  market  professionals  in  the  process  of  valuing  shares. ^^ 
This  process  of  valuing  the  shares,  affected  by  false  statements  or 
omissions,  causes  the  price  of  the  stock  to  deviate  from  what  its  intrinsic 
value  should  be.  As  a  result,  investors  are  hurt  by  false  statements  or 
omissions  even  if  they  do  not  personally  value  the  stock  on  the  mis- 
statements or  omissions.  Additionally,  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory 
serves  as  an  entree  for  plaintiff  class  actions  because  individual  direct 
reliance  need  not  be  proven.^'  The  theory  is  used  to  support  a  presumption 
of  reHance  in  Rule  lOb-5  securities  fraud  actions. ^^ 

The  Supreme  Court,  with  the  Basic  decision,  has  renewed  interest 
in  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory. ^^  This  Note  examines  the  background 
and  application  of  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory.  An  analysis  of  the 
Basic  majority  and  dissenting  opinions  follows.  Finally,  it  will  be  shown 
that  the  positive  aspects  of  the  Basic  decision  for  investors,  namely  a 
presumption  of  reliance  which  functions  to  remove  a  difficult  evidentiary 
burden  and  which  provides  for  easier  class  action  certification,  should 
be  weighed  against  the  uncertainty  that  corporations  and  their  counsel 
now  face  because  of  the  Court's  unrestricted  announcement  that  the 
fraud-on-the-market  theory  is  acceptable  in  Rule  lOb-5  actions.  The 
favoring  of  the  investor  by  the  United  States  Supreme  Court  will  be 


17.  Blue  Chip  Stamps  v.  Manor  Drug  Stores,  421  U.S.  723,  739  (1975).  The  Court 
was  concerned  with  strike  suits,  that  is,  those  cases  without  merit  but  which  have  a 
settlement  value  because  the  defendant  can  be  forced  to  engage  in  costly  discovery.  Id. 
at  740-41. 

18.  108  S.  Ct.  978  (1988). 

19.  See  generally  Black,  Fraud-on-the-Market:  A  Criticism  of  Dispensing  With 
Reliance  Requirements  in  Certain  Open  Market  Transactions,  62  N.C.L.  Rev,  435  (1984); 
Note,  The  Fraud-on-the-Market  Theory,  95  Harv.  L.  Rev.  1143  (1982). 

20.  See  supra  n.l9. 

21.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  978,  990-91  (1988). 

22.  See  Black,  supra  note  19;  Note,  supra  note  19. 

23.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  998.  The  Basic  court  determined  the  materiality  standard 
for  violation  of  §  10(b)  of  the  Securities  Exchange  Act  of  1934  in  the  context  of  corporate 
preliminary  merger  negotiations  statements  in  addition  to  approving  the  fraud-on-the- 
market  theory.  Id.  at  983. 


1064  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

seen  by  many  as  welcome  and  long  overdue.  However,  it  is  not  without 
a  cost.  With  the  Basic  decision,  the  Court  may  have  given  investors  the 
impression  that  they  no  longer  must  act  with  caution  and  care  when 
dealing  with  stock  market  risk.  At  the  same  time,  the  Court  seems  ready 
to  impose  a  greater  burden  on  those  who  make  the  disclosure  to  those 
who  are  careless. 

II.  Background 

The  purpose  of  the  Securities  Act  of  1933  and  the  Securities  Exchange 
Act  of  1934,  and  specifically  Rule  lOb-5,  was  to  protect  investors  against 
manipulation  of  stock  prices, ^"^  to  promote  fair  equitable  practices, ^^  and 
to  insure  fairness  in  securities  transactions.^^  Principles  of  basic  tort  law 
were  incorporated  into  the  1933  and  1934  Acts  as  means  of  accompHshing 
the  Acts'  ends.^^ 

The  lOb-5  cause  of  action  has  been  based  on  traditional  common 
law  fraud.^^  Misrepresentations,  as  the  basis  of  a  fraud  action,  had  to 
be  relied  upon  in  order  to  be  actionable. ^^  If  appUed  to  securities  fraud 
cases,  the  plaintiffs  would  be  required  to  show  that  they  had  relied  on 
the  prospectus  or  other  pubHcly  disclosed  information,  in  addition  to 
the  other  elements  of  fraud,  in  order  to  recover  damages. ^°  The  Second,^' 
Third, ^^  Fifth,"  Ninth^"^,  Tenth^^  and  Eleventh^^  Circuits  now  recognize 


24.  S.  Rep.  No.  792,  73d  Cong.,  2d  Sess.  1-5  (1934).  Rule  lOb-5  was  adopted  in 
1942. 

25.  3  L.  Loss,  Securities  Regulation  1455-56  (2d  ed.  1961).  See  also,  Santa  Fe 
Industries,  Inc.  v.  Green,  430  U.S.  462,  476-77  (1977)  {quoting  SEC  v.  Capital  Gains 
Research  Bureau,  Inc.,  375  U.S.  180,  186  (1963)). 

26.  Scott,  Insider  Trading:  Rule  lOb-5,  Disclosure  and  Corporate  Privacy,  9  J. 
Legal  Stud.  801,  804  (1980). 

27.  See  Restatement  (Second)  of  Torts  §§  525-530  (1977);  W.  Prosser,  Handbook 
OF  THE  Law  of  Torts  §  108  (4th  ed.  1971). 

28.  The  elements  for  common  law  fraud  include:  a  misrepresentation  of  a  material 
fact,  reliance,  causation  and  intent  or  scienter.  Restatement  (Second)  of  Torts  §§  525- 
530  (1977). 

29.  See  W,  Prosser,  supra  note  27. 

30.  Id. 

31.  Panzirer  v.  Wolf,  663  F.2d  365  (2d  Cir.  1981),  vacated  as  moot  sub  nom. 
Price  Waterhouse  v.  Panzirer,  459  U.S.  1027  (1982). 

32.  Peil  V.  Speiser,  806  F.2d  1154  (3d  Cir.   1986). 

33.  Shores  v.  Sklar,  647  F.2d  462  (5th  Cir.  1981)  (en  banc),  cert,  denied,  103  S. 
Ct.  772  (1983). 

34.  Blackie  V.  Barrack,  524  F.2d  891  (9th  Cir.  1975),  cert,  denied,  429  U.S.  816 
(1976). 

35.  T.J.  Raney  &  Sons  v.  Fort  Cobb,  Okla.  Irr.  Fuel  Auth.,  717  F.2d  1330  (10th 
Cir.),  cert,  denied,  104  S.  Ct.   1285  (1983). 

36.  Lipton  v.  Documation,  Inc.,  734  F.2d  740  (11th  Cir.  1984). 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1065 

that  the  securities  market  functions  in  response  to  all  information  fed 
into  it  whether  or  not  investors  read  and  use  the  information.^^  The 
reliance  element  is  demonstrated  by  showing  both  that  the  misstatements 
or  omissions  affected  the  market  and  that  the  purchase  or  sale  of  a 
security  caused  the  plaintiff's  injury.  A  misrepresentation  is  *' impounded 
in  the  market  price,  and  the  person  who  buys  without  knowledge  of 
the  prospectus  is  acting  on  false  information  to  the  same  extent  as  those 
who  buy  with  knowledge. "^^ 

Some  courts  have  distinguished  between  omissions  and  false  and 
misleading  statements, ^^  noting  that  proof  of  reliance  for  omissions  is 
a  particularly  difficult  problem  because  of  the  need  to  show  how  the 
plaintiff  would  have  acted  had  the  information  been  disclosed. "^^  However, 
a  presumption  of  reliance  is  now  employed  in  both  misstatement  and 
omission  cases. "^^ 

The  primary  purpose  of  the  reliance  presumption  in  a  Rule  lOb-5 
cause  of  action  is  to  allow  the  investor  to  rely  on  the  expectation  that 
the  securities  markets  are  fraud-free,'^^  prices  are  set  validly,"^^  and  the 
market  has  not  been  manipulated.'^  In  an  open  market  the  investor  is 
able  to  assume  that  a  security  is  priced  accurately,  that  is,  that  the 
market  price  is  in  fact  the  equivalent  of  the  intrinsic  value. "^^ 

A  secondary,  but  no  less  important,  purpose  for  allowing  a  pre- 
sumption of  reliance  is  to  maintain  a  class  action."^^  The  procedural 
concerns  of  class  actions  under  the  Federal  Rules  of  Civil  Procedure,"^^ 
namely,  the  need  for  each  plaintiff  to  show  individual  reliance,  are 
eHminated;  therefore,  the  potential  for  more  plaintiffs  and  larger  re- 
coveries exists.'*^  Additionally,  as  the  majority  in  Basic  pointed  out,  the 


37.  The  Fifth  Circuit  pointed  out  in  Shores  that  the  Supreme  Court  "did  not 
eliminate  reliance  as  an  element  of  a  lOb-5  omission  case;  it  merely  estabHshed  a  presumption 
that  made  it  possible  for  the  plaintiffs  to  meet  their  burden."  Id.  6A1  F.2d  at  468. 

38.  R.  PosNER,  Economic  Analysis  of  Law  423  (3d  ed.  1986). 

39.  See  cases  cited  infra  note  71. 

40.  Affiliated  Ute  Citizens  of  Utah  v.  United  States,  406  U.S.  128  (1972).  The 
Supreme  Court  held  that  in  a  face-to-face  transaction  where  the  defendant  failed  to  state 
material  facts,  the  plaintiff's  reliance  could  be  presumed  from  the  materiality  of  the  facts. 
The  defendant  would  then  have  an  opportunity  to  prove  that  the  plaintiff  had  not  relied 
on  the  material  omissions.  Id.  at  153-54. 

41.  See  cases  cited  infra  note  71. 

42.  Blackie  v.  Barrack,  524  F.2d  891,  907  (9th  Cir.  1975),  cert,  denied,  429  U.S. 
816  (1976). 

43.  Id. 

44.  Id. 

45.  Note,  The  Fraud-on-the-Market  Theory,  95  Harv.  L.  Rev.  1143  (1982). 

46.  Mills  V.  Electric  Auto-Lite  Co.,  396  U.S.  375  (1970). 

47.  Fed.  R.  Civ.  P.  23. 

48.  See  generally  Comment,  Class  Actions,   Typicality,  and  Rule  lOb-5:  Will  the 


1066  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

fraud-on-the-market  theory  removes  an  unrealistic  evidentiary  burden 
from  the  plaintiff/^ 

III.    The  Efficient  Capital  Market  Hypothesis  and  The  Fraud- 

On-The-Market  Theory 

The  notion  that  the  investor  expects  the  market  to  provide  an  accurate 
reflection  of  the  value  of  a  stock  is  based  on  the  efficient  capital  market 
hypothesis. ^°  The  premise  of  the  efficient  capital  market  hypothesis  is 
that  in  pricing  a  stock  the  market  anticipates  events  and,  consequently, 
a  stock's  price  is  the  best  estimate  of  its  intrinsic  value. ^^  The  hypothesis 
developed  from  the  random  walk  model, ^^  that  is,  that  market  prices 
will  fluctuate  randomly  and  be  independent  of  prior  changes. ^^  The 
efficient  market  hypothesis,  as  it  has  evolved,  suggests  that  the  market 
reacts,  completely  and  immediately,  to  information  about  the  shares 
being  traded.^'*  As  such,  the  market,  using  all  publicly  available  infor- 
mation, sets  a  price  which  reflects  the  actual  value  of  the  stock. ^^ 

There  are  three  forms  of  the  efficient  capital  market  hypothesis:  the 
weak  form  which  measures  whether  historical  price  data  is  fully  reflected; 
the  semi-strong  which  measures  whether  all  publicly  available  information 
is  reflected;  and  the  strong  form  which  measures  whether  all  information, 
including  information  not  publicly  available,  is  fully  reflected. ^^  The 
semi-strong  form  of  the  efficient  market  hypothesis  is  the  recognized 
basis  of  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory. ^^ 


Typical  Representative  Please  Stand  Up?,  36  Emory  L.J.  649  (1987);  Note,  The  Fraud- 
on-the-Market  Theory,  95  Harv.  L.  Rev.  1143,  1159  (1982). 

49.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  990. 

50.  See  generally,  Fischel,  Use  of  Modern  Finance  Theory  in  Securities  Fraud  Cases 
Involving  Actively  Traded  Securities,  38  Bus.  Law.  1  (1982);  Pickholz  &  Horahan,  The 
SEC's  Version  of  the  Efficient  Market  Theory  and  its  Impact  on  Securities  Law  Liabilities, 
39  Wash.  &  Lee  L.  Rev.  943  (1982);  Note,  Broker  Investment  Recommendations  and 
the  Efficient  Capital  Market  Hypothesis:  A  Proposed  Cautionary  Legend,  29  Stan.  L. 
Rev.  1077  (1977). 

51.  See  8  Economics  of  Corporation  Law  and  Securities  Regulation  438  (R. 
Posner  &  K.  Scott,  eds.  1980).  See  also,  A.  Bromberg  &  L.  Lowenfels,  Security  Fraud 
AND  Commodities  Fraud,  (1982). 

52.  J.  LoRiE,  P.  DoDD  &  M.  Kimpton,  The  Stock  Market:  Theories  and 
Evidence  55  (1985)  [hereinafter  cited  as  J.  Lorie]. 

53.  Id.  at  77. 

54.  Id.  at  76. 

55.  Id.  at  77.  See  also  Black,  Fraud-on-the-Market:  A  Criticism  of  Dispensing  with 
Reliance  Requirements  in  Certain  Open  Market  Transactions,  62  N.C.L.  Rev.  435,  449. 

56.  Fama,  Efficient  Capital  Markets:  A  Review  of  Theory  and  Empirical  Work, 
25  J.  Fin.  383  (1970). 

57.  See  J.  Lorie,  supra  note  52,  at  77. 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1067 

The  efficient  market  hypothesis  has  been  problematic  because  ran- 
domness would  seem  to  imply  a  lack  of  meaning  to  stock  pricing. ^^  Also 
there  is  the  obvious  paradox  of  investor  activity. ^^  In  an  efficient  market 
when  information  is  available,  the  share  price  will  approach  its  intrinsic 
value  because  of  investor  competition.  At  the  same  time,  investors  trade 
stock  because  they  believe  stocks  are  under-  or  overvalued,  that  is,  that 
the  market  prices  do  not  reflect  their  true  value.  Many  investors  purchase 
or  sell  stocks  because  they  believe  the  price  reflects  the  corporation's 
worth  inaccurately.^^  However,  *'[u]nder  conditions  of  efficiency,  no 
investor,  using  only  information  also  generally  available  to  other  inves- 
tors, can  systematically  identify  and  acquire  undervalued  (or  overvalued) 
securities."^'  It  has  been  pointed  out  by  economists'^  and  courts  "  that 
the  efficient  market  theory  has  some  difficulties  beyond  this  paradox. 
The  stock  market  is  not  only  to  receive  information  but  to  interpret  the 
information  and  transform  the  information  into  a  price.  The  information 
is  supposedly  factual.  However,  projections,  conjectures,  and  specula- 
tions, which  are  of  questionable  sufficent  factual  basis,  are  incorporated 
into  the  mix  of  information  to  be  interpreted  and  such  "information" 
is  filtered  regularly  into  the  market  place. ^ 

The  fraud-on-the-market  theory,  based  on  the  efficient  market  hy- 
pothesis, is  used  to  say  that  a  buyer  or  seller  of  securities  can  presume 
an  efficient  market.  The  Third  Circuit  Court  in  Peil  v.  Speiser^^  stated 
that  '*in  an  open  and  developed  securities  market,  the  price  of  a  com- 
pany's stock  is  determined  by  the  available  material  information  regarding 
the  company  and  its  business. "''  An  investor  may  rely  on  the  "sup- 
position that  the  market  price  is  validly  set  and  that  no  unsuspected 
manipulation  has  artificially  inflated  the  price. "'^  It  is  the  investor's 


58.  See  Wang,  Some  Arguments  That  the  Stock  Market  Is  Not  Efficient,  19  U.C.D. 
L.  Rev.  341  (1986).  Wang  has  stated  that  if  the  "semi-strong  [form  of  the  efficient 
market]  hypothesis  were  correct,  one  would  have  to  conclude  that  the  market  for  investment 
research  was  extremely  inefficent."  Id.  at  375.  See  also,  Tobin,  On  the  Efficiency  of  the 
Financial  System,  153  Lloyds  Bank  Rev.  1  (1984). 

59.  See  J.  Lorie,  supra  note  52,  at  77. 

60.  See  Black,  supra  note  19,  at  455. 

61.  Note,  The  Efficient  Capital  Market  Hypothesis,  Economic  Theory  and  the 
Regulation  of  the  Securities  Industry,  29  Stan.  L.  Rev.  1031,  1035  (1977). 

62.  See  generally  supra  notes  50-52. 

63.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  998  (White,  J.,  dissenting). 

64.  See  Hiler,  The  SEC  and  the  Courts'  Approach  to  Disclosure  of  Earnings 
Projections,  Asset  Appraisals,  and  Other  Soft  Information:  Old  Problems,  Changing  View, 
46  Md.  L.  Rev.   1114  (1987). 

65.  806  F.2d  1154  (3d  Cir.   1986). 

66.  Id.  at  1160. 

67.  Blackie  v.  Barrack,  524  F.2d  891,  907  (9th  Cir.  1975),  cert,  denied,  429  U.S. 
816  (1976). 


1068  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

reliance  on  the  market  and  not  on  the  information  disclosed  by  the 
corporation  that  is  presumed.  Therefore,  reliance  is  still  a  vital  part  of 
the  lOb-5  cause  of  action,  even  though  the  focus  of  the  investor's  reliance 
has  shifted  to  the  market.  Consequently,  misleading  statements  could 
defraud  traders  in  securities  even  if  the  investors  did  not  rely  directly 
on  the  misstatements.  The  misstatements  or  omissions  can  affect  the 
price  by  either  inflating  or  deflating  it  artificially,  which  could  defraud 
investors  who  rely  on  the  price  as  a  reflection  of  the  value  of  the  share. ^^ 
A  potential  problem  with  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory  is  the 
conflict  between  the  national  poHcy  of  full  and  fair  disclosure  of  material 
information  to  the  investing  public  and  the  public's  failure  to  rely  on 
that  information  because  the  market  is  supposedly  efficient.  As  the 
district  court  in  In  re  LTV  Securities  Litigation^^  stated  in  1980: 

[t]he  market  is  performing  a  substantial  part  of  the  valuation 
process  performed  by  the  investor  in  a  face-to-face  transaction. 
The  market  is  acting  as  the  unpaid  agent  of  the  investor,  in- 
forming him  that  given  all  the  information  available  to  it,  the 
value  of  the  stock  is  worth  the  market  price. ''^ 

If  indeed  the  market  is  functioning  as  an  informer/agent  of  the  investor, 
full  disclosure  to  investors  is  not  necessary  and  is,  in  fact,  superfluous. 

IV.    Fraud-On-The-Market  Theory  Applied 

The  various  federal  circuit  courts  have  applied  the  fraud-on-the- 
market  theory  in  securities  fraud  actions  brought  under  Rule  lOb-5.''' 
The  Second,  Ninth,  and  Eleventh  Circuits  have  applied  the  presumption 
of  reliance  only  to  existing  securities  on  developed  markets, ^^  but  the 
Fifth  and  Tenth  Circuits  have  applied  the  theory  to  newly  issued  shares 
on  undeveloped  markets."^^ 

The  first  Supreme  Court  case  to  dispense  with  proof  of  actual  reliance 
in  establishing  causation  in  non-disclosure  cases  was  Affiliated  Ute  Cit- 


es.   Note,  The  Fraud-on-the-Market  Theory,  95  Harv.  L.  Rev.  1143,  1154-56  (1982). 

69.  88  F.R.D.   134  (N.D.  Tex.   1980). 

70.  Id.  at  143  (cited  with  approval  in  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  990). 

71.  See,  Peil  v.  Speiser,  806  F.2d  1154  (3d  Cir.  1986),  Lipton  v.  Documation, 
Inc.,  734  F.2d  740  (11th  Cir.  1984),  cert,  denied,  105  S.  Ct.  814  (1985);  T.J.  Raney  & 
Sons  V.  Fort  Cobb,  Okla.  Irr.  Fuel  Auth.,  717  F.2d  1330  (10th  Cir.  1983),  cert,  denied 
104  S.  Ct.  1285  (1983);  Panzirer  v.  Wolf,  663  F.2d  365  (2d  Cir.  1981),  vacated  as  moot 
sub  nom.  Price  Waterhouse  v.  Panzirer,  459  U.S.  1027  (1982);  Shores  v.  Sklar,  647  F.2d 
462  (5th  Cir.  1981)  (en  banc),  cert,  denied,  103  S.  Ct.  772  (1983);  Blackie  v.  Barrack, 
524  F.2d  891  (9th  Cir.  1975),  cert,  denied,  429  U.S.  816  (1976). 

72.  Blackie,  524  F.2d  at  895;  Panzirer,  663  F.2d  at  367-68;  Documation,  734  F.2d 
at  745. 

73.  Shores,  647  F.2d  at  468;  T.J.  Raney,  111  F.2d  at  1333. 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1069 

izens  v.  United  States.'"^  In  Affiliated  Ute,  members  of  a  large  class  of 
shareholders  alleged  that  they  had  relied,  in  the  context  of  a  face-to- 
face  transaction,  on  the  advice  of  two  bank  employees  in  selling  their 
stock. ^^  The  bank  employees  failed  to  disclose  the  stock's  true  value  and 
that  they  were  market  makers  in  the  stock. ^^  The  Supreme  Court  held: 

Under  the  circumstances  of  this  case,  involving  primarily  a  failure 
to  disclose,  positive  proof  of  rehance  is  not  a  prerequisite  to 
recovery.  All  that  is  necessary  is  that  the  facts  withheld  be 
material  in  the  sense  that  a  reasonable  investor  might  have 
considered  them  important  in  the  making  of  this  decision.  This 
obligation  to  disclose  and  this  withholding  of  a  material  fact 
establish  the  requisite  element  of  causation  in  fact.^^ 

Since  1972  and  the  Affiliated  Ute  decision,  the  circuits  have  ap- 
proached the  fraud-on-the-market  theory  with  inconsistent  results. ^^  In 
Blackie  v.  Barrack, ^^  the  Ninth  Circuit  expanded  the  Affiliated  Ute 
decision  by  extending  the  reliance  presumption  to  a  material  misrepre- 
sentation case.^^  As  the  court  noted: 

Here,  we  eliminate  the  requirement  that  plaintiffs  prove  reliance 
directly  in  this  context  because  the  requirement  imposes  an  un- 
reasonable and  irrelevant  evidentiary  burden.  .  .  .  Requiring  di- 
rect proof  from  each  purchaser  that  he  relied  on  a  particular 
representation  when  purchasing  would  defeat  recovery  by  those 
whose  reliance  was  indirect,  despite  the  fact  that  the  causational 
chain  is  broken  only  if  the  purchaser  would  have  purchased  the 
stock  even  had  he  known  of  the  misrepresentation.  We  decline 
to  leave  such  open  market  purchasers  unprotected.^^ 


74.  406  U.S.  128  (1972).  With  Affiliated  Ute  the  Supreme  Court  established  a 
rebuttable  presumption  of  reliance  in  non-disclosure  cases  but  did  not  discuss  whether 
reliance  could  be  presumed  in  affirmative  misrepresentation  cases.  Id.  at  153. 

75.  Id. 

76.  Id. 

11.    Id.  at  153-54  (citations  omitted). 

78.  See  cases  cited  infra  notes  79-95. 

79.  524  F.2d  891  (9th  Cir.  1975),  cert,  denied,  429  U.S.  816  (1976). 

80.  The  Blackie  plaintiffs  claimed  that  they  purchased  shares  of  Ampex  Corporation 
stock  between  the  release  of  two  annual  reports  which  contained  misrepresentations  of 
the  corporation's  financial  position.  The  court  found  that  the  misrepresentations  had 
influenced  the  stock's  price  in  the  market.  Causation  in  the  market  place  was  established 
by  proof  of  purchase  and  proof  of  the  materiality  of  the  misrepresentation  even  though 
there  was  no  proof  of  direct  reliance.  Blackie,  524  F.2d  at  906. 

81.  Id.  at  907. 


1070  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

Consequently,  the  plaintiff  need  only  establish  that  the  fraud  adversely 
affected  the  market  price  in  order  for  the  presumption  to  apply. 

Defendants  can  prove  that  the  misstatements  are  immaterial.  De- 
fendants may  disprove  causation  by  showing  that  an  insufficient  number 
of  shares  were  purchased  or  sold  on  the  misrepresentation  to  affect  the 
price  or  that  the  plaintiff  knew  of  the  misrepresentation  or  would  have 
purchased  the  shares  even  though  she  knew  of  the  misrepresentation. ^^ 
The  court  in  Blackie  did  not  address  the  problem  that  the  defendant's 
proof  is  the  functional  equivalent  of  the  plaintiff's  proof,  that  is,  proof 
of  a  speculative  negative. ^^  Blackie  also  suggests  that  the  purpose  of  a 
reliance  element  is  to  show  causation. ^"^  If  reliance  is  equated  with 
causation,  the  presumption  is  nonrebuttable.  If  the  material  misrepre- 
sentation caused  the  plaintiff's  injury,  the  defendant  has  violated  Rule 
lOb-5.  The  Ninth  Circuit  Court  did  not  go  this  far;  however,  other 
courts  have.^^ 

In  Panzirer  v.  Wolf,^^  the  plaintiff  did  not  rely  on  the  market  price 
to  decide  to  purchase  shares  of  a  corporation.  Rather,  she  reUed  on  a 
newspaper  article  which  was  favorable  to  the  corporation.  The  plaintiff's 
reliance  was  not  on  the  integrity  of  the  market  price  as  it  had  been  in 
Blackie. ^'^  Instead,  reliance  was  eliminated  as  an  element  of  the  Rule 
lOb-5  action  because  the  plaintiff  could  show  a  causal  connection  between 
the  material  misrepresentation  in  the  corporation's  annual  report  and 
her  financial  loss.^^  Consequently,  in  the  Panzirer  case,  the  presumption 
of  reliance  is  nonrebuttable. 

The  fraud-on-the-market  theory  was  extended  to  new  securities  on 
an  undeveloped  market  in  Shores  v.  Sklar.^^  The  plaintiff  had  purchased 
municipal  bonds  but  not  in  reliance  on  the  offering  circular.  The  bonds 


82.  Id.  at  906.  See  Black,  Fraud  on  the  Market:  A  Criticism  of  Dispensing  with 
Reliance  Requirements  in  Certain  Open  Market  Transactions,  62  N.C.L.  Rev.  435,  448 
(1984). 

83.  Blackie,  524  F.2cl  at  908.  The  court  in  Blackie  stated  that  '*[d]irect  proof 
would  inevitably  be  somewhat  proforma,  and  impose  a  difficult  evidentiary  burden,  because 
addressed  to  a  speculative  possibility  in  an  area  where  motivations  are  complex  and  difficult 
to  determine."  Id. 

84.  Id.  at  906. 

85.  See  Fausett  v.  American  Resources  Management  Corp.,  542  F.  Supp.  1234  (D. 
Utah  1982);  Pellman  v.  Cinerama,  Inc.,  89  F.R.D.  386  (S.D.N. Y.  1981);  In  re  LTV  Sec. 
Litig.,  88  F.R.D.  134,  143  n.4  (N.D.  Tex.  1980);  Arthur  Young  &  Co.  v.  United  States 
Dist.  Ct.,  549  F.2d  686,  694-95  (9th  Cir.  1977),  cert,  denied,  434  U.S.  829  (1977). 

86.  663  F.2d  365  (1981),  cert,  denied,  458  U.S.  1107  (1982). 

87.  Blackie,  524  F.2d  at  906. 

88.  Panzirer,  663  F.2d  at  366. 

89.  647  F.2d  462  (5th  Cir.  1981)  {en  banc),  cert,  denied,  459  U.S.  1102  (1983), 
rev'd  sub  nom.  (in  part)  Fed.  Sec.  L.  Rep.  (CCH)  f  92,874,  appeal  dismissed,  844  F.2d 
1485,  vacated,  reh'g  granted,  855  F.2d  722  (11th  Cir.  1988)  {en  banc). 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1071 

soon  lost  their  value. ^^  The  bonds  were  new  securities  issued  on  an 
undeveloped  market,^'  in  contrast  to  both  Blackie^^  and  Panzirer.^^  In 
Shores,  the  Fifth  Circuit  found  that  the  newly  issued  securities  were 
unmarketable.^"^  The  plaintiff,  by  proving  that  he  was  willing  to  take  a 
marketable  risk,  demonstrated  that  he  relied  on  the  '^integrity  of  the 
offerings  of  the  securities  market. "^^  This  showing  of  reUance  suggests 
that  causation  was  shown  by  offering  bonds  which  were  not  marketable. 

The  broad  application  of  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory  by  many 
of  the  circuit  courts  may  represent  a  growing  consideration  for  investors' 
vulnerabilities.  As  early  as  1975  with  the  Blue  Chip  case,*^^  the  Supreme 
Court  recognized  that  reliance,  an  essential  element  in  common  law  tort 
misrepresentation  cases,  was  perhaps  not  as  critical  in  Rule  lOb-5  actions 
even  though  this  was  the  case  that  began  the  circumscription  of  the 
scope  of  the  fraud  action.  As  the  Blue  Chip  court  stated:  *'[T]he  typical 
fact  situation  in  which  the  classic  tort  of  misrepresentation  and  deceit 
evolved  was  light  years  away  from  the  world  of  commercial  transactions 
to  which  Rule  lOb-5  is  applicable. "^^  Investors  willing  to  accept  the 
usual  risks  of  trading  on  the  securities  market  should  not  be  subject  to 
schemes  that  are  not  only  meant  to  defraud  individual  investors  but  the 
market  in  general.  Material  misstatements  cause  the  market  to  react  in 
a  manner  that  causes,  in  turn,  investors  a  financial  harm.  The  courts 
should  not  neglect  investors'  indirect  reliance  on  the  integrity  of  the 
market  place  without  providing  an  alternative  solution  which  would 
redress  the  injury  suffered. 

The  availability  of  class  action  certification  is  greatly  enlarged  when 
the  burden  of  showing  individual  reliance  is  relaxed. ^^  Investors  with 
relatively  small  losses  would  not  go  forward  with  their  claims  unless  a 
class  action  could  be  maintained.  Where  individual  reliance  on  the 
misstatements  was  required,  class  actions  could  be  denied.  The  Advisory 


90.  Shores,  647  F.2d  at  463-64. 

91.  Id. 

92.  Blackie,  524  F.2d  at  908. 

93.  Panzirer,  663  F.2d  at  366. 

94.  Shores,  647  F.2d  at  467. 

95.  Id.  at  469. 

96.  Blue  Chip  Stamps  v.  Manor  Drug  Stores,  421  U.S.  723  (1975). 

97.  Id.  at  744-45. 

98.  Fed.  R.  Civ.  P.  23.  Prerequisites  for  a  class  action  include:  numerosity,  common 
questions  of  law  or  fact,  typicality  of  claims,  and  fair  and  adequate  protection  of  the 
interests  of  the  class.  In  addition,  one  of  the  three  subdivisions  of  Rule  23(b)  must  apply. 
Usually  securities  fraud  class  actions  attempt  to  meet  Rule  23(b)(3):  "that  the  questions 
of  law  or  fact  common  to  the  members  of  the  class  predominate  over  any  questions 
affecting  only  individual  members,  and  that  a  class  action  is  superior  to  other  available 
methods  for  the  fair  and  efficient  adjudication  of  the  controversy,"  Id. 


1072  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

Committee  on  Rule  23  suggests  that  class  actions  could  be  an  appropriate 
vehicle  for  fraud  actions: 

Subdivision  (b)(3)  encompasses  those  cases  in  which  a  class  action 
would  achieve  economies  of  time,  effort,  and  expense,  and  pro- 
mote uniformity  of  decision  as  to  persons  similarly  situated, 
without  sacrificing  procedural  fairness  or  bringing  about  other 
undesirable  results.  ...  [A]  fraud  perpetrated  on  numerous  per- 
sons by  the  use  of  similar  misrepresentations  may  be  an  appeahng 
situation  for  a  class  action,  and  it  may  remain  so  despite  the 
need,  if  Hability  is  found,  for  separate  determination  of  the 
damages  suffered  by  individuals  within  the  class.  On  the  other 
hand  ...  a  fraud  case  may  be  unsuited  for  treatment  as  a  class 
action  if  there  was  [sic]  material  variations  in  the  representations 
made  or  in  the  kinds  or  degrees  of  reliance  by  the  persons  to 
whom  they  were  addressed. ^^ 

In  applying  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory,  misrepresentations  are 
not  made  to  or  relied  upon  by  individuals  but  rather  to  and  by  the 
market  place.  Therefore,  it  is  appropriate  to  say  that  the  market  par- 
ticipants are  an  ideal  class '^  because  there  is  no  variation  in  representation 
and  yet  defendants  may  rebut  the  presumption  where  the  plaintiff  placed 
no  reliance  on  the  market  in  those  courts  where  reliance  is  not  equated 
with  causation  and  is  still  a  necessary  element  of  Rule  lOb-5  actions. 

V.    The  Basic  Case 

Basic,  Inc.  merged  with  Combustion  Engineering  after  14  months 
of  merger  negotiations. ^°^  Basic  expressly  made  three  pubHc  statements 
denying  that  merger  negotiations  were  taking  place  or  that  it  knew  of 
corporate  developments  that  would  account  for  heavy  trading  activity 
in  its  stock. ^°2  A  class  action  was  instituted  against  Basic  and  some  of 
the  directors  on  behalf  of  former  Basic  stockholders  who  sold  their  stock 
between  Basic's  first  denial  of  merger  activity  in  October,  1977  and  the 
suspension  of  trading  in  Basic  stock  just  prior  to  the  merger  announce- 
ment. ^^^  The  former  shareholders  claimed  that  Basic's  statements  had 
been  misleading  or  false  in  violation  of  the  Securities  Exchange  Act  of 
1934  section  10(b)  and  Rule  lOb-5,'^  and  that  they  were  injured  by 


99.  Fed.  R.  Civ.  P.  23(b)(3)  advisory  committee  note. 

100.  See  supra  note  31. 

101.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  981. 

102.  Id. 

103.  Id. 

104.  See  supra  note  13. 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1073 

selling  their  shares  at  prices  artificially  depressed  by  those  statements. ^°^ 
The  United  States  District  Court  for  the  Northern  District  of  Ohio 
certified  a  class  action  but  granted  a  summary  judgment  on  the  merits 
for  Basic. ^^  The  district  court  determined  that  the  misstatements  were 
immaterial  as  a  matter  of  law.'^^  The  United  States  Court  of  Appeals 
for  the  Sixth  Circuit  affirmed  the  class  certification  by  agreeing  that 
under  a  fraud-on-the-market  theory,  the  former  shareholders'  reliance 
on  the  company's  misrepresentations  could  be  presumed.  However,  the 
appellate  court  reversed  the  summary  judgment  and  remanded. '°^  The 
Court  of  Appeals  held  that  discussions  that  might  not  otherwise  be 
material  can  become  so  **by  virtue  of  the  statement  denying  their  ex- 
istence. "'^ 

The  United  States  Supreme  Court  granted  certiorari' ^°  in  order  to 
** resolve  the  split"  among  the  Courts  of  Appeal  as  to  the  materiality 
standard  applicable  to  preliminary  merger  negotiations' ''  and  to  determine 
whether  the  presumption  of  reliance  used  to  certify  the  class  was  properly 
applied. ''2 

The  materiality  standard  of  TSC  Industries,  Inc.  v.  Northway,  Inc.^^^ 
was  expressly  adopted  for  merger  negotiations  under  Section  10(b)  and 
Rule  lOb-S.''"*  Additionally,  the  Court  in  Basic  accepted  the  application 
of  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory  as  proper,  not  only  in  the  fact  pattern 
of  the  Basic  case  but  seemingly  in  all  lOb-5  class  actions.''^ 


105.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  981. 

106.  Levinson  v  Basic,  Inc.,  Fed.  Sec.  L.  Rep.  (CCH)  f  91,801  (Aug.  3,  1984). 

107.  The  district  court  found  that  there  were  no  negotiations  at  the  time  of  the 
first  statement.  Negotiations  were  being  conducted  when  the  second  and  third  statements 
were  made;  however,  the  district  court  applied  an  agreement-in-principle  test  and  found 
that  the  negotiations  were  not  "destined,  with  reasonable  certainty,  to  become  a  merger 
agreement  in  principle."  App.  to  Pet.  for  Cert.  103a. 

108.  786  F.2d  741,  751  (1986).  The  Sixth  Circuit  rejected  the  agreement-in-principie 
test  of  materiality  in  merger  and  acquisition  negotiations  and  held  that  "once  a  statement 
is  made  denying  the  existence  of  any  discussions,  even  discussions  that  might  not  have 
been  material  in  absence  of  the  denial  are  material  because  they  make  the  statement  made 
untrue."  Id.  at  749.  The  court  stated  that  statements  become  material  "by  virtue  of  the 
statement  denying  their  existence."  Id.  at  748. 

109.  Id.  at  748. 

110.  479  U.S.  1083  (1987). 

111.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  982. 

112.  Id. 

113.  426  U.S.  438  (1976).  "An  omitted  fact  is  material  if  there  is  a  substantial 
likelihood  that  a  reasonable  shareholder  would  consider  it  important  in  deciding  how  to 
vote."  Id.  at  449.  The  TSC  Court  went  on  to  state  that  "there  must  be  a  substantial 
likelihood  that  the  disclosure  of  the  omitted  fact  would  have  been  viewed  by  the  reasonable 
investor  as  having  significantly  altered  the  'total  mix'  of  information  made  available." 
Id. 

114.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  983. 

115.  M  at  989. 


1074  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

The  majority  opinion,  written  by  Justice  Blackmun,  asserted  that 
the  Court  was  not  assessing  the  validity  of  an  economic  theory, ^^^  namely, 
the  fraud-on-the-market  theory.  Rather,  the  majority  said  that  the  Court 
was  attempting  to  ascertain  whether  it  was,  and  is,  proper  to  apply  a 
rebuttable  presumption  of  reliance  based  on  the  fraud-on-the-market 
theory.  ^^^ 

The  Court  in  Basic  stated  that  reliance  continues  to  be  an  element 
of  a  Rule  lOb-5  cause  of  action. ^^^  Moreover,  the  Court  reasoned  that 
a  presumption  of  reliance  is  proper  in  Rule  lOb-5  class  actions  based 
on  practical  considerations  consistent  with  the  1934  Act's  full  disclosure 
policy  and  '^considerations  of  fairness,  pubhc  policy,  and  probability, 
as  well  as  judicial  economy  ...  for  allocating  the  burdens  of  proof 
between  parties.""^  The  majority  noted  that  the  Congressional  policy 
expressed  in  the  1934  Act  is  supported  by  the  presumption  device. *^^ 

Referring  to  the  district  court's  finding,  that  the  presumption  of 
reliance  provided  '*a  practical  resolution  to  the  problem  of  balancing 
the  substantive  requirement  of  proof  of  reliance  in  securities  cases  against 
the  procedural  requisites  of  [Fed.  Rule  Civ.  Proc]  23,"^^'  the  Supreme 
Court  concluded  that  a  presumption  of  reliance  removes  an  unrealistic 
evidentiary  burden  from  the  plaintiff  in  securities  fraud  cases. ^^^ 

Modern  securities  markets  differ  significantly  from  face-to-face  trans- 
actions. Where  the  market  is  performing  a  valuation  of  shares,  a  function 
ordinarily  performed  by  the  investor  in  private  transactions,  to  say  that 
the  worth  of  the  stock  is  equivalent  to  the  market  price,  the  investor 
looks  to  the  securities  market  with  the  confidence  usually  reserved  for 
expert  appraisal,  be  it  her  own  or  that  of  other  professionals  based  on 
knowledge  and  experience. ^^^  The  fraud-on-the-market  theory  is  clearly 
reflected  in  this  idea.^^"^ 

The  Court  in  Basic  found  no  inconsistency  with  the  1934  Act's 
purpose  of  promoting  full  and  fair  disclosure  of  information  and  the 
fraud-on-the-market  theory  even  though  many  commentators  ^^^  and  the 


116.  Id. 

117.  Id. 

118.  Id. 

119.  Id.  at  990. 

120.  Id.  at  990-91. 

121.  Id.  at '989. 

122.  Id.  at  990. 

123.  In  re  LTV  Securities  Litigation,  88  F.R.D.   134,  143  (N.D.  Tex.  1980). 

124.  See  supra  text  accompanying  notes  50-55,  64-66. 

125.  See,  R.  Karmel,  Regulation  by  Prosecution:  The  Securities  and  Exchange 
Commission  vs.  Corporate  America  (1982);  H.  Krdpke,  The  SEC  and  Corporate  Dis- 
closure: Regulation  in  Search  of  a  Purpose  (1979);  S.  Phillips  &  J.  Zecher,  The 
SEC  AND  the  Public  Interest  (1981);  Jarrell,  The  Economic  Effects  of  Federal  Regulation 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1075 

dissenters  in  Basic  have  disagreed. •^^  The  Basic  majority's  underlying 
rationale  is  that  even  though  an  individual  investor  has  not  chosen  to 
rely  on  the  disclosed  information,  the  market  has  relied  on  the  infor- 
mation. The  information  is  necessary  for  the  market  to  react.  It  is  the 
market  which  must  receive  material  information  in  order  to  perform  the 
task  of  valuation  that  gives  rise  to  the  buying  and  selling  of  a  security 
at  a  given  time. 

Since  1975/^^  the  Supreme  Court  has  taken  care  to  limit  the  scope 
of  lOb-5  actions. ^^^  However,  the  decision  in  Basic  will  faciUtate  investors 
bringing  class  actions  for  securities  fraud.  What  has  prompted  the  Court 
to  relax  the  plaintiff  class  burden  and  to  place  an  equally  unrealistic 
evidentiary  burden  on  the  defendant?  Perhaps  the  conduct  of  the  Basic 
defendants  was  so  egregious  that  no  other  solution  was  plausible.  Perhaps, 
given  the  shaken  faith  of  investors  in  the  wake  of  the  October  1987 
crash,  the  Court  wanted  to  act  quickly  and  confidently  to  calm  the  fears 
of  investors  and  return  to  a  more  idealistic  approach. ^^^ 

The  facts  of  the  Basic  case  are  atypical. '^°  The  plaintiffs  were  sellers 
rather  than  purchasers  of  shares,  the  time  between  the  misstatements 
and  the  decision  to  sell  the  shares  was  eleven  months,  and  the  plaintiffs 
all  made  money  on  their  sale  of  Basic  stock. '^'  As  such,  this  case  should 
not  have  been  the  basis  of  a  potentially  far  reaching  decision  and  one 
that  is  tantamount  to  the  Court's  endorsement  of  a  complex  economic 
theory.  There  is  no  evidence  to  date  that  the  decision  has  had  an  impact 


of  the  Market  for  New  Securities  Issues,  24  J.  Law  &  Econ.  613  ()981);  Scott,  Insider 
Trading:  Rule  lOb-5,  Disclosure  and  Corporate  Privacy,  9  J.  Legal  Stud.  801  (1980); 
Wolf  son,  A  Critique  of  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission,  30  Emory  L.J.  119 
(1981). 

126.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  997-98.  See  also,  Black,  supra  note  19. 

127.  Blue  Chip  Stamps  v.  Manor  Drug  Stores,  421  U.S.  723  (1975). 

128.  See  cases  cited  supra  note  16. 

129.  See  Phillips,  supra  note  14,  at  662-665. 

130.  Justice  White  in  his  dissent  states: 

None  of  the  Court  of  Appeals  cases  the  Court  cites  as  endorsing  the  fraud- 
on-the-market  theory,  ante,  at  991  n.  24,  99  L.Ed.  2d  218,  involved  seller- 
plaintiffs.  Rather,  all  of  these  cases  were  brought  by  purchasers  who  bought 
securities  in  a  short  period  following  some  material  misstatement  (or  similar  act) 
by  an  issuer,  which  was  alleged  to  have  falsely  inflated  a  stock's  price. 

Even  if  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory  provides  a  permissible  link  between 
such  a  misstatement  and  a  decision  to  purchase  a  security  shortly  thereafter, 
surely  that  link  is  far  more  attenuated  between  misstatements  made  in  October 
1977,  and  a  decision  to  sell  a  stock  the  following  September,  11  months  later. 
The  fact  that  the  plaintiff-class  is  one  of  sellers,  and  that  the  class  period  so 
long,  distinguish  this  case  from  any  other  cited  in  the  Court's  opinion,  and 
make  it  an  even  poorer  candidate  for  the  fraud-on-the-market  presumption. 
Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  998  n.9  (White,  J.,  dissenting)  (citation  omitted). 

131.  Id.  dii  998-99  (White,  J.,  dissenting). 


1076  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

on  corporate  behavior.  Likewise,  its  effect  on  plaintiff  class  actions  has 
yet  to  be  observed. 

VI.     The  Basic  Dissent 

Justice  White,  writing  for  the  dissent  in  Basic, ^^^  was  most  concerned 
with  the  the  majority's  uncritical  acceptance  of  the  fraud-on-the-market 
theory.^"  The  dissent  focused  on  the  role  of  Congress  in  shaping  economic 
policy^^"^  and  on  the  problem  of  assessing  damages  in  this  type  of  action. '^^ 

The  fraud-on-the-market  theory  is  a  recent  economic  theory  although 
the  economic  community  and  the  legal  system  have  accepted  it  with 
vigor. ^^^  However,  as  the  dissent  pointed  out,  it  is  a  theory,  neither  fact 
nor  a  "mature  legal  doctrine:  "^^^ 

[WJhile  the  economists'  theories  which  underpin  the  fraud-on- 
the-market  presumption  may  have  the  appeal  of  mathematical 
exactitude  and  scientific  certainty,  they  are  —  in  the  end — nothing 
more  than  theories  which  may  or  may  not  prove  accurate  upon 
further  consideration.  Even  the  most  earnest  advocates  of  ec- 
onomic analysis  of  the  law  recognize  this.'^^ 


132.  Justice  O'Connor  joined  in  the  dissent  to  Part  IV  of  the  Basic  decision.  Both 
Justices  White  and  O'Connor  concurred  with  the  materiality  standard  set  forth  in  TSC 
Industries,  Inc.  v.  Northway,  Inc.,  426  U.S.  438,  (1976)  and  specifically  adopted  in  Basic. 
108  S.  Ct.  at  993. 

133.  Id. 

134.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  996,  997.  For  an  interesting  analysis  of  the  competing 
currents  (idealism,  traditionalism,  economic  behaviorism,  paradigm  case  analysis,  literalism, 
and  textual  structuralism)  evident  in  recent  Supreme  Court  decisions  on  securities  actions, 
see  Phillips,  supra  note  14. 

135.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  998. 

136.  See  Gilson  &  Kraakman,  The  Mechanisms  of  Market  Efficiency,  70  Va.  L. 
Rev.  549  (1984). 

Of  all  recent  developments  in  financial  economics,  the  efficient  market  hypothesis 
.  .  .  has  achieved  the  widest  acceptance  by  the  legal  culture.  It  now  commonly 
informs  the  academic  literature  on  a  variety  of  topics;  it  is  addressed  by  major 
law  school  casebooks  and  textbooks  on  business  law;  it  structures  debate  over 
the  future  of  securities  regulation  both  within  and  without  the  Securities  and 
Exchange  Commission;  it  has  served  as  the  intellectual  premise  for  a  major 
revision  of  the  disclosure  system  administered  by  the  Commission;  and  it  has 
even  begun  to  influence  judicial  decisions  and  the  actual  practice  of  law.  In 
short,  the  [efficient  capital  market  hypothesis]  is  now  the  context  in  which  serious 
discussion  of  the  regulation  of  financial  markets  takes  place. 
Id.  at  549-550. 

137.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  993  (White,  J.,  dissenting). 

138.  Id.  at  995.  See,  e.g.,  Easterbrook,  Afterword:  Knowledge  and  Answers,  85 
CoLUM.  L.  Rev.   1117,   1118  (1985). 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1077 

Pointing  out  the  problems  associated  with  supplanting  "traditional  legal 
analysis  .  .  .  with  economic  theorization,"'^^  the  dissent  looked  to  the 
legislative  history  of  the  Securities  Exchange  Act  of  1934  and  prudential 
judicial  constraint  in  assessing  the  impact  of  the  majority  opinion. 

As  the  dissent  in  Basic  pointed  out,  if  current  economic  theory 
concerning  financial  markets  requires  that  established  legal  ideas  of  fraud 
be  considered  anew,  it  is  Congress'  role  to  do  so.^'^^  The  superior  resources 
and  expertise  of  the  Congress  in  enacting  legislation  should  be  given 
great  deference  by  the  courts.  Even  though  there  is  a  paucity  of  legislative 
history  concerning  Rule  lOb-5,  there  is  sufficient  history  surrounding 
other  portions  of  the  Securities  Exchange  Act  to  glean  the  intent  of 
Congress  in  proposing  and  passing  legislation  which  would  protect  inves- 
tors and  stabilize  the  economy. '"^^ 

The  Seventy-Third  Congress,  passing  Section  18  of  the  1934  Act,''*^ 
imposed  an  express  rehance  requirement.'"^^  Congress  specifically  rejected 
the  notion  that  plaintiffs  could  have  a  cause  of  action  based  '^solely 
on  the  fact  that  the  price  of  the  securities  they  bought  or  sold  was 
affected  by  a  misrepresentation  [without  reliance]:  a  theory  closely  akin 
to  the  [Basic]  Court's  holding  .  .  .  ."''*^  Analyzing  the  majority  opinion, 
the  dissent  viewed  the  acceptance  of  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory  as 
'*eviscerat[ing]  the  rehance  rule  in  actions  brought  under  Rule  lOb-5, 
and  negat[ing]  congressional  intent  to  the  contrary  expressed  during 
adoption  of  the  1934  Act."'^^ 

The  distinction  between  causation  and  reliance  is  blurred  in  the 
majority  opinion.  Causation  "involves  an  analysis  of  the  relationships 


139.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  994. 

140.  Id.  at  996-98. 

141.  Id.  at  997.  See  S.  2693,  73d  Cong,  2d  Sess,  §   17(a)  (1934);  78  Cong  Rec. 
7701  (1934). 

142.  Section  18(a)  of  the  Act  provides  for  civil  liability  for  misleading  statements 
concerning  securities: 

Any  person  who  shall  make  or  cause  to  be  made  any  statement  in  any  appHcation, 
report,  or  document  filed  pursuant  to  this  title  or  any  rule  or  regulation  there- 
under, which  statement  was  at  the  time  and  in  the  light  of  the  circumstances 
under  which  it  was  made  false  or  misleading  with  respect  to  any  material  fact, 
shall  be  liable  to  any  person  (not  knowing  that  such  statement  was  false  or 
misleading)  who,  in  reliance  upon  such  statement,  shall  have  purchased  or  sold 
a  security  at  a  price  which  was  affected  by  such  statement,  for  damages  cause 
by  such  reliance,  unless  the  person  sued  shall  prove  that  he  acted  in  good  faith 
and  had  no  knowledge  that  statement  was  false  or  misleading.  A  person  seeking 
to  enforce  such  liability  may  sue  at  law  or  in  equity  in  any  court  of  competent 
jurisdiction.  (Emphasis  added). 
73d  Congress,  Session  2,  Ch.  404  June  6,  1934  at  897,898. 

143.  Id. 

144.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  997  (White,  J.,  dissenting). 

145.  Id. 


1078  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

between  individuals  and  the  impact  of  their  actions  on  each  other  and 
third  parties. "'"^^  The  defendant's  conduct  was  a  "cause  in  fact"  of  the 
injury,  and  thus  it  should  be  recognized  as  a  legal  cause  on  policy 
grounds. ^"^^  Reliance  is  determined  by  whether  the  misrepresentation  was 
a  substantial  factor  in  determining  the  course  of  conduct  which  resulted 
in  the  plaintiff's  loss.^"^^  A  plaintiff  must  do  more  than  show  that  the 
defendant  violated  the  rule;  she  must  estabhsh  causation,  and,  according 
to  the  dissent,  should  also  be  required  to  show  reliance  in  estabUshing 
causation.  However,  materiaUty  can  estabhsh  causation,  at  least  in  certain 
circumstances.^'*^ 

Additionally,  Congress'  policy  of  full  and  fair  disclosure  is  com- 
promised when  the  disclosure  is  not  directed  to  the  purchaser  or  seller 
of  a  security.  In  1981,  the  dissent  of  Shores  v.  Sklar^^^  stated: 

[DJisclosure  ...  is  crucial  to  the  way  in  which  the  federal 
securities  laws  function.  .  .  .  [TJhe  federal  securities  laws  are 
intended  to  put  investors  into  a  position  from  which  they  can 
help  themselves  by  relying  upon  disclosures  that  others  are  ob- 
Hgated  to  make.  This  system  is  not  furthered  by  allowing  mon- 
etary recovery  to  those  who  refuse  to  look  out  for  themselves. 
If  we  say  that  a  plaintiff  may  recover  in  some  circumstances 
even  though  he  did  not  read  and  rely  on  the  defendants'  pubhc 
disclosures,  then  no  one  need  pay  attention  to  those  disclosures 
and  the  method  employed  by  Congress  to  achieve  the  objective 
of  the  1934  Act  is  defeated. ^^^ 

As  the  dissent  in  Basic  noted,  by  removing  individual  reliance  as 
an  element  in  Rule  lOb-5  actions,  the  Court  is  approaching  an  "investor 


146.  Crane,  An  Analysis  of  Causation  Under  Rule  lOb-5,  9  Sec.  Reg.  L.J.  99,  100 
(1981). 

147.  Restatement  (Second)  of  Torts  §§  546  (causation  in  fact),  548 A  (legal  cause) 
(1977).  Causation  in  common  law  fraud  actions  required  that  the  plaintiff  had  actually 
rehed  on  the  defendant's  misrepresentation  and  was  injured  by  the  reliance.  W.  Prosser, 
Handbook  of  the  Law  of  Torts  §  108,  at  774-75  (4th  ed.  1971). 

148.  Restatement  (Second)  of  Torts  §  546.  See  generally  A.  Bromberg,  Securities 
Fraud  §  8.6(1),  at  209  (Supp.  1970);  L.  Loss,  supra  note  25,  at  1430-44;  Note,  The 
Reliance  Requirement  in  Private  Actions  Under  SEC  Rule  lOb-5,  88  Harv.  L.  Rev.  584 
(1975);  Note,  Reasonable  Reliance  Under  lOb-5:  Is  the  "Reasonable  Investor"  Reasonable?, 
72  CoLUM.  L.  Rev.  562  (1972). 

149.  Mills  V.  Electric  Auto-Lite  Co.,  396  U.S.  375  (1970);  Affihated  Ute  Citizens 
V.  United  States,  406  U.S.  128  (1970). 

150.  647  F.2d  462  (5th  Cir.   1981)  {en  banc),  cert,  denied,  103  S.  Ct.  772  (1983). 

151.  Id.  at  483  (Randall,  J.,  dissenting)  {quoted  in  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  997-98 
(White,  J.,  dissenting)). 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1079 

insurance  scheme. "^^^  The  Court  should  not  overprotect  investors  from 
the  ordinary  risks  involved  in  market  transactions.'" 

It  would  be  a  mischaracterization  of  the  majority  opinion  to  say 
that  it  was  providing  investor  insurance.  Rather,  the  majority  wanted 
to  accompHsh  its  goal  of  facilitating  Rule  lOb-5  litigation '^"^  in  marked 
contrast  with  the  post- 1975  Suprenie  Court  decisions  in  this  area.'^^  The 
Court  in  Basic  did  so  with  its  acceptance  of  the  idea  of  investor  access 
to  all  information  even  when  not  relied  upon  directly,  with  its  recognition 
that  the  pubHc  should  be  protected  from  material  misrepresentations  and 
with  its  appreciation  for  the  deterrence  factor  in  prosecution. 

According  to  Justice  White's  dissent  in  Basic,  the  common  law 
elements  of  fraud  and  deceit  should  remain  in  Rule  lOb-5  actions:  **[T]he 
case  law  developed  in  this  Court  with  respect  to  §  10(b)  and  Rule  10b- 
5  has  been  based  on  doctrines  which  we,  as  judges,  are  famiHar:  common- 
law  doctrines  of  fraud  and  deceit. ''^^^  In  approaching  the  Rule  lOb-5 
action  from  this  perspective,  the  dissent  is  attempting  to  restrain  the 
scope  of  the  action  much  as  the  Court  had  done  in  1975  with  the  Blue 
Chip  case  and  subsequent  cases  until  the  Basic  decision. '^^ 

VII.    Effects  of  the  Basic  Case 

Prior  to  the  Basic  decision,  the  circuit  courts  were  divided  in  their 
appUcation  of  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory'^^  to  secondary  markets 
and/or  to  newly  issued  securities  on  undeveloped  markets. '^^  This  situation 
has  not  been  remedied  by  the  decision  in  Basic. 


152.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  996. 

153.  See  Easterbrook  &  Fischel,  Mandatory  Disclosure  and  the  Protection  of  Inves- 
tors, 70  Va.  L.  Rev.  669  (1984);  Note,  Causation  in  Fraud-on-the-Market  Actions — 
Investors'  Insurance  in  the  Second  Circuit?,  49  Brooklyn  L.  Rev.  1291  (1983). 

154.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  990. 

155.  Justice  Blackmun  has  written  several  dissents  expressing  his  view  on  the  Court's 
post  1975  decisions.  In  Blue  Chip  Stamps  v.  Manor  Drug  Stores,  421  U.S.  723  (1975) 
(Blackmun,  J.,  dissenting),  Justice  Blackmun  stated:  "[T]he  Court  exhibits  a  preternatural 
solicitousness  for  corporate  well-being  and  a  seeming  callousness  toward  the  investing 
public  quite  out  of  keeping,  it  seems  to  me,  with  our  own  traditions  and  the  intent  of 
the  securities  laws."  Id.  In  his  dissent  to  Dirks  v.  SEC,  463  U.S.  646  (1983),  Justice 
Blackmun  remarked  that  '*[t]he  Court  today  takes  still  another  step  to  limit  the  protections 
provided  investors  by  §  10(b)  of  the  Securities  Exchange  Act  of  1934."  Id. 

156.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  994.  See,  Sachs,  The  Relevance  of  Tort  Law  Doctrines 
to  Rule  lOb-5:  Should  Careless  Plaintiffs  Be  Denied  Recovery?,  71  Cornell  L.  Rev.  96 
(1985). 

157.  Blue  Chip  Stamps,  421  U.S.  723  (1975).  See  supra  notes  15-17  and  accompanying 
text. 

158.  See  supra  note  72. 

159.  See  supra  note  73. 


1080  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

The  majority  opinion  has  not  limited  specifically  application  of  the 
theory  to  secondary  markets. ^^°  Lower  courts  have  noted  that  the  fraud- 
on-the-market  theory  is  based  on  the  idea  that  there  is  a  ''nearly  perfect 
market  in  information"  ^^^  and  that  the  price  of  a  security  is  a  reflection 
of  its  intrinsic  value. ^^^  This  assumption  of  a  "perfect  market  in  in- 
formation" may  not  be  applicable  to  newly  issued  stock  on  undeveloped 
markets.  The  "efficiency"  of  these  markets  must  be  determined  before 
the  fraud-on-the-market  presumption  is  applied.'"  Therefore,  the  fraud- 
on-the-market  theory  should  be  limited  to  secondary  market  transactions 
or  those  cases  where  the  undeveloped  market  has  been  proven  to  be 
efficient.'^  Where  the  market  is  inefficent,  the  plaintiff  should  have  to 
prove  reliance  on  material  misrepresentations.  However,  at  least  one 
court  has  applied  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory  to  newly  issued  securities 
since  the  Basic  opinion. '^^ 

Additionally,  once  a  material  misrepresentation  is  proven,  the  reliance 
issue  can  be  viewed  in  at  least  two  ways,  either  as  a  complete  elimination 
of  the  reliance  element  or  as  a  reduction  in  the  plaintiff's  burden  of 
estabhshing  direct  reliance  by  providing  a  presumption  of  indirect  reliance. 
The  Court  in  Basic  specifically  did  not  eliminate  the  reliance  element. '^^ 
However,  because  the  Basic  Court  did  not  distinguished  the  fraud-on- 
the-market  theory  of  reliance  from  a  causation  theory,  the  dissent  is 
correct  when  it  states  that  the  majority  has  moved  dangerously  close  to 
removing  the  reUance  element  altogether.'^''  Under  a  causation  approach, 
the  only  question  is  whether  the  material  misstatement  or  omission  caused 
the  plaintiff's  injury. '^^  Once  a  causation  approach  is  adopted,  the 
presumption  becomes  nonrebuttable.'^^ 


160.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  991.  "Indeed,  nearly  every  court  that  has  considered  the 
proposition  has  concluded  that  where  materially  misleading  statements  have  been  dissem- 
inated into  an  impersonal,  well-developed  market  for  securities,  the  reliance  of  individual 
plaintiffs  of  the  integrity  of  the  market  price  may  be  presumed."  Id. 

161.  Peil,  806  F.2d  1154,  1161  n.lO. 

162.  Id. 

163.  Wemple  &  Westover,  Rule  lOb-5  Securities  Fraud:  Regulating  the  Application 
of  the  Fraud-on-the-Market  Theory  of  Liability,  18  J.  Mar.  L.  Rev.  733,  745-748  (1985). 

164.  See  id.;  Black,  Fraud-on-the-Market:  A  Criticism  of  Dispensing  with  Reliance 
Requirements  in  Certain  Open  Market  Transactions,  62  N.C.L.  Rev.  435  (1984). 

165.  Shores  v.  Sklar,  647  F.2d  462  (5th  Cir.  1981)  {en  banc),  cert,  denied,  459  U.S. 
1102  (1983),  rev 'd  sub  nom.  (in  part)  Fed.  Sec.  L.  Rep.  (CCH)  1  92,874,  appeal  dismissed, 
844  F.2d  1485,  vacated,  reh'g  granted,  855  F.2d  722  (11th  Cir.   1988)  {en  banc). 

166.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  989. 

167.  Id.  at  997  (White,  J.,  dissenting). 

168.  See  Panzirer  v.  Wolf,  663  F.2d  365  (2d  Cir.  1981),  vacated  as  moot,  463  U.S. 
646  (1982). 

169.  Blackie  v.  Barrack,  524  F.2d  891,  906-07,  n.22.  Justice  White  notes: 

[II n  practice  the  Court  must  realize,  as  other  courts  applying  the  fraud-on-the- 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1081 

The  Court  in  Basic  did  not  address  the  computation  of  damages  in 
a  Rule  lOb-5  cause  of  action, ^''^  but  as  Justice  White  noted,  "the  proper 
measure  of  damages  in  a  fraud-on-the-market  case  [is]  essential  for 
proper  implementation  of  the  fraud-on-the-market  presumption. "•^'  The 
measure  of  damages  under  Rule  lOb-5  is  beyond  the  scope  of  this  Note;'^^ 
however,  until  the  Court  or  Congress  speaks  to  this  issue,  uncertainty 
and  a  diversity  of  decisions  will  continue. 

One  implication  of  the  Basic  case  is  that  an  investor  might  be  well 
advised  not  to  read  disclosure  documents  corporations  provide.  This  is 
an  interesting  turn  of  events  because  providing  disclosures  to  the  public 
to  enable  investors  to  make  reasonable  and  informed  decisions  concerning 
the  risk  they  are  undertaking  is  at  the  heart  of  the  securities  regulations. 
As  a  result  of  no  longer  requiring  proof  of  direct  reliance,  the  protection 
of  the  securities  regulations  is  afforded  to  those  who  have  acted  irre- 
sponsibly for  failing  to  inform  themselves  with  readily  available  infor- 
mation. However,  it  must  be  noted  that  because  of  their  complexity, 
few  investors,  even  those  with  a  relatively  high  level  of  sophistication, 
read  disclosure  statements. '"^^  In  addition,  if  the  efficient  market  hy- 
pothesis is  correct,  anything  that  has  been  disclosed  publicly  will  have 
affected  the  market  place  fully  and  instantaneously  thereby  precluding 
the  individual  investor  from  outperforming  the  market. '^"^  An  investor 
should  not  have  to  rely  directly  on  disclosure  documents  that  are  not 
useful.  The  investor  has  relied  on  the  disclosure,  albeit  indirectly,  by 
looking  to  the  market  to  perform  the  function  of  interpreting  and 
accurately  pricing  the  securities  based  on  the  disclosures.  Therefore,  the 
appparent  inconsistency  between  the  policy  of  full  disclosure  and  investor 


market  theory  have,  that  such  rebuttal  is  virtually  impossible  in  all  but  the  most 
extraordinary  case.  .  .  .  [Tjhe  majority's  implicit  rejection  of  the  'pure  causation' 
fraud-on-the-market  theory  rings  hollow.  In  most  cases,  the  Court's  theory  will 
operate  just  as  the  causation  theory  would,  creating  a  non-rebuttable  presumption 
of  'reliance'  in  future  lOb-5  actions. 
Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  996  n.7  (White,  J.,  dissenting). 

170.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  995  n.5  (White,  J.,  dissenting).  Justice  White  quotes  R. 
PosNER,  Economic  Analysis  of  Law  §15.8,  423-24  (3d  ed.  1986). 

171.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  995  n.5. 

172.  Note,  The  Measure  of  Damages  Under  Section  10(b)  and  Rule  lOb-5,  46  Md. 
L.  Rev.  1266  (1987).  See  generally  D.  Dobbs,  Handbook  on  the  Law  of  Remedies  § 
9.3  (1973);  A.  Jacobs,  Litigation  and  Practice  Under  Rule  10b-5  §  260.03  (2d  ed. 
1983);  Thompson,  The  Measure  of  Recovery  Under  Rule  lOb-5:  A  Restitution  Alternative 
to  Tort  Damages,  37  Vand.  L.  Rev.  349  (1984);  Recent  Development,  Damages  for  Insider 
Trading  in  the  Open  Market:  A  New  Limitation  on  Recovery  Under  Rule  IOb-5,  34  Vand. 
L.  Rev.  797  (1981). 

173.  Kripke,  The  Myth  of  the  Informed  Layman,  28  Bus.  Law.  631  (1973). 

174.  H.  Kripke,  The  SEC  and  Corporate  Disclosure  86-87  (1979).  See  Black, 
supra  note  19,  at  458. 


1082  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1061 

failure  to  read  investment  information  is  not  as  great  as  it  may  at  first 
appear. 

The  decision  in  Basic  will  have  a  great  impact  potentially  on  cor- 
porations and  their  counsel.  The  issue  of  corporate  disclosure  of  in- 
formation is  perceived  to  be  fraught  with  difficulties. ^^^  Corporations 
must  provide  sufficient  disclosure  so  that  the  market  can  set  a  value  to 
the  corporate  securities,  that  is,  price  shares  at  their  intrinsic  worth,  and 
yet  not  jeopardize  shareholders'  best  interests. '^^  Until  recently,  the  Se- 
curities Exchange  Commission  prohibited  the  inclusion  in  fiUngs  of  most 
"soft  information"  such  as  earnings  projections  and  asset  appraisals. *^^ 
As  the  SEC  broadens  its  poHcy  to  include  this  type  of  information  as 
part  of  disclosure  requirements  and  as  the  courts  renew  efforts  to  protect 
investors  and  deter  corporate  behavior  characterized  as  unethical,  if  not 
fraudulent,  counsel  must  consider  carefully  the  ramifications  of  any 
corporate  statement.  Attorneys  in  the  corporate  legal  community  will 
perceive  this  responsibility  as  beyond  the  traditional  prudent  standard 
of  care  required  of  them. 

VIII.     Conclusion 

The  Supreme  Court,  with  the  Basic  case,  had  the  opportunity  to 
establish  the  limits  of  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory.  For  example,  the 


175.  See  Bagby  &  Ruhnka,  The  Predictability  of  Materiality  in  Merger  Negotiations 
Following  Basic,  16  Sec.  Reg.  L.J.  245  (1988)  [hereinafter  cited  as  Predictability].  In 
addition  to  the  fraud-on-the-market  theory,  the  Basic  Court  determined  the  materiality 
standard  to  be  applied  to  preliminary  merger  or  acquisition  negotiations. 

Th[e]  disclosure  dilemma  is  complicated  by  several  conflicting  public  policy  and 
private  policy  interests.  On  the  one  hand,  the  SEC  usually  urges  'prompt' 
disclosure  ...  to  enhance  the  market's  efficiency.  ...  By  contrast,  corporate 
managers  have  long  argued  that  'premature'  announcement  of  merger  or  ac- 
quisition negotiations  will  cause  a  run  up  in  the  target  company's  stock  price, 
possibly  jeopardizing  negotiations  to  the  detriment  of  shareholders.  .  .  .  This 
duty  and  the  regulatory  trend  in  disclosure  toward  'stopwatch  jurisprudence' 
can  present  conflicting  legal  obligations  that  produce  a  'damned  if  you  do — 
damned  if  you  don't'  potential  for  liability.  Predictability,  at  246. 

See  Ruhnka  &  Bagby,  Disclosure:  Dammed  If  You  Do,  Dammed  If  You  Don't,  64  Harv. 

Bus.  Rev.  34  (September-October  1986). 

176.  See  Predictability,  supra  note  176,  at  246. 

177.  Hiller,  The  SEC  and  the  Courts'  Approach  to  Disclosure  of  Earnings  Projec- 
tions, Asset  Appraisals,  and  Other  Soft  Information:  Old  Problems,  Changing  View,  46 
Md.  L.  Rev.  1114  (1987).  The  SEC's  policy  on  soft  information  disclosure  has  undergone 
significant  revision  during  the  past  ten  years.  Neither  outdated  policy  concerns  which 
prohibited  disclosure  of  soft  information  nor  concern  for  corporate  liability  can  excuse 
misleading  disclosure.  Investors  must  receive  full  disclosure  in  order  to  assess  risk  com- 
petently. Id.  at  1195-96.  See  generally  Symposium:  Affirmative  Disclosure  Obligations 
Under  the  Securities  Laws,  46  Md.  L.  Rev.  907  (1987). 


1989]  FRAUD-ON-THE-MARKET  1083 

fraud-on-the-market  theory,  dependent  as  it  is  on  the  efficient  market 
hypothesis,  should  be  applied  only  to  those  situations  where  the  market 
is  developed  or  proven  to  be  efficient.  Instead,  the  Court  approved  the 
fraud-on-the-market  theory  without  Umitation. 

Furthermore,  the  Court  in  Basic  had  the  opportunity  to  analyze  the 
distinction  between  reliance  and  causation.  Even  though  the  Court  states 
that  reliance  is  not  ehminated  as  an  element  in  a  Rule  lOb-5  action,  ^^^ 
the  practical  effect  of  the  Court's  decision  is  to  create  a  reUance- 
causation  equivalency.  In  doing  so,  the  presumption  becomes  non-re- 
buttable.  Although  the  Court  gives  examples  of  how  the  presumption 
of  reliance  can  be  rebutted, '^^  the  defendant  is  put  in  the  position  of 
proving  a  speculative  negative,  for  instance  that  the  plaintiff  disbelieved 
corporate  misstatements  or  would  have  traded  despite  knowing  the  state- 
ments were  untrue.  The  Court  has  shifted  the  "unnecessarily  unrealistic 
evidentiary  burden" '^^  from  plaintiff  to  defendant.  However,  this  al- 
location of  the  burden  of  proof  between  the  parties  may  be  reasonable 
in  light  of  the  plaintiff's  required  showing  of  a  material  misrepresentation 
by  the  defendant. 

Because  of  inroads  on  the  requirement  of  disclosure  of  seemingly 
"soft  information,"'*^  a  fluid  standard  on  the  question  of  materiality,'*^ 
and  the  suggestion  that  class  action  plaintiffs  will  not  be  dismissed 
easily,'*^  corporate  counsel  may  want  to  devise  new  strategies  for  advising 
disclosure  practices  among  clients. 

There  is  general  discontent  mixed  with  great  interest  in  the  "greed 
is  good  -  greed  works" '^"^  philosophy  portrayed  in  the  recent  film  Wall 
Street. ^^^  The  local  newspapers,  as  well  as  the  national  business  journals, 
will  continue  to  cover  the  various  million  and  biUion  dollar  insider 
trading,  leveraged  buyout,  and  junk  bond  stories.  The  investing  public 
may  feel  some  measure  of  vindication  in  knowing  that  they  may  suc- 
cessfully bring  a  Rule  lOb-5  class  action  more  easily  after  Basic  even  if 
their  dollar  figure  is  significantly  smaller  than  the  stories  making  the 
headlines.  Perhaps  that  is  all  the  Court  wanted  to  accompUsh. 

Rosemary  J.  Thomas 


178.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  989. 

179.  Id.  at  990. 

180.  Id.  at  989. 

181.  See  supra  text  accompanying  note  177. 

182.  See  supra  text  accompanying  note  74, 

183.  Basic,  108  S.  Ct.  at  990-91. 

184.  Wall  Street,  Twentieth-Century  Fox  Film  Corp.  (1987). 

185.  Id. 


Institutional  Arrangements  for  Governing  the  Construction 
of  Electric  Generating  Units:  A  Transaction  Cost  Analysis 

I.     Introduction 

The  total  cost  of  providing  this  nation's  electric  utility  service  is  in 
excess  of  $150  billion  per  year.'  During  the  past  decade,  an  increasing 
portion  of  that  cost  has  resulted  from  the  construction  of  generating 
plants  which  ultimately  are  either  canceled  or  redundant.^  Recent  estimates 
indicate  that  some  $50  biUion  have  been  spent  on  plants  which  were 
canceled  before  ever  going  into  service,  while  biUions  more  have  been 
spent  on  plants  which  are  redundant  due  to  excess  capacity  in  the  system.^ 
In  most  cases,  the  canceled  or  redundant  plant  was  planned  and  con- 
structed by  utility  investors  in  a  good  faith  effort  to  provide  ample 
electric  power  resources  for  robust  economic  growth/ 

As  electricity  prices  have  spiraled  ever  higher,  regulatory  commissions 
have  begun  to  disallow  complete  recovery  of  costs  which  are  attributable 
to  canceled  or  redundant  plants.^  For  consumers,  the  immediate  effect 
of  these  cost  disallowances  has  been  a  significant  reduction  in  utility 
bills  relative  to  full-recovery  levels.^  For  the  utilities  concerned,  the  most 
immediate  effect  has  been  financial  hardship  or  bankruptcy.^  The  long 
term  consequences  to  both  consumers  and  investors  may  be  less  readily 
observable,  but  they  are  equally  important.  For  example,  some  analysts 


1.  Standard  &  Poor's,  Utility  Compustat  II  (1988). 

2.  Depending  on  jurisdiction,  estimates  go  as  high  as  20*^0.  See  e.g.,  Komanoff, 
Assessing  the  High  Costs  of  New  Nuclear  Power  Plants,  Pub.  Util.  Fort.,  Oct.  11,  1984. 

3.  Id.  at  33. 

4.  No  cases  have  been  found  in  which  a  utility  was  charged  with  intentionally 
constructing  excess  electric  capacity. 

5.  States  which  have  disallowed  construction  costs  include  Maine,  New  Hampshire, 
Vermont,  Delaware,  New  Yoric,  Pennsylvania,  Connecticut,  Massachusetts,  Ohio,  Indiana, 
Michigan,  Kentucky,  Georgia,  Illinois,  Missouri,  California,  Washington,  South  Carolina, 
Alabama,  Mississippi,  Texas,  Oregon  and  Idaho.  The  Salomon  Brothers  100  Electric  Utilities 
-  Company  Summaries  (1987). 

6.  For  example,  in  the  recent  case  of  Public  Service  Co.  of  Indiana,  a  27%  rate 
reduction  was  urged  by  intervenors  based  on  the  difference  between  emergency  and  cost- 
based  rates.  Indiana  Utility  Regulatory  Commission,  Cause  No.  37414.  In  the  case  of 
Northern  Indiana  Public  Service  Co.,  the  regulatory  agency  ultimately  disallowed  some 
$200  miUion  in  utility  costs  -  resulting  in  an  annual  levenue  reduction  of  approximately 
$40  miUion.  Public  Service  Commission  of  Indiana,  Cause  No.  37023. 

7.  Among  the  investor-owned  utilities  which  have  faced  threats  of  bankruptcy 
due  to  construction  cost  disallowances  are  Long  Island  Lighting  Co.,  Middle  South  Utilities, 
Consumers  Power  Co.,  Gulf  States  Utihties,  Public  Service  Co.  of  Indiana  and  Public 
Service  Co.  of  New  Hampshire. 

1085 


1086  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

have  predicted  that  significant  shortages  in  electricity  supply  will  occur 
in  the  1990's  as  investors  become  increasingly  concerned  that  the  con- 
struction of  new  generating  facilities  does  not  provide  the  opportunity 
for  reward  commensurate  with  the  investment  risk.^  Even  if  shortages 
do  not  occur,  it  is  anticipated  that  the  increasing  risk  will  manifest  itself 
in  higher  costs  of  capital  for  utilities  engaged  in  construction — and, 
ultimately,  in  higher  rates  for  the  consumers  of  electric  power. ^ 

In  response  to  this  and  other  problems,  a  variety  of  regulatory 
reforms  have  been  proposed. ^°  Those  reforms  are  widely  disparate  and 
may  be  mutually  exclusive. ^^  While  most  of  the  reform  proposals  advocate 
introducing  competition  to  utility  markets,  there  is  significant  disagree- 
ment as  to  the  appropriate  nature  or  extent  of  that  competition.^^  Due 
to  the  significant  financial  impact  of  any  reform  alternative,  it  is  im- 
perative that  any  alteration  in  current  policy  be  a  well-reasoned  response 
aimed  at  minimizing  total  costs. ^^ 

This  discussion  evaluates  potential  institutional  structures  for  gov- 
erning transactions  between  utility  investors  and  consumers  by  applying 
the  theories  of  transaction  cost  analysis.  Transaction  cost  analysis  is  a 
framework  for  evaluating  contractual  relations  with  an  increased  emphasis 


8.  See,  e.g.,  Power  Supply  Forecasts  Grow  Pessimistic,  Wall  St,  J.,  October  12, 
1988  at  A2,  col.  2;  P.  Navarro,  The  Dimming  of  America  (1985);  Studness,  Why  a 
Shortage  of  Electric  Generating  Capacity  is  All  But  Inescapable,  Pub.  Util.  Fort.,  August 
22,  1985,  at  p.  44. 

9.  Estimates  by  financial  professionals  included  a  200  basis  point  risk  premium 
in  cost  of  equity  calculations  performed  for  Public  Service  Company  of  Indiana  in  a  1986 
rate  case  following  Indiana's  disallowance  of  some  $2.8  million  of  construction  costs. 
Testimonies  of  Prof.  Eugene  Brigham,  Ph.D.,  and  John  Curley,  Morgan  Stanley  &  Co., 
in  Public  Service  Company  of  Indiana's  rate  case  before  the  Indiana  Utility  Regulatory 
Commission,  Cause  No.  37414  (1985). 

10.  A  good  overview  of  specific  proposals  can  be  found  in  P.  Joskow  &  R. 
Schmalensee,  Markets  For  Power:  An  Analysis  of  Electric  Utility  Deregulation 
(1983).  Other  proposals  can  be  found  in  Plummer,  A  Different  Approach  to  Electricity 
Deregulation,  Pub.  Util.  Fort.,  July  7,  1983,  at  16;  Meyer,  A  Modest  Proposal  for  the 
Partial  Deregulation  of  Electric  Utilities,  Pub.  Util.  Fort.,  April  14,  1983,  at  23;  Dowd 
&  Burton,  Deregulation  is  Not  an  Answer  for  Electric  Utilities,  Pub.  Util.  Fort.,  September 
16,  1982,  at  21;  Killian  &  Trout,  Alternatives  for  Electric  Utility  Deregulation,  Pub.  Util. 
Fort.,  September  16,  1982,  at  34;  Butler,  A  Social  Compact  to  be  Restored,  Pub.  Util. 
Fort.,  December  26,  1985,  at  17;  Scranton,  Reforming  and  Improving  Electric  Utility 
Regulation,  Pub.  Uttl.  Fort.,  August  4,  1983,  at  19;  and  the  proposals  discussed  in  Re 
Pricing  and  Rate-making  Treatment  for  New  Electric  Generating  Facilities  Which  Are  Not 
Qualifying  Facilities,  93  PUR  4th  313  (Mass.  Dept.  Pub.  Util.   1988). 

1 1 .  For  example,  the  deregulation  proposals  are  mutually  exclusive  with  the  approach 
taken  in  Massachusetts.  See  infra  notes  105-07  and  133-43  and  accompanying  text. 

12.  This  debate  is  articulated  in  the  articles  cited  in  note  10,  above. 

13.  Total  costs  are  defined  to  include  the  costs  of  producing  electricity  and  the 
costs  of  negotiating,  monitoring  and  enforcing  the  transaction. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1087 

on  the  economic  and  behavioral  characteristics  of  the  transaction  and 
the  actors  involved.''*  It  recognizes  that  a  determination  of  the  most 
efficient  institutional  arrangement  for  governing  transactions  must  take 
into  account  the  costs  of  negotiating,  monitoring  and  enforcing  the 
contract.'^  It  also  recognizes  that  characteristics  such  as  the  uncertainty, 
complexity  and  frequency  of  the  transaction  are  central  in  predicting 
those  costs,  and  that  the  potential  for  opportunistic  behavior  is  an 
important  factor  in  determining  least-cost  institutional  structures.'^ 

II.     An  Overview  of  the  Industry 

The  electric  utility  industry  encompasses  the  generation,  transmission 
and  distribution  of  electric  power. '^  Generation  is  the  production  of 
electric  power,  typically  from  fossil  fuels;  transmission  is  the  bulk  transfer 
of  power  at  high  voltages  from  the  generating  unit  to  the  local  distribution 
grid;  and  distribution  is  the  disbursement  of  low  voltage  power  to  end- 
users.'^  Although  the  physics  of  electricity  require  that  the  generation, 
transmission  and  distribution  systems  operate  together  as  a  coordinated 
whole, '^  there  is  no  legal  requirement  that  all  of  those  services  must  be 
provided  by  a  single  company. ^°  Economies  of  scale,  however,  have  led 
to  a  large  amount  of  vertical  integration  within  the  industry  so  that,  in 
most  cases,  the  generation,  transmission  and  distribution  functions  are 
all  accomplished  by  one  corporate  structure.^' 

Most  companies  in  the  electric  utility  industry  are  privately  owned 
and  operated. ^^  There  are,  however,  a  large  number  of  co-operative 
utilities,  as  well  as  some  utilities  which  are  governmentally  owned. ^^  All 
utilities  are  granted  a  legally  enforceable  monopoly  franchise  to  provide 
service  to  some  particular  geographical  area.^"^  This  monopoly  franchise 
is  granted  in  recognition  of  the  economies  of  scale  which  can  be  realized 
by  constructing  only  one  transmission/distribution  system. ^^  The  mo- 


14.  Williamson,  Assessing  Contract,  1  J.  Law,  Econ.  and  Organ.   177,  at  179 
(1985). 

15.  P.  JosKOw  &  R,  Schmalensee,  supra  note  10,  at  109. 

16.  Id.  at  111. 

17.  A  good  overview  of  the  electric  utility  industry  can  be  found  in  C.  Phillips, 
The  Regulation  of  Public  Utilities  (1985). 

18.  See,  e.g.,  P.  Joskow  &  R.  Schmalensee,  supra  note  10,  at  25. 

19.  L.  Hyman,  Americans  Electric  Utilities:  Past,  Present,  and  Future  (1983). 

20.  P.  JosKOW  &  R.  Schmalensee,  supra  note  10,  at  11. 

21.  Id.  at  11. 

22.  Id.  at  12. 

23.  Id. 

24.  P.  JosKow  &  R.  Schmalensee,  supra  note  10,  at  29-32.  See  also  C.  Phillips, 
supra  note  17,  at  38-41. 

25.  Id. 


1088  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

nopoly  franchise  is  granted  subject  to  limitations  imposed  by  regulatory 
authorities  who  determine  utility  rates  calculated  to  preclude  monopoly 
prof  its.  ^^ 

The  sale  of  electricity  is  regulated  by  both  state  and  federal  regulatory 
agencies.^^  The  Federal  Energy  Regulatory  Commission  (FERC)  has  ju- 
risdiction over  wholesale  transactions  between  electric  utilities  based  on 
the  federal  commerce  power, ^^  while  state  regulatory  agencies  generally 
have  jurisdiction  over  sales  between  the  utility  and  its  retail  customer s.^^ 
State  authority  over  utility  rates  and  charges  is  limited  when  a  state 
decision  is  inconsistent  with  some  federal  determination. ^° 

The  decisions  of  both  state  and  federal  regulatory  agencies  are  framed 
within  the  parameters  of  statutes  and  case  law.^^  Although  the  admin- 
istrative agency  ultimately  determines  the  absolute  level  of  rates  and 
charges,  the  parameters  of  that  decision  are  determined  by  statutes  as 
interpreted  by  the  courts.  For  example,  in  Citizens  Action  Coalition  of 
Indiana  v.  Northern  Indiana  Public  Service  Co,,^^  the  Indiana  Supreme 
Court  interpreted  Indiana  statutes  to  preclude  a  particular  state  com- 
mission determination.  In  the  general  rate  case  which  spawned  that 
litigation,  the  Indiana  commission  had  determined  the  legal  level  of  rates 
and  charges  based  on  the  commission's  determination  of  the  value  of 
NIPSCO's  utility  plant."  That  net  plant  value  included  costs  incurred 
during  the  partial  construction  of  an  electric  generating  unit  which  had 
ultimately  been  cancelled.  The  commission's  decision  was  overturned  by 
the  Indiana  Supreme  Court  which  held  that  the  commission's  determi- 
nation was  contrary  to  Indiana  law  which  allows  only  '*used  and  useful" 
plants  to  be  included  in  the  calculation  of  utility  rates  and  charges.^"* 
On  remand,  the  regulatory  commission  recalculated  plant  value  in  ac- 
cordance with  the  guidelines  of  the  state  court. ^^ 

III.    The  Construction  of  Electric  Generating  Capacity 

Before  evaluating  the  effect  of  institutional  structure  on  the  gov- 
ernance of  any  transaction,  the  characteristic  features  of  that  transaction 


26.  C.  Phillips,  supra  note  17,  at  75-77. 

27.  P.  JosKOw  &  R.  ScHMALENSEE,  supra  note  10,  at  117,  127. 

28.  Id.  at  69-72. 

29.  Id.  at  117. 

30.  See,  e.g.,  Mississippi  Power  &  Light  Co.  v.  Mississippi,  108  S.  Ct.  2428  (1988); 
Nantahala  Power  &  Light  Co.  v.  Thornburg,  476  U.S.  953  (1986). 

31.  Utility  regulatory  agencies,  like  all  administrative  agencies,  must  operate  within 
the  confines  of  law.  Due  to  the  significant  public  interest  in  public  utilities,  there  is  a 
significant  amount  of  both  statutory  and  judicial  law  on  most  issues.  The  development 
of  public  utility  law  can  be  found  in  C.  Phillips,  supra  note  17,  at  67-108. 

32.  485  N.E.2d  610  (Ind.  1985),  affg  All  N.E.2d  938  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1984). 

33.  Pubhc  Service  Commission  of  Indiana,  Cause  No.  37023. 

34.  Citizens  Action  Coalition  of  Indiana,  485  N.E,2d  610. 

35.  Public  Service  Commission  of  Indiana,  Cause  No.  37023. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1089 

must  be  clearly  understood.  This  Note  focuses  on  the  transaction  between 
utility  investors  and  consumers  in  which  investors  agree  to  provide  electric 
generating  capacity  while  consumers  agree  to  pay  for  that  service.  Among 
the  distinguishing  features  of  the  transaction  are  the  length  of  time 
required  to  complete  the  exchange  and  the  high  degree  of  idiosyncrasy 
of  the  physical  asset. 

The  length  of  time  required  to  construct  a  utility  power  plant  ranges 
from  five  to  ten  years  depending  on  such  factors  as  size,  type,  location. ^^ 
In  addition,  full  recovery  of  the  plant's  value  is  not  achieved  until  the 
completion  of  its  useful  life  if  the  transaction  is  governed  by  traditional 
regulatory  structures. ^^  This  pay-back  period  is  longer  than  that  of  most 
other  investments  and  subjects  the  transaction  to  a  greater  degree  of 
uncertainty.^^  During  construction,  a  variety  of  factors  are  subject  to 
change,  including:  the  cost  of  borrowed  money,  the  cost  of  materials 
and  supplies,  the  design  standards  for  the  unit,  and  the  demand  for  the 
final  output. ^^  Because  all  of  those  factors  can  have  a  significant  impact 
on  costs  and/or  profits,  the  length  of  the  construction  period  directly 
impacts  the  uncertainty  of  the  transaction."^^ 

The  "idiosyncratic"  characteristics  of  a  utility  plant  are  also  sig- 
nificant."*^ Idiosyncratic  investments  are  investments  which  are  of  value 
primarily  to  the  original  parties  to  the  transaction;  they  cannot  be 
marketed  to  third  parties  if  the  original  transaction  cannot  be  completed. '^^ 
The  presence  of  idiosyncratic  investments  creates  the  potential  for  op- 
portunistic behavior  by  a  party  poised  to  take  advantage  of  differences 
in  ex  post  versus  ex  ante  valuation."*^  An  investment  in  electric  generating 


36.  Estimate  of  A.  Chang.  Ph.D.,  Assistant  Chief-Technical  Analysis,  Indiana 
Utility  Regulatory  Commission. 

37.  Full  recovery  is  accomplished  by  the  collection  of  depreciation  expense  as  an 
element  of  authorized  rates  and  charges.  Because  depreciation  expense  is  calculated  and 
collected  according  to  the  useful  life  of  the  plant,  full  recovery  is  not  complete  until  that 
period  of  time  has  expired.  See  Federal  Regulatory  Energy  Commission,  Uniform 
System  of  Accounts  (1983). 

38.  Teisberg,  Investment  Cost  Recovery  and  Incentive  for  Power  Plant  Construction, 
Pub.  Util.  Fort.  March  3,  1988,  at  9. 

39.  Changes  in  design  standards  during  construction  have  been  cited  as  a  primary 
reason  for  the  high  cost  of  nuclear  power  plant  construction.  See,  e.g.,  Komanoff,  supra 
note  2. 

40.  Uncertainty  here  is  defined  to  mean  that  probabilities  cannot  be  assigned  for 
potential  outcomes.  This  is  distinguished  from  risk  which  recognized  that  unfavorable 
outcomes  may  occur,  but  that  they  can  be  identified  and  quantified  as  to  probability. 

41.  A  more  complete  discussion  of  idiosyncrasy  and  its  effects  on  transaction  costs 
can  be  found  in  Williamson,  infra  note  49.  See  also  infra  notes  76-79. 

42.  Id.  at  239-41. 

43.  Ex  ante  means  before  the  transaction,  ex  post  means  after  the  transaction. 
Discussions  of  idiosyncrasy  and  opportunistic  behavior  can  be  found  in  WiUiamson,  supra 
note  14,  Williamson,  infra  note  49,  and  Pierce,  A  Proposal  to  Deregulate  the  Market  for 
Bulk  Power,  11  Va.  L.  R.  1183  (1986). 


1090  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

capacity  is  highly  idiosyncratic  for  both  physical  and  institutional  rea- 
sons."^ Physically,  electric  generating  units  cannot  be  moved  and  the 
power  they  produce  cannot  be  ** wheeled"  long  distances  due  to  a  variety 
of  engineering  constraints/^  Institutionally,  the  unified  ownership  of 
generation  and  distribution  facilities  creates  incentives  for  each  utility 
to  purchase  power  only  from  its  own  generating  units  so  that  full  recovery 
of  those  construction  costs  can  be  realized/^ 

IV.    Transaction  Cost  Analysis:  A  Lav^  and  Economics  Approach 

A  variety  of  economic  theories  may  be,  and  have  been,  applied  to 
evaluate  which  institutional  arrangements  are  most  likely  to  lead  to  the 
efficient  governance  of  contractual  relationships/^  This  analysis  applies 
*  transaction  cost"  theories  to  determine  which  institutional  arrangements 
are  most  likely  to  lead  to  the  efficient  governance  of  the  contractual 
relationship  between  utility  investors  and  consumers/^  Although  trans- 
action cost  theories  were  first  described  by  Coase  some  50  years  ago, 
they  have  only  recently  been  developed  by  a  new  school  of  institutional 
economists  including  WilHamson,  Klein,  Joskow,  Goldberg  and  others/^ 

In  his  1937  paper  'The  Nature  of  the  Firm,"  Ronald  Coase  argued 
that  governance  structures  emerge  to  minimize  the  costs  of  making 
transactions/^  The  governance  structures  Coase  considered  included  both 
internal  (corporate)  and  external  (market)  structures.  He  recognized  that 
the  determination  of  whether  an  internal  (intracorporate)  or  external 
(market  exchange)  framework  governed  an  exchange  between  two  or 
more  parties  depended  on  which  institutional  arrangement  could  most 


44.  The  institutional  reasons  for  generating  asset  idiosyncrasy  are  described  in 
Pierce,  supra  note  43. 

45.  Wheeling  is  moving  electric  power  from  one  company's  service  territory  to 
another's.  See,  e.g.,  Casazza,  Understanding  the  Transmission  Access  and  Wheeling  Prob- 
lem, Pub.  Util.  Fort.  October  31,  1985,  at  35. 

46.  So  long  as  the  generation  and  distribution  functions  are  owned  by  the  same 
entity,  joint  profit  maximization  will  require  that  the  distributor  purchase  power  from 
affiliated  generating  unit  unless  the  difference  in  operating  costs  is  unreasonable  large. 

47.  Among  the  economic  theories  which  have  been  applied  to  problems  in  contract 
are  price  theory  and  the  theory  of  property  rights.  See,  e.g.,  Posner,  The  Chicago  School 
of  Antitrust  Analysis,  111  Univ.  Pa.  L.R.  925-48  (1979). 

48.  Institutional  arrangements  to  be  discussed  herein  include  free  markets,  regulatory 
control,  binding  arbitration  and  vertical  integration. 

49.  Williamson,  Transaction-Cost  Economics:  The  Governance  of  Contractual  Re- 
lations, 22  J.  Law  Econ.  Organ.  233  (1979);  Goldberg,  Regulation  and  Administered 
Contract,  7  Bell  J.  Econ.  426  (1976);  Klein,  Transaction  Cost  Determinants  of  "Unfair" 
Contractual  Relations,  70  Am.  Econ,  Rev.  356  (1980);  Joskow,  Vertical  Integration  and 
Long-Term  Contracts,  1  J.  Law  Econ.  &  Organ.  33  (1985). 

50.  Coase,  The  Nature  of  the  Firm,  4  Economica  386  (1937). 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1091 

efficiently  govern  that  transaction.^^  He  further  recognized  that  the  total 
costs  of  a  transaction  include  not  only  the  cost  of  the  goods  or  service 
to  be  exchanged,  but  also  certain  transaction  costs  associated  with  es- 
tablishing and  administering  a  business  relationship." 

The  transaction  costs  applicable  to  contracts  in  general,  and  to  utility 
construction  contracts  in  particular,  include  the  costs  of  negotiating 
contractual  terms,  the  costs  of  monitoring  contractual  performance,  the 
costs  of  enforcing  contractual  provisions  and  the  costs  of  breach  of  the 
agreement. ^^  All  of  these  costs  are  real  economic  costs  which  must  be 
taken  into  account  along  with  the  traditional  costs  of  production  in 
determining  the  cost-minimizing  structure  of  any  legal/economic  rela- 
tionship.^'* Before  evaluating  transaction  costs,  however,  we  must  un- 
derstand not  only  their  general  nature,  but  also  the  specific  characteristics 
which  allow  them  to  be  used  in  a  predictive  way.^^ 

Williamson  in  particular  has  focused  on  identifying  the  critical  di- 
mensions of  transaction  costs  which  indicate  how  and  why  transactions 
can  be  matched  with  governance  structures  in  an  efficient  manner. ^^  To 
date,  he  has  identified  three  characteristics  of  transactions  that  affect 
the  nature  and  magnitude  of  transaction  costs,  and  thus  the  efficient 
governance  structure."  Those  characteristics  are:  (1)  The  complexity  and 
uncertainty  of  the  contemplated  transaction;  (2)  The  frequency  with 
which  the  transaction  is  likely  to  recur;  and  (3)  The  extent  to  which 
one  party  must  make  transaction-specific  (idiosyncratic)  investment  of 
time,  money  and  labor. ^*  These  characteristics  have  subsequently  been 
used  by  other  authors  in  their  applications  of  transaction  cost  theory. ^^ 

The  complexity  of  the  transaction  is  important  because  it  increases 
the  costs  of  bargaining,  monitoring  and  enforcing  the  contract. ^^  Com- 
plexity increases  transaction  costs  directly  by  increasing  the  number  of 
terms  which  must  be  negotiated,  monitored  and  enforced.^*  Complexity 
may  also  increase  transaction  costs  indirectly  by  making  information 


51.  Id. 

52.  Id. 

53.  Joskow,  supra  note  49,  at  36. 

54.  Id.  at  35. 

55.  Specific  transaction  characteristics  are  described  in  Williamson,  supra  note  49. 

56.  Id. 

57.  Id. 

58.  Id.  at  239. 

59.  See,  e.g.,  P.  Joskow  &  R.  Schmalensee,  supra  note  10;  Joskow,  supra  note 
49,  and  Klein,  supra  note  49. 

60.  Williamson,  supra  note  14. 

61.  Complex  transactions  are  defined  here  to  include  transactions  which  have  a 
large  number  of  terms,  typically  involving  technical  or  specialized  knowledge. 


1092  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

more  costly  and/or  less  reliable. ^^  Finally,  complexity  generally  increases 
uncertainty  due  to  the  constraints  of  imperfect  information  and  increased 
transaction  terms." 

The  uncertainty  of  the  transaction  is  also  an  important  determinant 
of  transaction  costs. ^"^  When  the  future  course  of  performance  is  un- 
certain, contractual  gaps  are  apt  to  be  larger  and  occasions  for  adaptation 
will  increase  in  number  and  importance. ^^  A  more  elaborate  and  costly 
governance  structure  is  typically  required,  including  provisions  for  ar- 
bitration when  unanticipated  contingencies  arise. ^^  Uncertainty  also  lowers 
the  economic  '^utility"  of  any  outcome  for  risk-adverse  parties  since  all 
outcomes  must  be  discounted  by  the  Ukelihood  of  success. ^^ 

Another  factor  that  has  been  shown  to  impact  transaction  costs  is 
the  frequency  of  the  transaction.^^  When  a  transaction  is  frequently 
repeated,  standard  terms  and  conditions  may  become  defined  by  past 
performance,  reducing  the  costs  of  negotiating  those  terms  independently 
for  each  transaction.^^  The  frequency  may  also  impact  transaction  costs 
by  affecting  the  uncertainty  of  the  transaction.^^  Transactions  which  are 
frequently  repeated  are  apt  to  have  a  more  certain  set  of  potential 
outcomes  since  information  is  available  concerning  the  outcomes  of  past 
transactions  executed  under  similar  circumstances.'^  Frequency  of  trans- 
actions may  also  impact  transaction  costs  by  affecting  the  behavior  of 
the  parties. ^^  Parties  who  must  deal  frequently  with  each  other  are  less 
apt  to  engage  in  opportunistic  behavior  that  may  adversely  affect  future 
transactions.^^  Personal  ethical  standards  may  also  be  higher  when  the 
same  individuals  must  frequently  interact,  and  those  personal  standards 
may  replace  the  more  opportunistic  corporate  ethic  which  operates  when 
personal  relationships  have  not  developed  between  the  contracting  parties.'''^ 


62.  The  relationship  between  information  and  transaction  costs  is  described  in 
Heckathorn  &  Masur,  Bargaining  and  the  Sources  of  Transaction  Costs:  The  Case  of 
Government  Regulation,  3  J.  Law,  Econ.  &  Organ,  69  (1981). 

63.  Id. 

64.  Wilhamson,  supra  note  49,  at  254. 

65.  Id.  at  253-54. 

66.  Williamson,  supra  note  49,  at  246-54. 

67.  Discussions  of  the  effect  of  uncertainty  on  utility  maximization  can  be  found 
in  many  advanced  texts  in  economics.  See,  e.g.,  E.  Malinvaud,  Lectures  on  Microe- 
coNOMic  Theory  (1972). 

68.  Williamson,  supra  note  49,  at  248-54. 

69.  Heckathorn  &  Masur,  supra  note  62. 

70.  Id. 

71.  Id. 

11.     Williamson,  supra  note  14. 

73.  Id. 

74.  Id. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1093 

The  idiosyncrasy  of  the  investment  impacts  transaction  costs  by 
allowing  one  party  to  behave  in  an  opportunistic  manner. ^^  Idiosyncratic 
goods  are  goods  in  which  transaction-specific  investments  in  either  human 
or  physical  capital  have  been  made.^^  Transaction-specific  investments 
are  those  investments  which  are  of  value  primarily  to  the  intended 
purchaser  under  the  contract. ^^  These  investments  pose  nonmarketability 
problems  because  the  investor  cannot  readily  recover  costs  by  selling  the 
investment  to  alternative  buyers. ^^  When  idiosyncratic  investments  must 
be  made,  the  relationship  between  buyer  and  seller  is  quickly  transformed 
into  one  of  bilateral  monopoly,  and  transaction  costs  increase  in  direct 
proportion  to  the  ability  of  one  party  to  exploit  that  monopoly  power. ^^ 
Opportunistic  behavior  is  behavior  that  involves  the  appropriation  of 
wealth  from  one  party  to  the  other  due  to  an  unanticipated  changes  in 
circumstances.^^  As  a  general  rule,  opportunistic  behavior  does  not  max- 
imize joint  profits.**  The  potential  for  opportunistic  behavior  has  been 
cited  as  a  primary  source  of  transaction  costs  due  to  its  impact  on 
transaction  risk.*^  The  recognition  of  idiosyncratic  investment  and  its 
impact  on  opportunistic  behavior  is  a  distinguishing  feature  of  transaction 
cost  analysis. 

V.     Transaction  Cost  Analysis  of  the  Traditional  Structure 

Transaction  cost  analysis  is  especially  useful  in  evaluating  transactions 
which  involve  high  degrees  of  uncertainty  and  idiosyncrasy,  and  which 
occur  only  infrequently  for  any  two  contracting  parties  because  it  places 
greater  emphasis  on  the  behavioral  characteristics  of  the  parties.  The 
transaction  for  the  construction  and  cost-recovery  of  an  electric  generating 
unit  is  subject  to  a  great  degree  of  uncertainty  due  to  the  long  time 
required  to  complete  construction  and  recover  costs. *^  The  transaction 
is  also  highly  complex  due  to  the  technical  nature  of  the  exchange  and 
the  long  time  period  required  to  complete  the  project.*"*  Due  to  the 
economies  of  scale  in  the  construction  and  operation  of  generating  units, 


75.  Williamson,  supra  note  49,  at  238-42, 

76.  Id.  at  241. 

77.  Id.  at  239-40. 

78.  Id.  at  238-42. 

79.  Id.  at  241.  A  bilateral  monopoly  occurs  when  both  the  buyer  and  the  seller 
face  a  monopoly  market;  i.e.,  when  there  is  only  one  buyer  and  one  seller. 

80.  Joskow,  supra  note  49,  at  37. 

81.  Id. 

82.  See  Pierce,  supra  note  43,  at  1199-1202. 

83.  Construction  times  range  from  five  to  ten  years  for  most  generating  units.  See 
supra  note  35  and  accompanying  text. 

84.  Pierce,  supra  note  43. 


1094  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

construction  transactions  also  take  place  infrequently  for  any  one  utility. ^^ 
On  average,  a  new  unit  is  added  every  seven  to  ten  years  in  most  service 
territories.^^  Finally,  the  investment  in  electric  generating  plants  may  be 
highly  idiosyncratic  if  the  power  cannot  be  sold  to  an  alternative  buyer 
once  construction  is  complete. ^^ 

The  institutional  structure  traditionally  governing  utility-consumer 
transactions  is  a  command-and-control  regulatory  structure. ^^  That  struc- 
ture imposes  terms  and  conditions  on  the  parties  to  the  construction 
transaction  by  application  of  law.^^  With  respect  to  the  contract  in 
question,  statutes  typically  provide  for  rates  which  are  "fair  and  rea- 
sonable."^ Recovery  of  the  costs  of  a  generating  unit  are  allowed  if, 
and  only  if,  the  generating  unit  becomes  "used  and  useful."^'  The  used 
and  useful  standard  evaluates  the  "price"  term  after  the  investment 
decision  has  been  made.^^ 

The  traditional  institutional  structure  allows  for  an  ex  post  revision 
of  the  value  of  the  generating  plant  since  the  used  and  useful  deter- 
mination cannot  be  made  prior  to  project  completion. ^^  Because  the 
investment  is  highly  idiosyncratic,  this  presents  an  ideal  environment  for 
opportunistic  behavior  on  the  part  of  consumers  acting  through  the  state 
regulatory  agency.^"*  Thus,  the  ex  ante  expectations  of  the  parties  are 
frustrated  and  the  seller  is  placed  in  the  position  of  being  forced  to 
accept  terms  which  have  not  been  bargained  for.^^  Ultimately,  the  op- 
portunistic behavior  increases  transaction  costs  and,  therefore,  the  costs 
of  future  transactions.^^ 

As  was  noted  earher,  one  example  of  ex  post  revision  of  the  parties' 
ex  ante  expectations  can  be  found  in  the  case  of  Northern  Indiana  Public 


85.  Due  to  significant  differences  in  demand  growth  across  local  jurisdictions,  there 
is  a  wide  variation  in  capacity  plans  for  local  generating  companies.  The  economies  of 
scale  indicate  that  the  optimal  size  for  new  generating  capacity  is  approximately  1200 
megawatts,  so  if  demand  grows  at  200  megawatts  per  year,  a  six  year  interval  between 
transactions  would  be  implied. 

86.  Recent  and  forecast  additions  to  generating  capacity  indicate  that  an  average 
electric  utility  might  be  expected  to  add  new  generating  capacity  once  every  5  to  7  years. 
See  Northeast  Area  Reliability  Council  Report  on  Electric  Power  Capacity  (1986). 

87.  See  supra  notes  44-46  and  accompanying  text. 

88.  Pierce,  supra  note  43,  at  1191-97. 

89.  Id. 

90.  See,  e.g.,  Ind.  Code  §  8-1-2-4  (1988). 

91.  See,  e.g..  Citizens  Action  Coalition  v.  Northern  Indiana  Pubhc  Service  Co., 
485  N.E.2d  610  (Ind.  1985),  aff'g  All  N.E.2d  938  (Ind.  Ct.  App.   1984). 

92.  Pierce,  supra  note  43,  at  1199-1202. 

93.  Id. 

94.  Id. 

95.  Id. 

96.  Id. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1095 

Service  Company  (NIPSCO).^^  In  that  case,  NIPSCO  determined  that 
the  future  electricity  needs  of  its  service  territory  would  require  the 
addition  of  significant  new  generating  capacity.  After  construction  was 
begun,  the  economic  climate  of  the  service  territory  changed  and  the 
capacity  additions  were  no  longer  necessary.^^  In  Citizens  Action  Coalition 
of  Indiana  v.  Northern  Indiana  Pub.  Serv.  Co.,^^  the  Indiana  court 
refused  to  allow  recovery  of  construction  costs,  regardless  of  their  pru- 
dency,  based  on  the  statutory  requirement  that  utility  property  must  be 
used  and  useful  before  recovery  is  warranted. ^^  That  disallowance  was 
later  cited  as  a  significant  factor  which  had  increased  NIPSCO 's  cost 
of  capital  when  construction  was  subsequently  begun  on  additional  NIP- 
SCO capacity. 'o» 

VI.     Alternative  Institutional  Arrangements 

If  the  traditional  institutional  structure  does  not  efficiently  govern 
the  utility  construction  transaction,  it  is  important  to  determine  what 
institutional  structure  would  accomplish  that  goal.  A  variety  of  regulatory 
reforms  have  been  proposed  in  response  to  this  problem,  although  no 
alternative  structure  has  been  proposed  as  a  transaction  cost  minimizing 
solution  per  se.^^^  Many  of  those  proposals  have,  however,  explicitly 
recognized  their  economic  consequences,  normally  characterizing  them- 
selves as  efforts  to  either  maximize  "economic  efficiency"  or  minimize 
* 'economic  costs. '*'°^ 

This  discussion  addresses  two  general  types  of  reforms-  "deregu- 
lation" alternatives,  and  preapproved  contract  approaches.  The  dereg- 
ulation reforms  at  issue  here  are  those  proposals  which  incorporate 
competitive  bidding  structures  as  alternatives  to  state  and  federal  reg- 


97.  See  supra  notes  33-35  and  accompanying  text. 

98.  Testimony  of  J.  Neiting,  representing  Petitioner  NIPSCO  before  the  Public 
Service  Commission  of  Indiana,  Cause  No.  37023. 

99.  485  N.E.2d  610  (Ind.  1985),  affg  All  N.E.2d  938  (Ind.  Ct.  App.  1984). 

100.  Citizens  Action  Coalition  of  Indiana  v.  Northern  Indiana  PubHc  Service  Co., 
485  N.E.2d  610  (Ind.   1985),  aff'd.  All  N.E.2d  938  (Ind.  Ct.  App.   1984). 

101.  Testimony  of  J.  Langum  in  NIPSCO  case  before  the  Indiana  Utility  Regulatory 
Commission,  Cause  No.  38045. 

102.  Transaction  cost  analysis  has  been  applied  to  utility  regulatory  problems  in  P. 
JosKOw  &  R.  ScHMALENSEE,  supra  note  10,  and  Pierce,  supra  note  43. 

103.  See,  e.g.,  S.  Breyer,  Regulation  and  Its  Reform  (1982);  Essay,  Efficiency 
and  Competition  in  the  Electric-Power  Industry,  88  Yale  L.J.  1511  (1979);  Fairman, 
Transmission,  Power  Pools,  and  Competition  in  the  Electric  Utility  Industry,  28  Hastings 
L.J.  1159  (1977);  Miller,  A  Needed  Reform  of  the  Organization  and  Regulation  of  the 
Interstate  Electric  Power  Industry,  38  Fordham  L.R.  635  (1970);  and  the  articles  cited 
in  notes  10  and  42. 


1096  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

ulation.^^'*  The  preapproved  contract  reforms  take  an  alternative  approach, 
requiring  an  increase  in  the  amount  of  regulatory  oversight. *^^  Because 
the  competitive  bidding  proposals  rely  on  market-based  governance,  while 
the  preapproved  contract  proposals  rely  on  a  regulatory  structure  to 
govern  the  contractual  relationship,  consideration  of  these  two  proposal 
types  will  provide  a  good  comparison  of  institutional  arrangements  which 
are  reasonably  "opposite"  in  structure. 

A.     Competitive  Bidding  Proposals 

Competitive  bidding  proposals  typically  involve  the  separation  of 
ownership  of  generation  and  distribution  facilities,  the  assurance  of  equal 
access  to  transmission  facilities,  and  the  deregulation  of  wholesale  (bulk) 
power  prices. *^^  After  bulk  power  prices  are  deregulated,  the  institutional 
structure  governing  transactions  would  be  the  competitive  market  rather 
than  the  regulatory  governance  structure  which  has  traditionally  con- 
trolled. ^^^  Because  the  deregulation  of  bulk  power  prices  is  the  central 
focus  of  competitive  bidding  proposals,  those  proposals  are  also  com- 
monly referred  to  as  "deregulation"  proposals. ^^^  Although  there  are  a 
variety  of  specific  competitive  bidding  proposals,  each  of  which  is  unique 
in  one  or  more  aspects,  it  is  practical  to  consider  them  collectively  as 
a  proposal  type  which  incorporates  the  essential  characteristics  described 
below. 

The  first  characteristic  of  a  competitive  bidding  proposal  is  the 
separation  of  ownership  of  generation  and  distribution  facilities. ^^^  The 
traditional  institutional  structure  reflects  the  transaction  cost  economies 
of  vertical  integration  through  the  common  ownership  of  generation  and 
distribution  facilities.  One  result  of  this  diversified  corporate  structure 
is  an  economic  incentive  for  the  local  distribution  grid  to  utilize  affihated 
generating  capacity  regardless  of  whether  there  is  an  alternative,  lower 
cost  provider.''^  Competitive  bidding  alternatives,  on  the  other  hand, 
typically  require  that  generating  and  distribution  facilities  be  owned  by 


104.  Competitive  bidding  is  accomplished  in  a  free-market  structure,  as  opposed  to 
the  traditional  command-and-control  regulatory  structure. 

105.  See,  e.g..  Re  Pricing  and  Rate-making  Treatment  for  New  Electric  Generating 
Facilities  Which  Are  Note  Qualifying  Facilities,  93  PUR  4th  313  (Mass.  Dept.  Pub.  Util. 
1988). 

106.  One  comprehensive  example  of  a  competitive  bidding  proposal  is  found  in 
Pierce,  supra  note  43.  See  also  Plummer,  supra  note  10;  Meyer,  supra  note  10;  and  the 
articles  hsted  in  note  101. 

107.  See,  e.g..  Pierce,  supra  note  43. 

108.  P.    JOSKOW  &   R.    SCHMALENSEE,   SUprO   UOtC    10. 

109.  See,  e.g..  Pierce,  supra  note  43,  at  1211. 

110.  P.    JoSKOW   AND    R.    SCHMALENSEE,   SUpra  UOtC    10. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1097 

separate  entities,  thus  eliminating  any  financial  incentive  for  the  distri- 
bution portion  of  the  company  to  favor  any  particular  generator.^'' 
Competitive  bidding  will  lead  to  efficient  market  transactions  only  when 
there  is  no  unity  of  interest  between  the  buyer  and  the  seller;  otherwise 
there  is  an  incentive  for  the  purchaser  to  contract  only  with  the  related 
supplier.''^  When  the  local  distributor  has  no  financial  interest  in  the 
success  of  particular  generating  facilities,  the  distributor  will  have  no 
incentive  to  purchase  from  an  inefficient  supplier  and  will  seek  a  com- 
petitive market-based  transaction  instead. ^'^ 

Equal  access  to  transmission  facilities  is  the  second  characteristic  of 
a  successful  competitive  bidding  program. ^^"^  Equal  access  to  transmission 
facilities  involves  assuring  that  any  buyer  and  any  seller  of  electricity 
may  transport  power  over  the  transmission  grid  at  a  non-discriminatory 
price. *^^  Because  transmission  facilities  are  required  by  the  transaction 
as  a  physical  means  of  exchange,  equal  access  to  transmission  facilities 
is  required  by  a  competitive  market  so  that  buyers  and  sellers  may  be 
efficiently  matched. ^'^  If  equal  access  is  not  assured,  purchasers  (distri- 
bution companies)  may  face  a  monopoly  market.  Regardless  of  the 
number  of  potential  suppliers,  the  generation  market  realistically  includes 
only  those  suppliers  who  could  actually  deliver  power. 

Deregulation  of  bulk  power  sales  is  the  final  component  of  com- 
petitive bidding  proposals.''^  The  deregulation  of  bulk  power  sales  is 
appropriate  when  a  competitive  market  for  those  sales  exists,  because  the 
competitive  market,  rather  than  the  regulatory  system,  will  provide  the 
necessary  governance  structure. ^'^  If  open  access  to  transmission  facilities 
is  assured  for  both  suppliers  and  end-users,  a  free  market  may  be 
maintained  and  prices  for  generating  capacity  are  determined  on  the 
basis  of  competitive  bidding. '^^  Competitive  prices  are  driven  toward  cost 
and  inefficient  suppliers  are  driven  from  the  market. ^^° 

Competitive  bidding  proposals  would  not  affect  the  complexity  or 
uncertainty  of  the  transaction  to  build  and  pay  for  generating  facilities. 


111.  Pierce,  supra  note  10. 

112.  Id. 

113.  Id. 

114.  See,  e.g..  Pierce,  supra  note  43,  at  1215-18. 

115.  Id. 

116.  Id. 

117.  See,  e.g..  Pierce,  supra  note  42,  at  1218-21. 

118.  Id. 

1 19.  Id. 

120.  Inefficient  suppliers  are  those  suppliers  who  are  unable  to  provide  service  at 
competitive  market  prices.  See,  e.g.,  M.  Crew  &  P.  Kleindorfer,  Public  Utelity  Ec- 
onomics (1979);  R.  MiLLWARD,  Public  Sector  Economics  (1983);  F.  Scherer,  Industrial 
Market  Structure  and  Economic  Performance  (1980). 


1098  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

Construction  times  would  not  be  shortened,  nor  would  costs  be  more 
accurately  estimated  or  controlled. •^^  Estimating  future  demand  would 
not  be  any  more  precise. '^^ 

The  frequency  of  transactions  would  also  not  be  affected  by  com- 
petitive bidding  alternatives.  The  frequency  of  construction  transactions 
is  a  function  of  the  size  of  the  generating  units  which  are  constructed, 
while  the  size  of  the  units  is  a  function  of  non-institutional  factors  such 
as  the  rate  of  anticipated  demand  growth  and  the  construction  and 
operating  costs  of  the  units. ^^^  There  is  no  reason  to  believe  that  the 
frequency  of  electric  generating  plant  construction  would  be  affected  by 
a  competitive  bidding  governance  structure. 

The  most  important  implication  of  competitive  bidding  proposals  is 
their  impact  on  the  idiosyncrasy  of  the  generating  plants.  Under  the 
existing  regulatory  scheme  each  electric  plant  is  * 'marketed*'  primarily 
to  one  distribution  company. '^"^  Under  competitive  bidding  proposals, 
each  generating  unit  could  be  marketed  to  any  distributor. ^^^  The  con- 
ditions of  bilateral  monopoly  would  never  arise  and  the  potential  for 
opportunistic  behavior  would  be  correspondingly  reduced. ^^^  The  elim- 
ination of  opportunistic  behavior  would  lower  the  costs  of  the  transaction 
because  investors  will  not  bear  the  risk  of  having  their  investment 
appropriated  by  consumers. '^^  The  risk  of  opportunistic  behavior  has 
been  cited  as  a  primary  source  of  transaction  cost,  so  any  governance 
structure  which  reduced  that  risk  could  more  efficiently  govern  the 
transaction. '2^ 

Negotiation  costs  would,  however,  be  significantly  increased  under 
a  competitive  bidding  approach.  The  present  regulatory  structure  requires 
only  minimal  negotiation  and  bargaining  costs  because  the  terms  of  the 


121.  Dowd  &  Burton,  supra  note  10. 

122.  Id. 

123.  For  a  discussion  of  the  determinants  of  optimal  generating  unit  size,  see  Edison 
Power  Research  Institute,  Moving  Toward  Integrated  Value-Based  Planning  (1988) 
(hereinafter  EPRI). 

124.  The  output  from  any  generating  station  is  used  primarily  to  serve  the  generating 
company's  own  service  territory.  Sales  are  made  to  other  territories,  however,  on  both  a 
short-term  (economy  power)  and  long-term  (unit  power)  basis.  The  regulatory  scheme  does 
not  specifically  preclude  extensive  inter-jurisdictional,  unit  power  sales;  however,  those 
sales  remain  the  exception  rather  than  the  rule. 

125.  The  output  from  each  unit  could  be  marketed  on  either  a  short-term  or  a 
long-term  basis. 

126.  Pierce,  supra  note  43.  Bilateral  monopoly  was  defined  in  note  79. 

127.  Id. 

128.  See,  e.g..  Pierce,  supra  note  43;  Williamson,  supra  note  48;  and  Joskow,  supra 
note  49. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1099 

transaction  are  largely  defined  by  law.'^^  Market  transactions  of  this 
complexity  would  require  extensive  bargaining  and  contracting  proce- 
dures— procedures  which  would  raise  transaction  costs. '^^  Monitoring  and 
enforcement  costs  would  be  decreased,  though,  as  market  governance 
replaced  much  of  the  existing  regulatory  structure.'^' 

The  net  impact  of  the  competitive  bidding  proposals  would  be  a 
more  efficiently  governed  utility  construction  transaction  if  a  competitive 
market  can  truly  be  established.  Unfortunately,  the  engineering  constraints 
on  wheeling  power  long  distances,  as  well  as  the  institutional  constraints 
of  disintegrating  the  generation  and  distribution  functions,  may  be  too 
great  to  allow  a  market  to  form  and  survive. ^^^  If  those  difficulties  can 
be  overcome,  the  elimination  of  opportunistic  behavior  would  reduce 
transaction  costs  making  the  governance  of  the  transaction  more  efficient. 

B.     Preapproved  Contract  Approaches 

As  an  alternative  to  competitive  bidding  proposals,  some  states  have 
adopted  a  preapproved  contract  approach  to  governing  the  utility  con- 
struction transaction. ^^3  Preapproved  contract  approaches  typically  require 
pre-construction  (ex  ante)  approval  of  all  construction  plans,  followed 
by  a  continuing  re-evaluation  of  the  need  and  cost  of  those  capacity 
additions. '^"^  If  the  need  or  cost  of  construction  changes,  the  approval 
for  construction  may  be  terminated  at  any  time.^^^  All  costs  incurred 
prior  to  the  termination  of  regulatory  approval  are  recoverable — re- 
gardless of  whether  the  plant  is  ultimately  completed. ^^^ 

One  benefit  of  this  alternative  is  that  it  requires  minimal  change  in 
the  current  structure  of  the  industry  and  in  the  regulatory  framework. 
Generating  divisions  would  not  have  to  be  separated  from  the  transmission 
and  distribution   functions — thus  economies   of  scale   could  be   main- 


129.  The  negotiation  and  bargaining  costs  are  already  "sunk"  costs,  having  been 
expended  as  the  statutes  were  written  and  the  judicial  cases  were  litigated.  Little  if  any 
negotiation  is  now  performed,  due  to  the  existence  of  legal  requirements  which  may  not 
be  bargained  away. 

130.  Dowd  &  Burton,  supra  note  10. 

131.  See,  e.g..  Pierce,  supra  note  43;  Miller,  supra  note  100;  and  Weiss,  Antitrust 
in  the  Electric  Power  Industry,  in  Phillips  &  Almarin,  Promoting  Competition  in 
Regulated  Markets  (1975). 

132.  See  supra  notes  45-46  and  accompanying  text. 

133.  States  which  have  adopted  some  form  of  preapproved  contract  approach  include 
California,  Connecticut,  Maine,  Indiana,  Massachusetts  and  Wisconsin, 

134.  See,  e.g.,  Ind.  Code  §  8-1-8.5-1  et  seq.  (1988). 

135.  See,  e.g.,  Ind.  Code  §  8-1-8.5-6  (1988). 

136.  Id. 


1100  ^_^         INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

tained.^^^  Many,  if  not  most,  states  currently  have  deemed  forecasting 
components  which  are  increasingly  able  to  adequately  review  construction 
proposals.  ^^^ 

The  frequency  and  uncertainty  of  the  transaction  would  not  be 
affected  significantly  by  the  preapproved  contract  approach.  Non-insti- 
tutional factors  would  continue  to  define  optimal  unit  size  and  the 
uncertainties  of  cost  and  demand  would  not  be  affected. ^^^  The  complexity 
of  the  transaction  would  be  increased,  however,  as  the  parties  are  forced 
to  evaluate  and  re-evaluate  the  prudency  of  the  construction. ^'^'^ 

Negotiation,  monitoring  and  enforcement  costs  are  high  under  a 
preapproved  contract  structure.  The  regulatory  agency  would  acquire 
responsibility  to  approve  the  construction  expenditures  prior  to  construc- 
tion, thereby  increasing  the  costs  of  negotiation. '"^^  The  regulatory  agency 
would  also  be  required  to  re-evaluate  the  construction  program  on  an 
ongoing  basis,  increasing  the  costs  of  monitoring  the  transaction. ^"^^ 
Although  the  regulatory  structure  required  to  perform  these  negotiation 
and  monitoring  functions  is  currently  in  place  in  many  jurisdictions,  the 
increase  in  workload  that  would  accompany  implementation  of  a  preap- 
proved contract  alternative  would  most  certainly  increase  negotiation  and 
monitoring  costs  as  construction  programs  are  begun. '"^^ 

The  primary  benefit  of  the  preapproved  contract  approach  is  its 
powerful  limit  on  opportunistic  behavior.  A  preapproved  contract  creates 
a  legal  obligation  on  the  part  of  the  regulatory  commission  to  allow 


137.  Economies  of  scale  are  economic  savings  which  are  reaUzed  solely  due  to  the 
size  of  the  transaction.  For  example,  many  goods  can  be  purchased  at  a  lower  price  when 
many  units  are  bought  at  once.  Some  economies  of  scale  in  management,  purchasing, 
etc.,  would  be  present  regardless  of  whether  generation  and  distribution  are  separated  or 
not.  The  magnitude  of  those  economies,  of  course,  would  be  greatest  with  a  larger, 
integrated  corporate  structure. 

138.  States  with  some  demand  forecasting  ability  include  California,  Connecticut, 
Delaware,  Florida,  Indiana,  Iowa,  Maine,  Maryland,  Michigan,  Nevada,  New  York,  Ohio, 
Oklahoma,  Pennsylvania,  Texas,  Virginia,  Washington  and  Wisconsin.  Berry,  Least-Cost 
Planning  and  Utility  Regulation,  Pub.  Util.  Fort.  March  17,  1988  at  9. 

139.  See  EPRI,  supra  note  123. 

140.  The  preapproved  contract  approach  includes  a  continual  re-evaluation  of  con- 
struction needs  and  costs.  See,  e.g.,  Ind.  Code  §  8-1-8.5-1  to  8-1-8.5-7  (1988);  and  Re 
Pricing  and  Rate-making  Treatment  for  New  Electric  Generating  Facilities  Which  Are  Not 
Qualifying  Facilities,  93  PUR  4th  313  (Mass.  Dept.  Pub.  Util.  1988). 

141.  Id. 

142.  Id. 

143.  Although  several  states  have  initiated  preapproved  contract  provisions,  or  have 
created  demand  forecasting  components  within  their  utility  regulatory  agencies,  no  state 
has  yet  constructed  a  generating  unit  following  that  approach.  The  regulatory  effort 
necessary  to  evaluate  and  monitor  construction  programs  is  significant  indeed,  and  because 
the  utihties  must  duplicate  those  efforts,  the  total  negotiation  and  monitoring  costs  of 
the  transaction  would  doubtless  increase  when  compared  to  historical  levels. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1101 

full  recovery  of  all  approved  costs;  there  can  be  no  ex  post  re-evaluation 
of  the  contract  price. '"^  Although  the  idiosyncrasy  of  the  asset  would 
remain  high  under  this  alternative,  the  statutory  controls  over  the  recovery 
of  costs  provide  the  necessary  balance  to  avoid  opportunistic  behavior. '"^^ 
Total  transaction  costs  should  be  reduced  from  present  levels  under 
a  preapproved  contract  approach. ^"^^  Although  the  costs  of  negotiating 
and  monitoring  are  high,  reducing  the  potential  for  opportunistic  behavior 
would  more  than  compensate  for  that  increase. ^'^^  The  preclusion  of 
opportunistic  behavior  allows  investment  decisions  to  be  based  on  ec- 
onomic value,  and  significantly  reduces  unnecessary  transaction  costs. '"^^ 

VII.     Development  of  Alternative  Governance  Structures 

An  understanding  of  transaction  costs  makes  it  possible  not  only  to 
evaluate  existing  proposals,  but  also  to  devise  additional  institutional 
alternatives  that  might  more  efficiently  govern  the  construction  trans- 
action.^"*^ This  section  will  suggest  two  alternative  governance  structures 
and  will  discuss  how  those  structures  could  lead  to  a  more  efficient 
utility  construction  transaction. 

A.     Binding  Arbitration 

In  'Transaction-Cost  Economics:  The  Governance  of  Contractual 
Relations,"  Oliver  Williamson  suggests  efficient  governance  structures 
for  a  variety  of  transaction  types. '^°  Among  those  transaction  types  are 
"occasional"  transactions  which  involve  a  high  degree  of  uncertainty 
and  idiosyncratic  investment. ^^'  The  governance  structure  identified  by 
Williamson  as  most  efficient  for  that  transaction  type  is  a  ''trilateral" 
governance  structure  whereby  third  party  assistance  (arbitration)  is  em- 


144.  See,  e.g.,  Ind.  Code  §  8-1-8.5-6  (1988);  and  Re  Pricing  and  Rate-making 
Treatment  for  New  Electric  Generating  Facilities  Which  Are  Not  Qualifying  Facilities,  98 
PUR  4th  313  (Mass.  Dept.  Pub.  Util.  1988). 

145.  Opportunistic  behavior  cannot  occur  when  ex  post  revision  is  precluded  by 
statute, 

146.  Recall  that  total  transaction  costs  include  the  costs  of  production,  plus  the 
costs  of  negotiation,  monitoring  and  enforcement. 

147.  There  is  no  empirical  data  supporting  this  conclusion.  The  conclusion  is  based 
on  the  opinions  of  the  commentators  in  Re  Pricing  and  Rate-making  Treatment  for  New 
Electric  Generating  Facilities  Which  Are  Not  Qualifying  Facilities,  93  PUR  4th  313  (Mass. 
Dept.  Pub.  Util.  1988). 

148.  Pierce,  supra  note  43. 

149.  Efficient  transaction  governance  is  that  governance  which  minimizes  total  trans- 
action costs. 

150.  Williamson,  supra  note  49. 

151.  Id.  at  249. 


1102  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

ployed  to  evaluate  performance  and  resolve  disputes. '^^  One  gov- 
ernance structure  consistent  with  Prof.  Williamson's  suggestion  could  be 
achieved  by  providing  for  federal  arbitration  of  state  decisions  concerning 
whether  construction  costs  should  be  fully  recovered. '^^  For  example, 
the  Federal  Energy  Regulatory  Commission  could  be  given  binding  ar- 
bitration power  over  any  state  disallowances  of  construction  costs,  and, 
in  addition,  the  freedom  to  apply  federal  prudency  rules  to  that  arbi- 
tration. The  freedom  to  apply  federal  prudency  rules  is  an  important 
component  of  this  proposal  since  the  success  of  arbitration  depends 
largely  on  the  ability  to  allocate  costs  fairly. '^"^  An  alternative  that 
provided  for  federal  arbitration  yet  required  the  arbitrator  to  use  state 
*'used  and  useful"  rules  would  deprive  the  arbitrator  of  the  flexibility 
necessary  to  achieve  an  efficient  allocation. 

Federal  arbitration  should  have  the  effect  of  reducing  opportunistic 
behavior.  Although  the  federal  commission  is  also  theoretically  subject 
to  opportunistic  pressures,  the  fact  is  that  the  FERC  has  never  disallowed 
any  utility  investment  as  being  imprudent  or  excessive. ^^^  The  potential 
for  federal  disallowance  of  imprudent  construction  expense  would  pre- 
clude the  utilities  from  constructing  unnecessary  plants  except  when  the 
reasonable  expectations  of  the  parties  are  that  the  capacity  will  be 
required. '^^  On  the  other  hand,  federal  arbitration  would  preclude  the 
states  from  appropriating  the  utility  investment  by  eliminating  ex  post 
review  of  the  transaction  based  on  results  which  could  not  have  been 
reasonably  anticipated.^"  This  elimination  of  opportunistic  behavior  re- 
duces transaction  costs  by  allowing  the  investment  to  be  valued  eco- 
nomically in  a  predictable  manner. '^^ 

Negotiation  and  monitoring  costs  would  be  unaffected  by  binding 
arbitration  alternatives  since  the  existing  regulatory  framework  would 
continue  to  operate  unless  disagreement  as  to  cost  recovery  is  encoun- 


152.  Id.  at  249-50. 

153.  Federal  arbitration  of  state  decision-making  is  an  example  of  the  trilateral 
governance  structures  described  by  Williamson. 

154.  Arbitration  without  flexibility  is  no  more  than  administrative  review  of  the 
application  of  set  rules  and  procedures.  Flexibility  is  typically  necessary  to  find  efficient 
solutions  which  are  distinct  from  the  proposals  of  the  parties. 

155.  Teisberg,  supra  note  38. 

156.  No  profit-maximizing  firm  will  knowingly  construct  imprudent  generating  fa- 
cilities if  a  procedure  exists  for  regulatory  disallowance  of  those  imprudent  costs.  If  there 
is  a  good  faith  expectation  that  the  facilities  will  be  needed,  generating  plants  that  are 
eventually  unnecessary  may  be  constructed. 

157.  The  appropriation  of  utility  investment  occurs  by  the  ex  post  revision  of  the 
mutual  expectations  of  the  parties.  See,  e.g..  Pierce,  supra  note  43. 

158.  Id. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1103 

tered.'^^  The  cost  of  enforcement  would,  however,  be  increased  due  to 
the  inevitable  cost  of  the  arbitration  structure J^°  This  increase  in  en- 
forcement costs  would  be  minimal  when  compared  with  the  reduction 
in  transaction  costs  which  accompanies  the  reduction  in  opportunistic 
behavior.  ^^^ 

A  consideration  of  transaction  costs  implies  that  an  institutional 
structure  incorporating  binding  arbitration  would  more  efficiently  govern 
the  utility  construction  transaction. '^^  Although  enforcement  costs  would 
increase,  the  potential  for  opportunistic  behavior  that  pervades  the  ex- 
isting institutional  structure  would  be  reduced  significantly. 

B.     Public  Ownership  of  Generating  Facilities 

Another  alternative  governance  structure  is  suggested  by  Williamson's 
analysis  if  the  utility  construction  transaction  is  determined  to  be  re- 
current, rather  than  infrequent. '^^  When  the  frequency  of  the  transaction 
is  recurrent,  a  unified  (vertically  integrated)  governance  structure  is  im- 
plied. ^^"^  Vertical  integration  exists  when  one  firm  both  supplies  and 
utiUzes  some  factor  of  production  such  that  the  output  from  one  portion 
of  the  company  is  the  input  for  another  portion. '^^  For  example,  the 
current  electric  utility  industry  is  vertically  integrated  since  each  utility 
company  generates,  transmits  and  distributes  electric  power. ^^^  The  output 
from  the  generation  portion  of  the  company  is  the  input  of  the  trans- 
mission portion,  and  the  output  of  the  transmission  portion  is  the  input 
for  the  distribution  function.  The  advantage  of  vertical  integration  is 
that  adaptations  can  be  made  sequentially  without  the  need  to  consult. 


159.  Binding  arbitration  would  not  affect  negotiation  and  monitoring  costs  in  this 
case  because  those  costs  are  determined  by  the  existing  regulatory  structure.  In  some  cases, 
binding  arbitration  would  affect  negotiating  and  monitoring  costs  depending  on  the  con- 
fidence the  parties  have  in  the  arbitration  process.  The  less  confidence  the  parties  have 
in  arbitration,  the  more  likely  they  are  to  address  all  terms  and  conditions  in  the  negotiation 
process. 

160.  A  federal  arbitration  structure  would  be  relatively  inexpensive  to  establish  and 
maintain  because  the  federal  institutional  structure  is  already  in  place.  It  can  be  reasonably 
assumed  that  the  FERC  would  seldom  have  to  arbitrate  specific  disagreements  since  it  is 
the  threat  of  arbitration,  rather  than  the  arbitration  itself,  that  will  modify  the  parties' 
behavior, 

161.  Again,  the  costs  of  opportunistic  behavior  are  beUeved  to  be  significant  in 
most  jurisdictions.  See  Pierce,  supra  note  43. 

162.  Efficiency  is  achieved  by  minimizing  transaction  costs. 

163.  Williamson,  supra  note  49. 

164.  Id.  at  253. 

165.  M.  Crew  &  P.  Kleindorfer,  The  Economics  of  Public  Utility  Regulation 
(1986). 

166.  P.  JosKow  &  R.  ScHMALENSEE,  supra  note  10,  at  11, 


1104  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

complete  or  revise  interfirm  agreements. ^^^  When  a  single  ownership 
spans  both  sides  of  the  transaction,  joint  profit  maximization  exists  and 
price  and  quantity  adjustments  can  be  made  with  the  frequency  necessary 
to  maximize  joint  profits. ^^^ 

One  example  of  an  institutional  structure  which  incorporates  the 
principals  of  unified  governance  is  the  public  ownership  of  generating 
facilities. ^^^  Although  public  ownership  of  generating  facilities  is  not 
vertical  integration  per  se,  public  ownership  does  provide  for  unified 
ownership  on  both  sides  of  the  transaction,  thereby  creating  a  unity  of 
interest  similar  to  vertical  integration  schemes. *^°  With  public  ownership, 
the  same  party  would  be  both  buyer  and  seller,  and  opportunistic  behavior 
would  not  occur  since  it  has  no  ability  to  maximize  joint  profits. ^^' 

The  complexity,  uncertainty  and  frequency  of  the  transaction  is  not 
affected  by  public  ownership  of  generating  capacity.  As  was  the  case 
with  the  competitive  bidding  scenario,  construction  times  would  remain 
long,  while  predicting  costs  and  demand  would  remain  highly  complex 
and  subject  to  error. '^^  The  frequency  of  the  transactions  should  not  be 
impacted  so  long  as  the  optimal  unit  size  is  determined  by  non-insti- 
tutional factors. '^^  The  significant  cost  of  financing  utility  construction 
might,  however,  be  an  incentive  for  constructing  smaller  units. ^^"^ 

The  idiosyncrasy  of  the  investment  may  not  be  affected  by  a  pubhc 
ownership  scenario  since  neither  the  asset  nor Jts  output  need  be  trans- 
ferable for  public  ownership  to  be  in  force. '^^  If  generating  units  are 
financed  and  owned  by  local  consumers,  and  are  to  be  used  solely  for 
their  benefit,  the  physical  and  institutional  constraints  may  continue  to 
exist. ^''^  If  the  ownership  of  generating  facilities  is  accomplished  at  the 
state  or  federal  level  the  idiosyncrasy  of  the  investment  may  be  reduced 
as  the  output  from  any  unit  may  be  used  to  serve  a  variety  of  service 


167.  Williamson,  supra  note  49,  at  253. 

168.  Id. 

169.  Public  ownership  of  generating  facilities  incorporates  the  principles  of  vertical 
integration,  but  it  is  not  truly  a  vertical  integration  structure. 

170.  Public  ownership  is  distinct  from  true  vertical  integration  since  individual 
consumers  would  still  purchase  the  electricity.  With  true  vertical  integration  assets  are 
transferred  intrafirm,  without  a  market  transaction. 

171.  Joint  profits  are  the  sum  of  the  buyer's  profits  and  the  seller's  profits.  Joint 
profits  are  not  necessarily  achieved  by  maximizing  the  profits  of  each  party  separately. 

172.  Dowd  &  Burton,  supra  note  10. 

173.  Id. 

174.  If  the  economies  of  scale  tending  to  make  large  units  more  economic  are  not 
significant  it  may  be  more  efficient  to  build  smaller  units  more  frequently. 

175.  Public  ownership  per  se  does  not  require  that  a  generating  unit  serve  more 
than  one  service  territory. 

176.  The  physical  and  institutional  constraints  are  described  in  notes  45-46  and 
accompanying  text. 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1105 

territories. ^^"^  The  impact  of  the  idiosyncrasy  would  be  eliminated  because 
the  unification  of  financial  interest  precludes  opportunistic  behavior. '^^ 
Idiosyncrasy  is  only  important  due  to  its  opportunistic  impact  so  the 
idiosyncrasy  of  the  investment  is  not  of  great  concern  when  public 
ownership  is  accompHshed.^''^  Under  pubHc  ownership,  the  consumers 
are  at  interest  on  both  sides  of  the  transaction  so  there  is  no  potential 
for  opportunistic  gain  by  ex  post  revision  of  the  contract. 

The  most  persuasive  factors  against  the  public  ownership  proposal 
are  political  and  financial.  On  the  political  level,  there  is  a  national 
aversion  to  public  ownership. '^°  The  American  economy  is  based  on  free 
enterprise  and  any  proposal  to  eliminate  private  ownership  of  utility 
assets  would  undoubtedly  meet  substantial  resistance.  The  significant 
cost  of  generating  capacity  would  also  create  financial  constraints.*^' 
While  utility  investors  may  voluntarily  commit  millions  of  dollars  to  a 
construction  project,  a  public  ownership  scenario  would  make  those 
investments  mandatory  for  all  consumers. '^^  Many  people  do  not  have 
sufficient  resources  to  prospectively  pay  for  generating  facilities  which 
may  not  be  used  for  several  years. '^^ 

A  transaction  cost  analysis  of  public  ownership  of  generating  facilities 
indicates  that  transaction  costs  could  be  significantly  reduced  through 
that  alternative.  The  potential  for  opportunistic  behavior  would  be  ehm- 
inated,  although  bargaining  and  monitoring  costs  may  be  increased. 
Political  and  financial  constraints  may,  however,  preclude  this  alternative 
from  extensive  consideration. 

VIII.     Conclusion 

Governance  structures — the  institutional  framework  within  which 
transactions  are  negotiated  and  executed — vary  with  the  nature  of  the 


177.  When  the  output  from  a  generating  unit  can  be  sold  to  a  competitive  market 
of  potential  purchasers  the  investment  is  no  longer  idiosyncratic.  Idiosyncrasy  requires 
that  the  asset  be  transaction-specific. 

178.  Opportunistic  behavior  is  precluded  since  joint  profit  maximization  is  not 
achieved  by  uncooperative  behavior  for  a  unified  firm. 

179.  WiUiamson,  supra  note  49,  at  241. 

180.  The  trend  in  the  United  States  has  been  toward  more  private  ownership  rather 
than  more  public  ownership. 

181.  Costs  of  new  generating  facilities  range  from  $100  million  to  $5  billion.  See 
Dept.  of  Energy,  Projected  Costs  of  Electricity^  from  Nuclear  and  Coal-Fired 
Power  Plants  (1986). 

182.  It  can  be  assumed  that  all  taxpayers  would  participate  in  any  public  ownership 
of  electric  generating  facilities  since  any  plan  involving  optional  participation  would  en- 
counter "free-rider"  problems. 

183.  The  cost  to  consumers  over  time  would  remain  the  same  as  it  currently  is 
since  the  existing  regulatory  scheme  provides  for  the  "purchase"  of  generating  facilities 
through  the  collection  of  depreciation  expense.  There  would  be  an  upfront  cost,  though, 
as  existing  plant  were  transferred  from  private  to  public  ownership. 


1106  INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW  [Vol.  22:1085 

transaction.  Transaction  cost  analysis  evaluates  the  characteristics  of  a 
transaction  to  determine  what  institutional  structure  can  most  efficiently 
govern.  In  particular,  the  characteristics  of  complexity,  uncertainty,  fre- 
quency and  idiosyncrasy  are  emphasized  by  transaction  cost  analysis. 
Transaction  cost  analysis  recognizes  that  these  characteristics  affect  the 
costs  of  negotiating,  monitoring  and  enforcing  the  contract,  and  that 
these  transaction  costs  are  real  costs  which  must  be  accounted  for  in 
determining  the  least-cost  institutional  structure. 

The  transaction  at  issue  here  is  the  transaction  whereby  utility  inves- 
tors finance  and  build  an  electric  utility  plant  for  consumers  who  sub- 
sequently compensate  the  investors  for  their  costs.  That  transaction  may 
be  characterized  as  an  infrequent  transaction  requiring  significant  amounts 
of  transaction-specific  investment  to  be  made  under  conditions  of  great 
uncertainty.  The  transaction  is  infrequent  because  economies  of  scale 
dictate  the  addition  of  large  generating  units  which  are  added  every  five 
to  ten  years.  The  transaction  requires  a  large  amount  of  transaction- 
specific  (idiosyncratic)  investment  so  long  as  physical  and  institutional 
factors  preclude  the  wheeling  of  bulk  power.  The  transaction  is  uncertain 
since  the  long  time  necessary  to  build  the  plant  and  complete  the 
transaction  makes  the  ultimate  economic  value  of  the  plant  difficult  to 
predict. 

The  traditional  regulatory  governance  structure  is  not  an  efficient 
way  to  govern  the  utility  construction  transaction  because  it  allows  the 
amount  of  construction  expense  which  can  be  recovered  through  rates 
to  be  determined  after  the  investment  has  been  made.  Because  the 
investment  is  idiosyncratic  (involves  a  high  level  of  sunk  costs),  this  ex 
post  determination  of  asset  value  allows  opportunistic  behavior  by  con- 
sumers acting  through  the  regulatory  agency.  The  potential  for  oppor- 
tunism is  especially  troublesome  under  this  governance  structure  because 
of  the  great  uncertainty  caused  by  the  long  time  necessary  to  build  the 
plant  and  complete  the  transaction.  The  potential  for  opportunistic  be- 
havior by  regulators  increases  the  cost  of  the  transaction  by  imposing 
significant  risks  on  investors  who  may  have  their  investment  "appro- 
priated" by  an  ex  post  determination  of  the  asset's  value. 

Competitive  bargaining  proposals  may  reduce  transaction  costs  by 
ehminating  the  generating  asset's  idiosyncrasy.  Once  the  investment  is 
not  transaction-specific,  the  potential  for  opportunistic  behavior  is  sig- 
nificantly lowered  and  the  total  cost  of  the  transaction  is  correspondingly 
reduced.  The  risks  and  uncertainties  of  opportunistic  behavior  present 
significant  costs  to  the  transaction,  and  any  institutional  arrangement 
which  reduces  those  costs  should  more  efficiently  govern.  The  costs  of 
regulation  (monitoring  and  enforcement)  are  also  decreased  significantly 
as  a  market  governance  structure  accomphshes  those  duties  at  a  lower 
cost.  Competitive  bidding  proposals  do  require  an  increase  in  bargaining 


1989]  INSTITUTIONAL  ARRANGEMENTS  1107 

costs,  although  the  reduction  in  other  transaction  costs  should  more  than 
compensate  for  that  increase. 

Preapproved  contract  approaches  may  also  reduce  transaction  costs 
by  limiting  the  potential  for  opportunistic  behavior.  In  contrast  to  com- 
petitive bidding  proposals,  preapproved  contract  alternatives  do  not  limit 
opportunistic  behavior  by  reducing  the  investment's  idiosyncrasy;  instead, 
they  utilize  extensive  regulatory  monitoring  coupled  with  the  statutory 
preclusion  of  opportunistic  behavior.  Preapproved  contract  approaches 
will  increase  negotiation  and  monitoring  costs,  but  the  reduction  in 
opportunistic  behavior  makes  the  total  transaction  cost  low. 

Institutional  arrangements  incorporating  binding  arbitration  might 
also  be  a  more  efficient  means  of  governance.  Binding  arbitration  is  a 
form  of  the  trilateral  governance  structure  that  is  especially  efficient 
when  investments  are  idiosyncratic  and  transactions  are  infrequent.  Bind- 
ing arbitration  increases  enforcement  costs,  but  decreases  the  risk  of 
asset  appropriation  and  thereby  lowers  the  cost  of  the  construction 
transaction.  Like  preapproved  contract  alternatives,  binding  arbitration 
would  require  minimal  change  in  the  existing  institutional  structure. 

The  public  ownership  of  generating  facilities  is  another  institutional 
structure  which  would  decrease  total  transaction  costs.  When  one  party 
is  both  '^seller"  and  "buyer"  there  is  no  incentive  to  shift  costs  onto 
another  party  by  behaving  in  an  opportunistic  manner.  Negotiation, 
monitoring  and  enforcement  costs  would  also  be  reduced  as  those  proc- 
esses are  internalized  through  vertical  integration.  In  spite  of  the  potential 
benefits,  however,  the  political  and  financial  constraints  arising  from 
the  public  ownership  of  private  property  would  appear  to  preclude  this 
option  from  gaining  widespread  acceptance. 

The  transaction  cost  literature  has  identified  opportunistic  behavior 
as  a  primary  determinant  of  transaction  costs,  and  of  the  efficiency  of 
institutional  structures  which  govern  transactions.  All  of  the  proposals 
discussed  reduce  transaction  costs  by  limiting  opportunistic  behavior  when 
compared  with  traditional  regulatory  governance.  Serious  consideration 
of  alternative  institutional  structures  for  governing  the  utility  construction 
transaction  is  required  if  transaction  costs  are  to  be  reduced  and  utility 
construction  is  to  proceed  at  the  levels  necessary  to  support  American 
economic  growth. 

Timothy  N.  Thomas 


INDIANA 
LAW  REVIEW 


VOLUME  22 

1989 

INDEX  &  TABLE  OF  CASES 


The  Trustees  of  Indiana  University 
Copyright  ©  1990 


Indiana  La^v  Revie^v 


Volume  22 


1989 


Editor-in-Chief 
Robert  G.  Solloway 

Executive  Editors 


Articles  and  Production 
Carol  Kirk 


Notes  and  Topics 
Katharine  Liell  Polito 


Articles  Editors 
Rebecca  S.  Bowman  Madonna  F.  McGrath 

Debra  Linn  Burns  Peggy  J.  Naile 

Cynthia  Pearson  Purvis 

Business  Editor  and  Survey  Coordinator 
Robert  Davis 

Note  Development  Editors 
Bruce  J.  Alvarado  Catherine  A.  Kling 

Douglas  E.  Cressler  OH  via  A.  Napariu 

Karen  Glasser  Deane  Douglas  K.  Norman 


Associate  Editors 

Rene  F.  Barnard  Kisti  L.  Good 

Carolyn  A.  Bielefeld  Barbara  E.  Lollar 

Raymond  Charles  Bowyer  Karen  R.  McClure 

Thomas  A.  Brodnik  Deborah  B.  Noah 

Gary  L.  Chapman  Paul  F.  Reidy 

L.S.  John  Ciecimirski  Mara  J.  Snyder 

Jane  A.  B.  Eppink  Clare  M.  Sproule 

Brian  S.  Fennerty  Darlene  M.  Stephens 

E.  Scott  Tread  way 


Editorial  Assistant 
Amy  Morrison  Grubbs 

Faculty  Advisor 
Paul  J.  Galanti 


1989)  INDEX  m 

ARTICLES 


Current  Issues  Affecting  Indiana  Tax  Policy 

Larry  J.  Stroble 
Ronald  d'Avis     449 
Defending  Purchase  Money  Security  Interests  Under  Article  9  of  the  UCC 
From  Professor  Buckley 

Paul  M.  Shupack     111 
Developments  in  Federal  Civil  Practice  Affecting  Indiana  Practitioners:  Survey 
of  Supreme  Court,  Seventh  Circuit,  and  Indiana  District  Court  Opinions 

John  R.  Maley     103 
Developments  in  Indiana  Emloyment  Law 

Leland  B.  Cross,  Jr. 
Douglas  Craig  Haney     249 
Developments  in  Social  Security  Law 

Michael  G.  Ruppert     401 
Discoverability  of  Privileged  Physician-Patient  and  Peer  Review  Communica- 
tions: Not  What  the  Doctor  Ordered 

Peter  M.  Racher     151 
The  Dram  Shop:  Closing  Pandora's  Box 

William  Hurst     487 
The  Efficiency  of  a  Disgorgement  as  a  Remedy  for  Breach  of  Contract 

Sidney  W.  Belong     131 
Frivolous,  Unreasonable  or  Groundless  Litigation:  What  Shall  the  Standard 
Be  for  Awarding  Attorney's  Fees? 

Donald  Clementson-Mohr 

Jeffrey  A.  Cooke     299 
An  Indiana  Doctor's  Duty  to  Warn  Non-Patients  at  Risk  of  HIV  Infection 
from  an  AIDS  Patient 

Kenneth  M.  Stroud     587 
The  Indiana  Motor  Vehicle  Protection  Act  of  1988:  The  Real  Thing  for 
Sweetening  the  Lemon  or  Merely  a  Weak  Artificial  Sweetener? 

Harold  Greenberg       57 
Indiana  Revised  Uniform  Limited  Partnership  Act 

Paul  J.  Galanti       11 
Indiana's  New  Guardianship  Code:  A  New  Emphasis  on  Alternative  Forms 
of  Protection 

David  M.  Berry     335 
Insurance  Law 

John  C.  Trimble     229 
McClanahan  v.  Remington  Freight  Lines,  Inc. :  Making  a  Mountain  Out  of 
Molehill 

Richard  Pitts 
Susan  Stuart         1 


Medical  Malpractice 

The  New  Indiana  Child  Support  Guidelines 


Thomas  R.  Ruge     535 

Gale  M.  Phelps 
Jerald  L.  Miller     203 
Professional  Responsibility 

Martin  E.  Risacher     313 
Recent  Developments  Affecting  the  Criminal  Procedure  in  Indiana 

Monica  Foster     163 


iv  INDIANA  LA  W  REVIEW  [Vol.  22 


The  Right  to  a  Lawyer  at  a  Lineup:   Support  From  State  Courts  and 
Experimental  Psychology 

Neil  C.  McCabe     905 
Second  Wind  for  the  Indiana  Bill  of  Rights 

Chief  Justice  Randall  T.  Shepard     575 
Selected  Current  Topics  in  Indiana  Taxation 

Francina  A.  Dlouhy     419 
Survey  of  Indiana  Products  Liability  Cases:  1987-88 

Michael  Rosiello 
Ronald  V.   Weisenberger     263 
Survey  of  Indiana  Property  Law 

Walter  W.  Krieger     369 
A  Survey  of  Indiana  Tort  Law 

Michael  Rosiello 
John  R.  Talley     503 
Survey  of  Recent  Developments  in  the  Indiana  Law  of  Evidence 

Norman  T.  Funk     181 
Worker's  Compensation 

Robert  A.  Fanning     553 


NOTES 


Delimiting  the  Manufacturer's  Liability:  An  Examination  of  Loss  of  Con- 
sortium Recovery  in  Strict  Products  Liability  Actions  Under  Section  402A 
of  the  Restatement  (Second  of  Torts) 821 

The  Eleventh  Amendment  Controversy  Continues:  The  Availability  and  Scope 
of  Relief  Against  State  Entities  Under  the  Education  of  the  Handicapped  Act     707 

The  Fraud-on-the-Market  Theory:  A  "Basic"ally  Good  Idea  Whose  Time 
Has  Arrived,  Basic,  Inc.  v.  Levinson 1061 

Institutional  Arrangments  for  Governing  the  Construction  of  Electric 
Generating  Units:  A  Transaction  Cost  Analysis  1085 

"A  Modest  Proposal" — The  Prohibition  of  All- Adult  Communities  by  the 
Fair  Housing  Amendments  Act  of  1988 1021 

Partial  Settlement  of  Multiple  Tortfeasor  Cases  Under  the  Indiana  Com- 
parative Fault  Act 939 

Random  Drug  Testing  of  PoUce  Officers:  A  Proposed  Procedure  Which 
Satisfies  Fourth  Amendment  Requirements 799 

Retroactive  Application  of  Legislatively  Enlarged  Statutes  of  Limitations  for 
Child  Abuse:  Time's  No  Bar  to  Revival 989 

The  Standard  of  Proof  in  Civil  RICO  Actions  for  Treble  Damages:  Why 
the  Clear  and  Convincing  Standard  Should  Apply 881 

The  Test  for  Patent  Infringement  Under  the  Doctrine  of  Equivalents  After 
Pennwalt  v.  Durand-  Wayland 849 

Tort  Liability  for  DPT  Vaccine  Injury  and  the  Preemption  Doctrine  ....      655 

The  Work  Made  for  Hire  Doctrine  Under  the  Copyright  Act  of  1976: 
Employees,  Independent  Contractors  and  the  Actual  Control  Test  ....      619 


1989] 


INDEX 


TABLE  OF  CASES 


Abbot  V.  American  Cyanamid 

Co.  676 

Acme  Milles  &  Elevator  Co.  v. 

Johnson  769-70 

ACS  Hospital  Systems,  Inc.  v. 

Montefiore  Hospital     856,  863,  865 
Addington  v.  Texas  892 

Aetna  Insurance  Co.  v.  Rodriguez 

229,  233-34 
Affiliated  Ute  Citizens  v.  United 

States  1068-69 

Aldon  Accessories  Ltd.  v.  Spiegel, 

Inc.  630,  633,  635-36, 

643-45,  648-52 
Al-Kazemi  v.  General  Acceptance 

&  Investment  Corp.  897 

Allen  V.  State  169 

Alston  V.  State  179 

American  United  Life  Insurance  Co. 

V.  Peffley  184 

Anderson  v.  Liberty  Lobby,  Inc. 

104-05,  113-24,  126-30 
Anderson  v.  Thompson  722-23,  725 
Armco  Industrial  Credit  Corp.  v. 

SLT  Warehouse  Co.  888 

Arnold  v.  State  Farm  Mutual 

Automobile  Insurance  Co.  242 

Ashlock  V.  Norris  499 

Ashton  V.  Anderson  198-99 

Atascadero  State  Hospital  v. 

Scanlon  708-09,  711-12,  714, 

716-19,  721,  725-28,  734 
Automobile  Underwriters,  Inc.  v. 

Hitch  230-34 


B 


Babcock  v.  Jackson  264 

Baggett  V.  State  159 

Baker  v.  American  States  Insurance 

Co.  517 

Baker  v.  Townsend  399-400 

Barnes  v.  A.H.  Robins  Co.        284-89 
Basic  Inc.  v.  Levinson  1063-65, 

1073-83 
Bass  Foundry  &  Machine  Works  v. 

Board  of  Commissioners  2,  3 

Batchelor  v.  State  579 

Bates  V.  State  Bar  of  Arizona 

313,  315 
Bates  V.  State  172 


Batson  v.  Kentucky  170-71 

Baxter  v.  State  166 

Beach  v.  M  &  N  Modern  Hydraulic 

Press  963 

Beem  v.  Chestnut  491 

Bellew  V.  Byers  504 

Bemis  Co.  v.  Rubush  278 

Betsey  v.  Turtle  Creek  Assoc.        1031 
Billman  v.  Hensel  400 

Blackie  v.  Barrack  1069-71 

Bleistein  v.  Donaldson  Lithographing 

Co.  621,  623 

Blood  V.  Poindexter  420, 

443-44,  446-47 
Blue  Chip  Stamps  v.  Manor  Drug 

Stores  900,  1062-63,  1071-79 

Blue  V.  State  930 

Board  of  Commissioners,  Allen  County 

V.  Trautman  3,  5 

Board   of  Zoning  Appeals   v.    Sink 

981,  983,  985-86 
Bostic  V.  McClendon  812 

Boston  V.  Chesapeake  &  Ohio 

Railway  515-16 

Bowles  V.  Tatom  510-11,  953-54 

Bown  &  Sons  v.  Honabarger  396 

Boyle  V.  United  Technologies 

Corp.  293-95,  297-98,  698-99 

Brant  Construction  Co.  v.  Lumen 

Construction,  Inc.  184 

Braughton  v.  Metropohtan  Board  of 

Zoning  Appeals  5,  7 

Bridgewater  v.  Economy  Engineering 

Co.  278 

Brokers,  Inc.  v.  White  530-31 

Brooks  V.  State  163 

Brown  v.  American  Fletcher  National 

Bank  397 

Brown  v.  Board  of  Education         729 
Brown  v.  Keill  960,  962-67,  971 

Brown  v.  Penn  Central  Corp.         378 
Brunswick  Beacon,  Inc.  v.  Schock- 

Hopchas  Publishing  Co.  651 

Bud  Wolf  Chevrolet,  Inc.  v. 

Robertson  518,  520 

Burger  Man,  Inc.  v.  Jordan  Paper 

Products,  Inc.  184 

Burk  V.  Anderson  493 

Burke  v.  Capello  190 

Burlington  School  Committee  v. 

Department  of  Education  722, 

724,  731 


VI 


INDIANA  LA  W  REVIEW 


[Vol.  22 


Burns  v.  State 


166      Craig  v.  ERA  Mark  Five 
Realtors 
Cross  V.  State 


369 

172 


Calder  v.  Bull  998-99, 

1002-03,  1007-08,  1011-12 
Calvary  Baptist  Church  v. 

Joseph  531-33 

Campbell  v.  Holt  1015,  1018 

Canfield  v.  Sandock  151-52 

Cannaday  v.  State  926 

Capua  v.  City  of  Plainfield  810, 

816-17 
Celotex  Corp.  v.  Catrett  104-05, 

108-13,  117,  124,  126 
Charlie  Stuart  Oldsmobile,  Inc. 

v.  Smith  516,  518 

Chase  Securities  Corp.  v. 

Donaldson  1010,  1014,  1018 

Chase  v.  Nelson  384 

Childers  v.  High  Society  Magazine, 

Inc.  641,  648-49 

Citizens  Action  Coahtion  of  Indiana 

V.  Nothern  Indiana  PubUc  Service 

Co.  1088,  1095 

City  of  Bloomington  v. 

Kuruzovich  523-24 

City  of  Palm  Bay  v.  Bauman  812 
City  of  Tucson  v.  Gallagher  981 

Cleveland  Board  of  Education  v. 

Lafleur  1034 

Closson  Lumber  Co.  v.  Wiseman 

(I)  (II)  382-84 

Colligan  v.  Cousar  493 

ColUns  V.  Associated  Pathologists, 

Ltd.  125 

Commonwealth  v.  Bargeron  1008-09 
Commonwealth  v.  Richman  925,  927 
Community  for  Creative  Non- Violence 

V.  Reid  620,  631 

Complete    Auto    Transit,    Inc.    v. 

Brady  438 

Conafay  v.  Wyeth  Laboratories  681 
Conrad  v.  State  195 

Consolidated  Products,  Inc.  v. 

Lawrence  258,  262,  564 

Cooper  V.  Robert  Hall  Clothes 

943,  948 
Covalt  V.  Carey-Canada,  Inc.         285, 

287,  290-91 
Cox  V.  Indiana  Subcontractors 

Association,  Inc.  13,  17-18, 

20-22,  24 
Coy  V.  Iowa  583 


D 


Dague  V.  Piper  Aircraft  Corp.       284, 

286-89 

David  D.  V.  Dartmouth  School 

Committee  727,  729-32 

Davis  Cattle  Co.  v.  Great  Western 

Sugar  Co.  761, 

763-64,  766,  771-72 
Decker  v.  State  168-69 

Department  of  Revenue  v.  Kimball 

International,  Inc.  473 

Derrick  v.  Ontario  Community 

Hospital  598-99 

Dillon  V.  Legg  839-41 

Doe  ex  rel.  Gonzales  v.  Maher       727 
Don  Meadows  Motors,  Inc.  v.  State 

Board  of  Tax  Commissioners      419 
Dunlap  V.  Wagner  491,  493 

Dunn  V.  Cadiente  542 


E 


Easley  v.  Metropolitan  Board  of 

Zoning  Appeals  6,  7 

Easter  Seal  Society  For  Crippled 

Children  and  Adults  of  Louisiana, 

Ind.  V.  Playboy  Enterprises        630, 

632,  651 
Eastham  v.  Whirlpool  Corp.  562,  568 
Edelman  v.  Jordan  719 

Eichler  v.  Scott  Pools,  Inc.  245 

Eisenstadt  v.  Baird  1048 

Elder  v.  Fisher  492-94,  496-97 

Ellis  V.  Union  Pacific  Railroad 

Co.  969-72 

Elmore  v.  American  Motors 

Corp.  839 

Ember  v.  BFD.,  Inc.  522-23, 

527,  596 
Enyeart  v.  Kepler  373 

Epoch  Producing  Corp.  v.  Killiam 

Shows,  Inc.  625 

Escobedo  v.  lUinois  920 

Escola  V.  Coca-Cola  Bottling 

Co.  825-26 

Estate  of  Fasken  484-85 

Estate  of  Mathes  v.  Ireland  539 

Evans  Newton,  Inc.  v.  Chicago 

Systems  Software  650-51 


1989] 


INDEX 


Vll 


Evans  v.  Yankeetown  Dock  Corp. 

258-60,  553,  561-69 
Everts  v.  Arkham  House  Publishers, 

Inc.  649 

Ex  Parte  Virginia  720 

Exeter  Towers  Associates  v. 

Bowditch  893-94 


Farm  Bureau  Co-Op  v.  Deseret  Title 

Holding  Corp.  392 

Farmers  &  Merchants  State  Bank  v. 

Norfolk  &  Western  Railway 

Co.  507 

Fendley  v.  Ford  186 

Feres  v.  United  States  295-96 

Ferriter  v.  Daniel  O'Connell's 

Sons  Inc.  824 

Fidelity  &  Casualty  Co.  v. 

Garcia  236 

Finney  v.  Johnson  462 

Fitzpatrick  v.  Bitzer  719,  721 

Fleischer  v.  Hebrew  Orthodox 

Congregation  523-24 

Flowers  v.  John  Burnham  & 

Co.  1036-37 

Flowers  v.  State  175 

Forte  V.  State  932-35 

Foster  v.  States  (see  n.  92)  905, 

916,  932,  934 
Frampton  v.  Central  Indiana  Gas. 

Co.  11,  249-53,  261 

Freeman  v.  Robinson  577 

French  v.  Sunburst  Properties, 

Inc.  526 

Frey  v.  Snelgrove  978-81,  983-84 

Frick  V.  Pennsylvania  483 


Gammill  v.  United  States  598 

Gariup  Construction  Co.  v. 

Foster  497-99 

Gary  A.  v.  New  Trier  High  School 

District  No.  203  725-27 

Gear  v.  City  of  Des  Moines 

13-18,  21-22 
Geier  v.  Wikel  966-67 

Gideon  v.  Wainwright  578 

Gilbert  v.  California  919, 

921,  933,  935 
Givens  v.  Lederle  Laboratories        681 


Glover  v.  Tacoma  General 

Hosp.  985 

Goff  V.  Graham  390 

Gomez  v.  Illinois  State  Board 

of  Education  726,  732 

Graham  v.  Wyeth  Laboratories 

689,  693 
Graver  Tank  &  Manufacturing  Co.  v. 

Linde  Air  Products  850,  852, 

858,  861,  872-73,  876,  878 

Gray  v.  Chacon  503-04,  947-49, 

966,  987 
Great  Western  Sugar  Co.  v.  Northern 

Natural  Gas  Co.  764,  766, 

770-71,  773-74 
Greenman  v.   Yuba  Power  Products, 

Inc.  821,  826-27,  829-30 

Griffith  v.   County  School  Board  of 

Prince  Edward  County  729 

Groce  v.  Johns-Manville  Sales 

Corp.  292 

Groves  v.  First  National  Bank  of 

Valparaiso  517-18 

Gulf  Stream  Coach,  Inc.  v.  State  Board 

of  Tax  Commissioners         427,  429 


H 


Hager  v.  National  Union  Electric 

Co.  266 

Halet  V.  Wend  Investment  Co.     1032, 
1034,  1036,  1048-49 
Halliday  v.  Auburn  Mobile 

Homes  388 

Hammond  v.  North  American  Asbestos 

Corp.  842 

Hammonds  v.  Aetna  Casulty  593 

Haroco  v.  American  National  Bank 

and  Trust  Co.  894 

Hatcher  v.  State  197-98 

Hayes  v.  State  194-95 

Henley  v.  State  197 

Herff  Jones,  Inc.  v.  State  Bd.  of  Tax 

Comm'rs  444-45 

Herman  &  MacLean  v.  Huddleston 

889,  899,  900-01 
Hill  V.  Metropolitan  Trucking,  Inc. 

507-08,  952,  964 
Hillsborough  County,  Florida  v. 

Automated  Medical  Laboratories, 

Inc.  690 

Hinkle  v.  Niehaus  Lumber  Co.      113, 

268,  270 


Vlll 


INDIANA  LA  W  REVIEW 


[Vol.  22 


Hitaffer  v.  Argonne  Co.  823 

Hoffman  v.  Blackmon  597 

House  V.  D.P.D.,  Inc.  565-67 

Hubbard  Manufacturing  Co.  v. 

Greeson  263,  265-67,  297 

Huber  v.  Henley         506-09,  952,  964 
Hughes  Aircraft  Co.  v.  United 

States  856,  860-65,  869-71,  873 

Hurley  v.  Lederle  Laboratories 

690-92,  694 
Hurtado  v.  California  576 

Hutto  V.  Finney  733 


In  re  Agnew 
In  re  Briggs 
In  re  Holloway 
In  re  Jones 
In  re  Klein 


372 

327 

332 

330-31 

111-12 


In  re  LTV  Securities  Litigation  1068 
In  re  Musser  329,  331 

In  re  Oliver  330,  332 

In  re  Orbison  326 

In  re  Petit  329-31 

In  re  Sandy  Ridge  Oil  Co.,  Inc.  395 
In  re  Swihart  329 

In  re  Wurm  356 

Indiana  Department  of  Revenue  v. 

Kimberly-Clark  Corp.  439 

Indiana  Department  of  State  Revenue  v. 

AMAX,  Inc.  473 

Indiana  Department  of  State  Revenue 

V.  Cave  Stone,  Inc.  471-74 

Indiana  Department  of  State  Revenue 

V.  Estate  of  Pearson  476-77, 

482-83,  486 
Indiana  Department  of  State  Revenue 

V.  Indiana  Harbor  Belt  Railroad 

Co.  473 

Indiana  Department  of  State  Revenue 

V.  Indianapolis  Transit  System,     Inc. 

470 
Indiana  Department  of  State  Revenue 

V.  RCA  Corp.  469-71,  474 

Indiana  State  Board  of  Tax 

Commissioners  v.  Lyon  and  Greenleaf 

Co.  462,  464 

Indiana  State  Board  of  Tax 

Commissioners  v.  Stanadyne, 

Inc.  429 

Indiana  State  Highway  Commission 

V.  Morris  158 

Ingram  v.  Hook's  Drugs,  Inc.         282 


Inter  dent  Corp.  v.  United  States 

859-60,  864 
International  Sygma  Photo  News,  Inc. 

V.  Glove  International  Inc.  649 

ITT  Industrial  Credit  Co.  v.  R.T.M. 

Development  Co.,  Inc.  380 


J.  C.  Penney  Co.  v.  Wesolek 

521-22,  524 
Jennings  v.  State  167-68 
Jeski  V.  Connaught  Laboratories, 

Inc.  692 

Johnson  v.  Moberg  982 

Johnson  v.  Padilla  547 

Jones  V.  Griffith                       543,  547 

Jones  V.  State  184 

Jordan  v.  State  176 


K 


Kately  v.  Wilkinson  841 

Kennedy  v.  City  of  Sawyer  968, 

970-72 
KerHn  v.  State  198 

Kikkert  v.  Krumm  300-04 

Kindred  v.  State  159 

King  V.  State  195 

Kirby  v.  lUinois  906-08,  916,  918-35 
Kline  v.  Business  Press,  Inc.  187-89 
K-Mart  Corp.  v.  Novak  259,  262 

Knox  V.  AC  «fe  S,  Inc.  285,  290 

Kroske  v.  Townsend  Engineering 

Co.  277 

Krach  v.  Heilman  490-91,  493 

Kring  v.  Missouri  1014,  1016 

Kroger  Co.  Sav-On  Store  v. 

Presnell  270,  272 

Kuchel  V.  State  198 


Lafary  v.  Lafary  189,  374 

Lamont  Building  Co.  v.  Court  1036 
Langley  v.  Monumental  Corp.  1035 
Larsen  v.  General  Motors  Corp.  273 
Laurin  v.  DeCaroHs  Constr.  Co., 

Inc.  748 

Lemelson  v.  United  States  856, 

864-65,  871 
Lesher  v.  Baltimore  Football  Club 

306-07,  310 
Liebig  v.  Superior  Court  of  Napa 

County  1017 


1989] 


INDEX 


IX 


624 
980 


Lin-Brook  Builders  Hardware!  v. 

Gertler 
Lines  v.  Ryan 
Liquid  Air  Corp.  v.  Rogers 

892,  899,  901 
Livingston  v.  State  927-28 

Love  V.  State  170-71 

Lovvorn  v.  Chattanooga  811 

Luna  V.  Bowen  401,  406,  410, 

412,  414,  416-17 


M 


594 


MacDonald  v.  dinger 
MacPherson  v.  Buick  Motor 

Co.  825-46 

Maggio  V.  Lee  301-02 

Mapp  V.  Ohio  575,  578 

Marina  Point,  Ltd.  v.  Wolfson 

1037-38,  1044-45,  1050 
Marshall  v.  Miles  Laboratores, 

Inc.  651 

Marshall  v.  Reeves  307 

Martinkovic  v.  Wyeth  Laboratories, 

Inc.  681 

Mathes  v.  Ireland  601 

Mathews  v.  United  States  169-70 

Mauricio  v.  Duckworth  164-65 

Maxwell  v.  Hahn  379 

May  V.  Morganelli-Heumann  & 

Associates  649 

McCambridge  v.  State  935 

McCIanahan  v.  Remington  Freight 

Lines,  Inc.  1,  10,  12-17, 

19-22,  24-25,  250-53,  261 
McDonell  v.  Hunter  816 

McDowell  V.  Johns-Mansville  Sales 

Corp.  292 

McMartin  v.  County  of  Los 

Angeles  990 

Meltzer  v.  Zoller  649 

Meredith  v.  Bowen  401-06, 

410,  412,  414,  416 
Merrill  v.  Wimmer  398 

Metro  Cable  Co.  v.  CATV  of 

Rockford,  Inc.  901 

MetropoHtan  Housing  Development 

Corp.  V.  Village  of  Arlington 

Heights  1032 

Miller  v.  Loman  234,  237-38 

Miller  v.  Todd  274 

Mills  V.  State  583 

Miranda  v.  Arizona  920 

Mirtinez  v.  State  932 

Moffatt  V.  Brown  127 


Moore  v.  City  of  East  Cleveland  1034 
Moore  v.  General  Motors  Corp.,  Delco 

Remy  Division  505 

Moore  v.  General  Motors  Corp. 

953,  960 
Moravian  Development  Corp.  v.  Dow 

Chemical  Co.  896 

Morgan  Drive  Away,  Inc.  v. 

Brant  250-52 

Murray  v.  Gelderman  624 

Muth  V.  Central  Bucks  School 

District  731 

Myers  v.  State  184 

N 

Nagunst  v.  Western  Union  Tel 

Co.  958,  960 

National  Can  Corp.  v.  Jovanovich 

260,  262 
National  Mutual  Insurance  Co. 

V.  Edward  241,  243 

Neal  V.  Home  Builders,  Inc.  596 

Nelson  v.  Secretary  of  Health  & 

Human  Serv.  416 

Niagara  Mohawk  Corporation  v. 

Wanamaker  468 

NLRB  V.  United  Insurance  co.  of 

America  647 

Nobiesville  Casting  Division  of 

TRW,  Inc.  V.  Prince  193 

Northwestern  States  Portland  Cement 

Co.  V.  Minnesota  437-38 

Nur  V.  Blake  Developmen 

Corp.  109,  112 


O 


O'Bryant  v.  Veterans  of  Foreig 

Wars  532 

O'Connor  v.  Ortega  808 

O'Connor  v.  Sears,  Roebuck  and 

Co.  130-31,  135-38 

Or  kin  Exterminating  Co.  v 

Traina  121 

Orr  V.  State  195 

Orr  V.  Turco  Manufacturing 

Co.  304-12 

Ortho  Pharmaceutical  Corp.  v. 

Chapman  280,  282 


Pacific  Gas  &  Electric  Co.  v.  State 
Energy  Resources  Conservation  & 
Development  Commission  697 


INDIANA  LA  W  REVIEW 


[Vol.  22 


Page  Two,  Inc.  v.  P.C.  Management 

Inc.  388 

Page  V.  State  177,  926-27 

Panzirer  v.  Wolf  1070-71 

Parden  v.  Terminal  Railway  717-18 
Park   100  Development  Company  v. 

Indiana  Department  of  State 

Revenue  423 

Park  V.  Standard  Chemical  Way 

Co.  840,  843 

Parkview  Memorial  Hospital,  Inc. 

V.  Pepple  157 

Patterson  v.  State  188-89 

Patton  V.  State  173 

Paul  V.  Kuntz  511-12 

Payne  v.  State  184,  186 

Peil  V.  Speiser  1067 

Penmanta  Corp.  v.  Mollis  393 

Pennhurst  State  School  &  Hosp.   v. 

Halderman  728 

Pennwalt  Corp.  Durand-Wayland,  Inc. 
849,  857-59,  870-72,  874 
Penny  v.  Kennedy  811 

People  V.  Anderson  929 

People  V.  Bustamante  930-31 

People  V.  Fowler  931 

People  V.  Jackson  929 

Peregrine  v.  Lauren  Corp.  638,  641 
Per  kin-Elmer  Corp.   v.   Westinghouse 

Electric  Corp.  857,  862, 

868-71,  873-74 
Perry  v.  Sindermann  257 

Perry  v.  State  178 

Phelps  v.  Sherwood  Medical 

Industries  279,  281-83 

Picadilly,  Inc.  v.  Colvin  489-90, 

494,  496-99 
Picture  Music,  Inc.  v.  Bourne, 

Inc.  624 

Pierringer  v.  Hoger  976, 

978-82,  986-87 
Pieters  v.  B-Right  Trucking, 

Inc.  514-16 

Pohcemen's  Benevolent  Association 

V.  Washington  Township  800, 

814-16,  820 
Popp  V.  Hardy  385 

Posey  V.  Lafayette  Bank  and  Trust 

Company  306-07,  311 

Prigg  V.  Pennsylvania  577 


R 


Rahn  v.  Gerdts 
Raj  ski  V.  Tezich 


838 
376 


Rambaum  v.  Swisher  975-76 

Ramsey  v.  United  Mine  Workers 

900,  902 
Rappaport  v.  Nichols  488-89 

Rasp  V.  Hidden  Valley  Lake, 

Inc.  375 

RCA  V.  State  Board  of  Tax 

Commissioners  432 

Reed  v.  Ford  Motor  Co.  120, 

122,  272 
Reeve  v.  Georgia-Pacific  Corp. 

528-29 
Roberts  v.  Carrier  Corp.  160-61 

Rochin  v.  California  580 

Rodriguez  v.  Bethlehem  Steel 

Corp.  834 

Rogers  v.  Hembd  569 

Romack  v.  Public  Service  Co.       253, 

255-56,  261 
Rylands  v.  Fletcher  835 


Saenz  v.  Playbor  Enterprises       117-19 
Samuels  v.  State  189 

San  Jose  Country  Club  Apartments 

V.  County  of  Santa  Clara  1049 

Sanders  v.  Cole  Municipal  Finance  132 
Sanders  v.  Townsend  321, 

323-26,  528 
Santosky  v.  Kramer  887 

Sarratore  v.  Longview  Van  Corp. 

250,  252,  261 
Scherr  v.  Universal  Match  Corp.  625 
Schmerber  v.  California  580,  809 

Schneider  v.  Wilson  199-200 

Schon  V.  Van  Diest  Supply  Co.      372 
Schreiber  Distribution  Co.  v. 

Serv-Well  Furniture  Co.  885 

Scroggins  v.  Uniden  Corp.  of 

America  160-61 

Scully  V.  United  States  120 

Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  v. 

Capital  Gains  Research  Bureau    901 
Sedima,  S.P.R.L.  v.  Imrex  Co., 

Inc.  886-88,  894 

Senff  V.  Estate  of  Levi  186-87 

Sepulveda  v.  American  Motors  Sales 

Corp.  85 

Shannon  v.  Bepko  256-57,  262 

Shapero  v.  Kentucky  Bar 

Association  313-21 

Sharp  V.  Bailey  568 

Shelton  v.  Tucker  1049 

Shepard  v.  Supeiior  Court  840-41 


1989] 


INDEX 


XI 


Shockley  v.  Prier  824 

Shoemaker  v.  Handel     809-10,  814-17 
Shores  v.  Sklar  1070-71,  1078 

Shortridge  v.  Review  Board  of  Indiana 

Employment  Security  Division 

18,  23 
Silkwood  V.  Kerr-McGee  Corp.  697-98 
Skendzel  v.  Marshall  232 

Slaughter-House  Cases  576 

Sloan  V.  Metropolitan  Health  Counsel 

of  Indianapolis,  Inc.  538-40 

Smith  V.  Robinson  724,  730 

Smithers  v.  Mettert  238,  240 

Smock  V.  Coots  1053 

South  Bend  Federation  of  Teachers 

V.  National  Education  Association 

13,  20,  21,  23 
Sports  Bench,  Inc.  v.  McPherson  526 
St.  Joseph  College  v.  Morrison, 

Inc.  300,  302 

Stainko  v.  Tri-State  Coach  Lines, 

Inc.  525 

Starks  v.  State  174 

State  Board  of  Tax  Commissioners  v. 

Chicago,  Milwaukee,  St.  Paul  & 

Pacific  Railroad  464 

State  Department  of  Revenue  v. 

Calcar  Quarries,  Inc.  471-72 

State  ex.  rel.  Hiland  v.  Fountain 

Circuit  Court  540 

State  ex.  rel.  Keaton  v.  Rush  Circuit 

Court  165-66 

State  Farm  Mutual  Automobile 

Insurance  Co.  v.  Barton  236-37 

State  Line  Elevator,  Inc.  v.  State  Board 

of  Tax  Commissioners         429,  431 
State  V.  Creekpaum  999,  1001-03 

State  V.  Hodgson  1006-07 

State  V.  Lasselle  577 

State  V.  Purdue  National  Bank      478, 

482,  486 
Stockberger  v.  Meridian  Mutual 

Insurance  Co.  230-34 

Stone  V.  State  189 

Stroud  V.  State  584 

Struble  v.  Nodwift  490-91 

Stueve  V.  American  Honda  Motors 

Co.  966 

Sunshine  Anthracite  Coal  Co.  v. 

Adkins  8,  9 

Swain  v.  Alabama  170 


Taber  v.  Hutson 


584 


Tarasoff  v.  Board  of  Regents 

599-606,  608-12 
Taxpayers  Association  of  Weymouth 

Township,  Inc.  v.  Weymouth 

Township  1050 

Taylor  v.  State  583 

Teamsters  Local  282  Pension  Trust 

Fund  V.  Angelos  120 

Terre  Haute  Regional  Hospital,   Inc. 

V.  Basden  158 

Texas  Instruments  Inc.  v.  International 

Trade  Commission  856,  865, 

867-68,  870,  872-73,  878-79 
Thompson  v.  Utah  1016-17 

Toner  v.  Lederle  Laboratories         676 
Treichler  v.  Wisconsin  483-85 

TSC  Industries,  Inc.  v.  Northway, 

Inc.  1073 


U 


United  States  Tobacco  Co.  v. 

Commonwealth  439 

United  States  v.  Ash  906,  929 

United  States  v.  Cappetto  895-96 

United  States  v.  Gouveia  922-23 

United  States  v.  Guiliano  894 

United  States  v.   Local  560  of  Inter- 
national Brotherhood  of  Teamsters 
887,  892,  896,  900 
United  States  v.  Utah  Construction  & 
Mining  Co.  7,  10 

United  States  v.  Wade  905-08, 

910,  916-21,  924-25,  930-35 


Vaccaro  v.  Squibb  Corp.  841 

Valentine  v.   Joilet  Township  High 

School  District  No.  204  111-12 

Valley  Liquors,  Inc.  v.  Renfield 

Importers,  Ltd.  124 

Van  Cleave  v.  State  173 

Veal  V.  Bowen  401,  406,  410, 

412-14,  416 


W 


Walker  v.  Bowen  401,  406, 

410,  412,  414,  416 
Walter  v.  Schuler  460 

Walters  v.  Dean  510 

Walters  v.  Mintec  International       838 
Walters  v.   Owens-Corning  Fiberglass 
Corp.  285-87 


xu 


INDIANA  LAW  REVIEW 


[Vol.  22 


Walters  v.  Rinker  536-37 

Weaver  v.  Graham  1000,  1002 

Welch  V.  Texas  Department  of  Highways 

and  Pubhc  Transportation  718,  735 
Wells  V.  State  183-84 

West  Publishing  Co.  v.  Indiana 

Department  of  Revenue  419-20, 

439-42 
Whisman  v.  Fawcett  494,  496-97 


179 


V. 


White  V.  State 
Whiteco  Industries,  Inc. 

Kopani  255,  261 

Wilcox  V.  First  Interstate  Bank       898 
Williams  v.  Crist  244 

Willis  V.  State  184-85 

Wilmington  v.  Harvest  Insurance 

Cos.  253,  261 

Wilson  V.  Sligar  196 

Wilson  V.  State  198 

Winans  v.  Denmead  858 

183-84 


Wishard  Memorial  Hospital  v. 

Logwood  516 

Witherspoon  v.  Salm  264 

Wixom  V.   Gledhill  Road  Machinery 


Co. 
Wojcik  V.  Aluminum  Co.  of 

America 
Woodby  V.  INS 
Woodhill  V.  Parke  Davis  & 

Co. 

Y 


275-76 

597 
886-92 

841-43 


192 


Wiseman  v.  State 


Yang  V.  Stafford 

Yardley  v.  Houghton  Mifflin  Co.  624 

Young  V.  Hoke  948-49 


Zauderer  v.  Office  of  DiscipHnary 

Counsel  315 

Zimmerman  v.  State  195